Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Explaining the Current Innovative R&D Outsourcing to Developing Countries

  • Published:
Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

While multinational firms from developed countries have used researchers from emerging areas to assist in the adaption of an existing product, few multinational firms have carried out innovative R&D, or R&D for the creation of a new product, in these areas. Using the threat of imitation and wage differences of researchers across regions, this study proposes a partial equilibrium model to explain the lack of innovative R&D in developing countries. I build a North-South model examining a single firm’s choice of research locations. The model predicts that weak IPR-protection in developing countries does not necessarily explain the lack of Southern research. In some situations, reduced IPR-protection can even increase Southern research. Harsh competition resulting from information leaks coupled with weak IPR-protection can explain much of the lack of innovative research investment in the developing world. My model also predicts that firms with low research needs, or firms in low-tech industries, locate their R&D in the North. Firms with medium research need locate in both countries while the firms with the largest research needs, or firms in high-tech industries, locate research in just the South.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Ganco (2013), using a researcher’s prior work at the firm as a proxy for the knowledge internalized within the researcher, finds evidence suggesting researchers with a higher degree of internalized knowledge are more likely to begin their own firm. Knowledge complexity also seems to be positively associated with an entire team of researchers starting their own firm rather than individual entrepreneurship. Yang and Jiang (2007) provide a literature review of employee mobility in R&D outsourcing for emerging countries.

  2. Offshoring of innovative research in the 1990s was largely driven by the desire to reduce costs and the need to increase the speed to markets; following this period, access to quality researchers becomes the driving factor (Lewin et al. 2009). The knowledge profile is less of a motivator as capable researchers can now be found in a number of emerging economies. For example, China’s first year doctoral students have increased by a factor of six during that same time period (Lewin et al. 2009).

  3. Skaperdas (1996) uses an axiomatic approach to provide support for using the CSF proposed by Tullock in a number of rent seeking contests. Tulluck contests have been applied to R&D races in the past (Baye and Hoppe 2003). Leininger (1993) examines the asymmetric Tullock lottery function similar to the one used in this paper. Leininger includes a scaling parameter on the effort of one player in order to reflect differential advantages. Baik (1994) and Fonseca (2009) explore the properties of asymmetric Tullock lotteries; however, few authors have looked at Tullock lotteries where a single player chooses both players’ effort levels. Jia et al. (2013) outline many difficulties in empirically examining a contest. Specifically, effort tends to be unobservable. Seeing as the actual researchers working on the project largely drive successful innovation, I model effort as the number of researchers in each region.

  4. Linking R&D costs to the fixed cost of entry has been long established by previous international trade literature. For example, Melitz (2003) uses a model with a fixed cost a firm must pay in order to export. This fixed cost of exporting is explained as the cost of adaptive research in order to prepare the product to be sold in new markets.

  5. The probability of imitation is based around the large amount of fixed costs that the Southern firm must pay if it is not able to copy the product through mobile Southern researchers. I assume that the Southern firm will face sufficiently large costs to further research the product if the firm loses the imitation lottery. This additional fixed cost of entry is high enough to keep the firm out of the market. Also, I assume that successful imitation requires very little extra cost in order to enter the market. Thus, successful imitation leads to the entry of the Southern firm.

  6. As outlined in Keupp et al. (2009), there are multiple other methods to protecting against imitation: increasing the complexity of the product, using trade secrets, fostering loyalty among employees, building strong relationship with regulatory government bodies, and advertising to increase consumer preference over a lesser quality imitation. Firms experiment with trial and error to determine the best strategy for their specific situation. There is little empirical research on how successful these techniques are for preventing imitation. Given the empirical literature indicating IPR-protection as a major driver of location decisions, these alternate methods of protecting innovations seem to be not as important as traditional legal methods.

  7. Multinational firms have been shown to apply for patents in areas with weak IPR-protection institutions. Using survey evidence from multinational firms from developed countries with foreign affiliates in China, Keupp et al. (2012) find that seeking patents in weak IPR-environments is often done as a way of signaling advanced technology to the market. Firms may also patent with the expectation that IPR-protection will soon strengthen.

  8. Although there has been some evidence to suggest that employee mobility and entrepreneurship is tied to individual performance (Carnahan et al. 2012), I treat each Southern researcher as homogenous in their threat of leaving to bring their knowledge to a competing firm.

  9. In general, 𝜃 adds a certain amount of realism to the model in providing an additional barrier to imitation when all research is carried out in the South. Allowing Southern researchers to be less effective does not change the comparative static results of this model. I explore the case where 0 < 𝜃 < 1 in Appendix B.1.

  10. I prove this claim in Appendix B.2.

  11. Offshoring R&D is often used as a method of accessing specialized knowledge that differs from the knowledge accumulated in the home country. Following the findings of Demirbag and Glaister (2010), I assume that the knowledge profile of the country does not affect the offshoring decision for firms locating in developing regions. Thus, employing Southern researchers only decreases labor costs and does not introduce any productivity gains.

  12. This is proven in Appendix B.3.

  13. These parameter relationships are explored in Result 1.

  14. Some innovations are not able to be split across multiple countries. A complex innovation may require that all research tasks are pursued together. Firms then locate all innovative activities within one location. However, complex innovations can have modulars of tasks that can be pursued individually and then reassembled to create the larger innovation (Simon 1962).

  15. FOCs actually yield two solutions for RN; however, the unreported value of Northern researchers is a negative value and exists on the portion of the profit function that is convex. This unreported solution is thus a minimum.

  16. The assumptions on parameter values for Case 1 can be seen by plugging in RN < 0. Likewise, the assumptions for Case 2 are found using \(0<{R^{N}}^{*}<\overline {R}\). Finally, Case 3 assumptions are found using \(\overline {R}<{R^{N}}^{*}\). The specific assumptions are presented in Result 1.

  17. This case is shown in Appendix B.1.

  18. Imitation can occur without any offshoring of innovation. For example, Connolly (2003) shows that exporting products to a country can cause product imitation from firms in that country. This model deals with products that are sufficiently difficult to imitate. That is, the cost of imitation is so great that the Southern firm will not find it profitable to reverse engineer the product without some inside information regarding the innovation process. Multinational firms ensure high imitation costs of their products through “masquing” (Taylor 1993) or protecting complementary resources (Zhao 2006). Smith (1999) shows that US firms are not deterred from exporting their product to a country if the firms do not consider the country to pose a strong threat of imitation.

References

  • Alacer J, Zhao M (2012) Local R&D strategies and multilocation firms: the role of internal linkages. Manag Sci 58(4):734–753

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antras P, Helpman E (2004) Global sourcing. J Polit Econ 112(3):552–580

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arvanitis S, Hollenstein H (2011) How do different drivers of R&D investment in foreign locations affect domestic firm performance? An analysis based on Swiss Panel micro data. Ind Corp Chang 20(2):605–640

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baik K H (1994) Effort levels in contests with two asymmetric players. South Econ J 61(2):367–378

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baye MR, Hoppe HC (2003) The strategic equivalence of rent-seeking, innovation, and patent-race games. Games Econom Behav 44:217–226

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Branstetter L, et al. (2007) Intellectual property rights, imitation, and foreign investment: theory and evidence. National Bureau of Economic Research

  • Canals C, Sener F (2014) Offshoring and intellectual property rights reform. J Dev Econ 108:17–31

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carnahan S, Agarwal R, Campbell BA (2012) Heterogeneity in turnover: the effect of relative compensation dispersion of firms on the mobility and entrepreneurship of extreme performers. Strateg Manag J 33:1411–1430

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chowdhury SM, Sheremeta RM (2011) A generalized Tullock contest. Public Choice 147(3):413–420

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Colombo L, et al. (2017) Does easy start-up formation hamper incumbents’ R&D investment? Small Bus Econ 49(3):513–531

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Connolly M (2003) The dual nature of trade: measuring its impact on imitation and growth. J Dev Econ 72(1):31–55

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • d’Aspremont C, Jacquemin A (1988) Cooperative and noncooperative R&D in Duopoly with spillovers. Am Econ Rev 78(5):1133–1137

    Google Scholar 

  • Demirbag M, Glaister KW (2010) Factors determining offshore location choice for R&D projects: a comparative study of developed and emerging regions. J Manag Stud 47 (8):1534–1560

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dinopoulos E, Segerstrom P (2007) North-South trade and economic growth. Stockholm School of Economics

  • Dinopoulos E, Segerstrom P (2010) Intellectual property rights, multinational firms, and economic growth. J Dev Econ 92:13–27

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ekholm K, Hakkala K (2007) Location of R&D and high-tech production by vertically integrated multinationals. Econ J 117:512–543

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fonseca MA (2009) An experimental investigation of asymmetric contests. Int J Ind Organ 27:582–591

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gambardella A, Ganco M, Honoré F (2014) Using what you know: patented knowledge in incumbent firms and employee entrepreneurship. Organ Sci 26(2):456–474

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ganco M (2013) Cutting the Gordian knot: the effect of knowledge complexity on employee mobility and entrepreneurship. Strateg Manag J 334:666–686

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glass A J, Wu X (2007) Intellectual property rights and quality improvement. J Dev Econ 82:393–415

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman GM, Helpman E (2002) Integration vs outsourcing in industry equilibrium. Q J Econ 117(1):85–120

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gustafsson P, Segerstrom P (2011) North-South trade with multinational firms and increasing product variety. Int Econ Rev 52(4):1123–1155

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall BH, Jaffe AB, Trajtenberg M (2001) The NBER patent citation data file: lessons, insights and methodological tools. No. w8498. National Bureau of Economic Research

  • Helpman E (1993) Innovation, imitation, and intellectual property rights. Econometrica 61(6):1247–1280

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hedge D, Hicks D (2008) The maturation of global corporate R&D: evidence from the activity of US foreign subsidiaries. Res Policy 37:390–406

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ito B, Wakasugi R (2007) What factors determine the mode of overseas R&D by multinationals? Empirical evidence. Res Policy 36:1275–1287

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jia H, Skaperdas S, Vaidya S (2013) Contest functions: theoretical foundations and issues in estimation. Int J Ind Organ 31(3):211–222

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kamien M I, Muller E, Zang I (1992) Research joint ventures and R&D Cartels. Am Econ Rev 82(5):1293–1306

    Google Scholar 

  • Keupp M M, Beckenbauer A, Gassmann O (2009) How managers protect intellectual property rights in China using de facto strategies. R&D Manag 39(2):211–224

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keupp M M, Friesike S, von Zedtwitz M (2012) How do foreign firms patent in emerging economies with weak appropriability regimes? Archetypes and motives. Res Policy 41(8):1422–1439

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lai EL-C, Riezman R, Wang P (2009) Outsourcing of innovation. Econ Theory 38(3):485–515

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leininger W (1993) More efficient rent-seeking: a Munchhausen solution. Public Choice 75(1):43–62

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewin AY, Massini S, Peeters C (2009) Why are companies offshoring innovation? The emerging global race for talent. J Int Bus Stud 40(6):901–925

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lundin N, Serger S S (2007) Globalization of R&D and China: empirical observations and policy implications. No. 710. IFN Working Paper 710

  • Melitz MJ (2003) The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity. Econometrica 71(6):1695–1725

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moncada-Paterno-Castello P, Vivarelli M, Voigt P (2011) Drivers and impacts in the globalization of corporate R&D: an introduction based on the European experience. Ind Corp Chang 20(2):583–603

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon HA (1962) The architecture of complexity. Proc Am Philos Soc 106 (6):467–482

    Google Scholar 

  • Skaperdas S (1996) Contest success functions. Econ Theory 7(2):283–290

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith PJ (1999) Are weak patent rights a barrier to US exports? J Int Econ 48 (1):151–177

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sun Y, Du D, Huang L (2006) Foreign R&D in developing countries: empirical evidence from Shanghai, China. China Rev 6(1):67–91

    Google Scholar 

  • Taylor MS (1993) TRIPS, trade, and technology transfer. Can J Econ 26(2):625–637

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Unesco Science Report 2010 Unesco (2011)

  • US BEA (2018) U.S. Direct Investment Abroad, all majority-owned foreign affiliates (data for 2009 and forward), Research and Development Expenditures (accessed November 14)

  • Yang Q, Jiang CX (2007) Location advantages and subsidiaries’ R&D activities in emerging economies: exploring the effect of employee mobility. Asia Pac J Manag 24 (3):341–358

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhao M (2006) Conducting R&D in countries with weak intellectual property rights protection. Manag Sci 52(8):1185–1199

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Zachary Cohle.

Appendices

Appendix A: Proof of Propositions and Results

1.1 A.1 Proof of Proposition 1

The second derivative of profit function (7) is equal to:

$$ \frac{\partial^{2} \pi}{\partial {R^{N}}^{2}}=\frac{-(1-\zeta) \zeta \overline{R} [\overline{\pi}-\underline{\pi}] }{(R^{N}(1-\zeta)+\zeta\overline{R})^{3}} <0 $$
(13)

Since 1 > ζ > 0, \( [\overline {\pi }-\underline {\pi }]\), and RN > 0, it must be the case that \(\frac {\partial ^{2} \pi }{\partial {R^{N}}^{2}}<0\). Therefore, the profit function (7) is concave.

1.2 A.2 Proof of Result 1

Result 1 presents the assumption values for Cases 1, 2, and 3. In Case 1, the Northern firm locates entirely in the North. Using Eq. 8, the Northern firm sets \(R^{N}=\overline {R}\) when \( {R^{N}}^{*} \geq \overline {R} \):

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \left( \frac{1}{1-\zeta}\right)\left( \frac{[\overline{\pi}-\underline{\pi}]\zeta\overline{R}}{w^{N}-w^{S}}\right)^{\frac{1}{2}}-\left( \frac{\zeta}{1-\zeta}\right)\overline{R} & \geq& \overline{R} \\ \left( \frac{1}{1-\zeta}\right)\left( \frac{[\overline{\pi}-\underline{\pi}]\zeta\overline{R}}{w^{N}-w^{S}}\right)^{\frac{1}{2}} &\geq& \overline{R}+ \left( \frac{\zeta}{1-\zeta}\right)\overline{R} \\ \left( \frac{1}{1-\zeta}\right)\left( \frac{[\overline{\pi}-\underline{\pi}]\zeta\overline{R}}{w^{N}-w^{S}}\right)^{\frac{1}{2}} &\geq& \left( \frac{1}{1-\zeta}\right)\overline{R} \\ \left( \frac{[\overline{\pi}-\underline{\pi}]\zeta}{w^{N}-w^{S}}\right) &\geq& \overline{R} \\ \end{array} $$

Thus, in Case 1, \(\left (\frac {[\overline {\pi }-\underline {\pi }]\zeta }{w^{N}-w^{S}}\right ) \geq \overline {R} \) must be true. For Case 2, the Northern firm is at an interior condition. Using Eq. 8, the Northern firm sets RN = RN when \(0 < {R^{N}}^{*} < \overline {R} \):

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} 0&<& \left( \frac{1}{1-\zeta}\right)\left( \frac{[\overline{\pi}-\underline{\pi}]\zeta\overline{R}}{w^{N}-w^{S}}\right)^{\frac{1}{2}}-\left( \frac{\zeta}{1-\zeta}\right)\overline{R} < \overline{R} \\ \left( \frac{\zeta}{1-\zeta}\right)\overline{R} &<& \left( \frac{1}{1-\zeta}\right)\left( \frac{[\overline{\pi}-\underline{\pi}]\zeta\overline{R}}{w^{N}-w^{S}}\right)^{\frac{1}{2}} < \overline{R}+ \left( \frac{\zeta}{1-\zeta}\right)\overline{R} \\ \left( \frac{\zeta}{1-\zeta}\right)\overline{R} &<& \left( \frac{1}{1-\zeta}\right)\left( \frac{[\overline{\pi}-\underline{\pi}]\zeta\overline{R}}{w^{N}-w^{S}}\right)^{\frac{1}{2}} < \left( \frac{1}{1-\zeta}\right)\overline{R}\\ \zeta &<& \left( \frac{[\overline{\pi}-\underline{\pi}]\zeta}{(w^{N}-w^{S})\overline{R} }\right)^{\frac{1}{2}} < 1\\ \end{array} $$
$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \zeta^{\frac{1}{2}} &<& \left( \frac{[\overline{\pi}-\underline{\pi}]}{(w^{N}-w^{S})\overline{R} }\right)^{\frac{1}{2}} < \zeta^{\frac{-1}{2}} \\ \zeta^{\frac{1}{2}} \left( \frac{[\overline{\pi}-\underline{\pi}]}{(w^{N}-w^{S}) }\right)^{\frac{-1}{2}} < (\overline{R} )^{\frac{-1}{2}} &<& \zeta^{\frac{-1}{2}} \left( \frac{[\overline{\pi}-\underline{\pi}]}{(w^{N}-w^{S}) }\right)^{\frac{-1}{2}} \\ \frac{\zeta [\overline{\pi}-\underline{\pi}]}{(w^{N}-w^{S})}&<&\overline{R}<\frac{[\overline{\pi}-\underline{\pi}]}{\zeta (w^{N}-w^{S})} \end{array} $$

Therefore, the condition needed for an interior solution is, or for a Northern firm in Case 2:

$$ \frac{\zeta [\overline{\pi}-\underline{\pi}]}{(w^{N}-w^{S})}<\overline{R}<\frac{[\overline{\pi}-\underline{\pi}]}{\zeta (w^{N}-w^{S})} $$
(14)

Using Eq. 8, the Northern firm sets RN = 0 when RN≤ 0:

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} 0 &\leq& \left( \frac{1}{1-\zeta}\right)\left( \frac{[\overline{\pi}-\underline{\pi}]\zeta\overline{R}}{w^{N}-w^{S}}\right)^{\frac{1}{2}}-\left( \frac{\zeta}{1-\zeta}\right)\overline{R} \\ \left( \frac{\zeta}{1-\zeta}\right)\overline{R} &\leq& \left( \frac{1}{1-\zeta}\right)\left( \frac{[\overline{\pi}-\underline{\pi}]\zeta\overline{R}}{w^{N}-w^{S}}\right)^{\frac{1}{2}}\\ (\zeta \overline{R})^{\frac{1}{2}} &\leq& \left( \frac{[\overline{\pi}-\underline{\pi} ] }{w^{N}-w^{S}}\right)^{\frac{1}{2}}\\ \overline{R} &\leq& \left( \frac{[\overline{\pi}-\underline{\pi} ] }{\zeta(w^{N}-w^{S})}\right)^{\frac{1}{2}}\\ \end{array} $$

Thus, in Case 3, \(\overline {R} \leq \left (\frac {[\overline {\pi }-\underline {\pi } ] }{\zeta (w^{N}-w^{S})}\right )^{\frac {1}{2}}\) must be true.

1.3 A.3 Proof of Result 2

The Northern firm in Case 2 is the only type of firm to be affected by IPR changes. Taking the derivative of Eq. 8 wrt ζ for a Northern firm in Case 2 yields:

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} {} \frac{\partial R^{N}}{\partial \zeta}&=&\left( \frac{[\overline{\pi}-\underline{\pi}]}{\overline{R}(w^{N}-w^{S})} \right)^{\frac{1}{2}} \left( \frac{1}{1-\zeta} \right) \left( \frac{\zeta^{\frac{1}{2}}}{1-\zeta} + \frac{1}{2\zeta^{\frac{1}{2}}} \right) - \left( \frac{1}{1-\zeta} \right) \left( 1+\frac{\zeta}{1-\zeta} \right) \\ && \frac{\partial R^{N}}{\partial \zeta}=\left( \frac{[\overline{\pi}-\underline{\pi}]}{\overline{R}(w^{N}-w^{S})} \right)^{\frac{1}{2}} \left( \frac{1+\zeta} {(1-\zeta)2\zeta^{\frac{1}{2}}} \right) - \left( \frac{1}{1-\zeta} \right) \end{array} $$
(15)

For the Northern firm to increase Northern research in the face of weaker IPR-protection, or \( \frac {\partial R^{N}}{\partial \zeta }>0\), the following must be true:

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} {}\frac{\partial R^{N}}{\partial \zeta}>0 \ \ \ \ \\ \left( \frac{[\overline{\pi}-\underline{\pi}]}{\overline{R}(w^{N}-w^{S})} \right)^{\frac{1}{2}} \left( \frac{1+\zeta} {(1-\zeta)2\zeta^{\frac{1}{2}}} \right)&>\left( \frac{1}{1-\zeta} \right) \\ \left( \frac{[\overline{\pi}-\underline{\pi}]}{\overline{R}(w^{N}-w^{S})} \right)^{\frac{1}{2}} >&\frac{2}{1+\zeta} \\ \left( \frac{[\overline{\pi}-\underline{\pi}]}{\zeta(w^{N}-w^{S})} \right) \left( \frac{1+\zeta}{2}\right)^{2} >& \overline{R} \end{array} $$

So, for a firm with a value of total research that is smaller than \(\frac {[\overline {\pi }-\underline {\pi }]}{\zeta (w^{N}-w^{S})}\left (\frac {1+\zeta }{2}\right )^{2}\), weakening of IPR-protection results in more northern research. Since ζ is less than one, it is not difficult to see that:

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} {} \frac{\zeta[\overline{\pi}-\underline{\pi}]}{(w^{N}-w^{S})}<\frac{[\overline{\pi}-\underline{\pi}]}{\zeta(w^{N}-w^{S})} \left( \frac{1+\zeta}{2}\right)^{2} <\frac{[\overline{\pi}-\underline{\pi}]}{\zeta(w^{N}-w^{S})} \end{array} $$

Therefore, when the Northern firm locates in both countries, its reaction to IPR reform will be ambiguous. Low-tech firms in Case 2 will increase the amount of Northern research when IPR-protection weakens, while the high-tech firms will react by lowering the amount of Northern researchers.

1.4 A.4 Proof of Result 3

Taking the derivative of Eq. 8 wrt \([\overline {\pi }-\underline {\pi }]\) for a Northern firm in Case 2 yields:

$$ \frac{\partial R^{N}}{\partial [\overline{\pi}-\underline{\pi}] }=\left( \frac{1}{2} \right) \left( \frac{1}{1-\zeta} \right) \left( \frac{\overline{R} \zeta }{ [\overline{\pi}-\underline{\pi}] (w^{N}-w^{S})} \right)^{\frac{1}{2}} >0 $$
(16)

So, the amount of Northern researchers employed by the Northern firm in Case 1 and 3, the Northern firm’s choice in Northern researchers does not change as the penalty of imitation changes.

1.5 A.5 Proof of Result 4

Taking the derivative of Eq. 8 wrt (wNwS) for a Northern firm in Case 2 yields:

$$ \frac{\partial R^{N}}{\partial (w^{N}-w^{S})}=\left( \frac{-1}{2} \right) \left( \frac{1}{1-\zeta} \right) \left( \frac{\overline{R} [\overline{\pi}-\underline{\pi}] \zeta }{ (w^{N}-w^{S})^{2}} \right)^{\frac{1}{2}} <0 $$
(17)

In Case 1 and 3, the Northern firm’s choice in Northern researchers does not change as the difference in wages changes while holding the penalty of imitation constant.

Appendix B: Additions to the Model

2.1 B.1 Including 𝜃 as an IPR-Protection Parameter

Let 0 < 𝜃 < 1. This yields a new expected profit function:

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} {} E(\pi)&=&\frac{R^{N}+\zeta R^{S}(1-\theta)}{R^{N}+\zeta R^{S}} \overline{\pi}- \frac{\zeta\theta R^{S}}{R^{N}+\zeta R^{S}} \underline{\pi}-w^{N}(R^{N})-w^{S}(R^{S}) \\ &=&\left( \frac{R^{N}+\zeta R^{S}(1-\theta)}{R^{N}+\zeta R^{S}} \right)[\overline{\pi}-\underline{\pi}]+\underline{\pi}-w^{N}(R^{N})-w^{S}(\overline{R}-R^{N}) \end{array} $$
(18)

Maximizing equation (18) by choosing RN yields:

$$ R^{N}=\left( \frac{1}{1-\zeta}\right)\left( \frac{\theta[\overline{\pi}-\underline{\pi}]\zeta\overline{R}}{w^{N}-w^{S}}\right)^{\frac{1}{2}}-\left( \frac{\zeta}{1-\zeta}\right)\overline{R} $$
(19)

While 𝜃 does decrease the value RN at any given \(\overline {R}\), the inclusion of the IPR-protection parameter does not affect the directional response of RN to any other given parameter; however, with 0 < 𝜃 < 1, the magnitude of any comparative statics will change. Since 𝜃 enters equation (19) in only one place, the parameter can be absorbed into the penalty of imitation variable. So, the inclusion of the variable will be akin to lowering the penalty of imitation. Results 3 and 4 remain unchanged then. This can be seen by reworking Appendix A using Eq. 19. Result 1 slightly changes; however, the general result does not change. That is, Northern firms with small research needs still locate research in the North while Northern firms with large research needs locate all research in the North. Firms with medium research needs locate in both countries. Result 1 can then be rewritten:

Result 1

Low values of total research, \(\overline {R}\leq \frac {\zeta \theta [\overline {\pi }-\underline {\pi }]}{(w^{N}-w^{S})}\) , induce the Northern firm to locate all research in the North (Case 1). Large values of total research, specifically \(\overline {R}\geq \frac { \theta [\overline {\pi }-\underline {\pi }]}{\zeta (w^{N}-w^{S})}\) , induce the Northern firm to locate research only in the South (Case 3). The Northern firm locates in both countries (Case 2) for medium values of research, \(\frac {\zeta \theta [\overline {\pi }-\underline {\pi }]}{ (w^{N}-w^{S})}<\overline {R}<\frac { \theta [\overline {\pi }-\underline {\pi }]}{\zeta (w^{N}-w^{S})}\) .

Result 2 also changes in specific values; however, the general result does not change. Reworking Appendix A.3 yields:

Result 2

Weakening Southern IPR-protection has an ambiguous effect on R N and R S . Specifically, a weakening of Southern IPR-protection, or increasing ζ , decreases R N iff \( \left (\frac {1+\zeta }{2}\right )^{2}\frac {\theta [\overline {\pi }-\underline {\pi }]}{\zeta (w^{N}-w^{S})}<\overline {R}<\frac { \theta [\overline {\pi }-\underline {\pi }]}{\zeta (w^{N}-w^{S})} \) . Otherwise, \(\frac {\partial R^{N}}{\partial \zeta }\geq 0\) and \(\frac {\partial R^{S}}{\partial \zeta }\leq 0\) .

2.2 B.2 Including a Probability of Failure to Create the New Product

First, I assume that the innovation may not succeed even after the total amount of research requirement has been met. That is, the creating of one new unit of knowledge, or Y = 1, yields a successful innovation at a probability 1 − y0. The new expected profit function can be determined:

$$ E(\pi)=y_{0} \left[ (1-\phi)\overline{\pi}+\phi\underline{\pi}\right]-f_{e} $$
(20)

where y0 is less than 1. Expected profit function (7) can then be rewritten as:

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} {} E(\pi)&=&y_{0}\frac{R^{N}}{R^{N}+\zeta R^{S}} \overline{\pi}- y_{0}\frac{\zeta R^{S}}{R^{N}+\zeta R^{S}} \underline{\pi}-w^{N}(R^{N})-w^{S}(R^{S}) \\ &=&y_{0}\left( \frac{R^{N}+\zeta }{R^{N}+\zeta R^{S}} \right)[\overline{\pi}-\underline{\pi}]+y_{0}\underline{\pi}-w^{N}(R^{N})-w^{S}(\overline{R}-R^{N}) \end{array} $$
(21)

Maximizing Eq. 21 by choosing RN yields:

$$ R^{N}=\left( \frac{1}{1-\zeta}\right)\left( \frac{y_{0}[\overline{\pi}-\underline{\pi}]\zeta\overline{R}}{w^{N}-w^{S}}\right)^{\frac{1}{2}}-\left( \frac{\zeta}{1-\zeta}\right)\overline{R} $$
(22)

Again, y0 does decrease the value RN at any given \(\overline {R}\), but the overall results are not affected greatly. In fact, the inclusion of y0 changes the model in the exact way that inclusion of 𝜃 in the previous subsection. Since y0 enters Eq. 22 in only one place, the parameter can be absorbed into the penalty of imitation variable. So, the inclusion of the variable will be akin to lowering the penalty of imitation. Results 3 and 4 remain unchanged then. Result 1 changes:

Result 1

Low values of total research, \(\overline {R}\leq \frac {\zeta y_{0}[\overline {\pi }-\underline {\pi }]}{(w^{N}-w^{S})}\) , induce the Northern firm to locate all research in the North (Case 1). Large values of total research, specifically \(\overline {R}\geq \frac { y_{0} [\overline {\pi }-\underline {\pi }]}{\zeta (w^{N}-w^{S})}\) , induce the Northern firm to locate research only in the South (Case 3). The Northern firm locates in both countries (Case 2) for medium values of research, \(\frac {\zeta y_{0} [\overline {\pi }-\underline {\pi }]}{ (w^{N}-w^{S})}<\overline {R}<\frac { y_{0} [\overline {\pi }-\underline {\pi }]}{\zeta (w^{N}-w^{S})}\) .

Result 2 also changes in specific values; however, the general result does not change.

Result 2

Weakening Southern IPR-protection has an ambiguous effect on R N and R S . Specifically, a weakening of Southern IPR-protection, or increasing ζ , decreases R N iff \( \left (\frac {1+\zeta }{2}\right )^{2}\frac {y_{0} [\overline {\pi }-\underline {\pi }]}{\zeta (w^{N}-w^{S})}<\overline {R}<\frac { y_{0} [\overline {\pi }-\underline {\pi }]}{\zeta (w^{N}-w^{S})} \) . Otherwise, \(\frac {\partial R^{N}}{\partial \zeta }\geq 0\) and \(\frac {\partial R^{S}}{\partial \zeta }\leq 0\) .

2.3 B.3 Including Productivity Differences as an IPR-Protection Parameter

Suppose that Northern researchers are more effective than Southern researchers. So, \(\overline {R}=R^{N}+dR^{S}\), where 1 > d > 0. The profit function (7) can then be written as:

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} {} E(\pi)&=&\frac{R^{N}}{R^{N}+\zeta R^{S}}\overline{\pi}-\frac{\zeta R^{S}}{R^{N}+\zeta R^{S}}\underline{\pi}-w^{N}R^{N}-w^{S}R^{S} \\ &=&\left( \frac{R^{N}}{R^{N}(1-\frac{\zeta}{d} )+\frac{\zeta}{d} \overline{R}}\right)[\overline{\pi}-\underline{\pi}]+\underline{\pi}-w^{N}R^{N}-\frac{w^{S}}{d}*(\overline{R}-R^{N}) \end{array} $$
(23)

Taking the new FOC yields:

$$ {R^{N}}^{*}=\left( \frac{1}{1-\frac{\zeta}{d} }\right)\left( \frac{ [\overline{\pi}-\underline{\pi}]\frac{\zeta}{d} \overline{R}}{w^{N}-\frac{w^{S}}{d} }\right)^{\frac{1}{2}}-\left( \frac{\frac{\zeta}{d} }{1-\frac{\zeta}{d} }\right)\overline{R} $$
(24)

The inclusion of the d scales both the IPR-protection parameter ζ and the Southern wage. This does not affect the directional response of RN to any other given parameter. Reworking Appendix A using Eq. 24 shows that Results 3 and 4 are unchanged by allowing the productivities of Northern and Southern workers to differ. Result 1 slightly changes; however, the general result does not change. Result 1 can then be rewritten:

Result 1

Low values of total research, \(\overline {R}\leq \frac {\frac {\zeta }{d} [\overline {\pi }-\underline {\pi }]}{(w^{N}-\frac {w^{S}}{d})}\) , induce the Northern firm to locate all research in the North (Case 1). Large values of total research, specifically \(\overline {R}\geq \frac { [\overline {\pi }-\underline {\pi }]}{\frac {\zeta }{d} (w^{N}-\frac {w^{S}}{d})}\) , induce the Northern firm to locate research only in the South (Case 3). The Northern firm locates in both countries (Case 2) for medium values of research, \(\frac {\frac {\zeta }{d} [\overline {\pi }-\underline {\pi }]}{ (w^{N}-\frac {w^{S}}{d})}<\overline {R}<\frac { [\overline {\pi }-\underline {\pi }]}{\frac {\zeta }{d}(w^{N}-\frac {w^{S}}{d})}\) .

Result 2 also changes in specific values; however, the general result does not change. Reworking Appendix A.3 yields:

Result 2

Weakening Southern IPR-protection has an ambiguous effect on R N and R S . Specifically, a weakening of Southern IPR-protection, or increasing ζ , decreases R N iff \( \left (\frac {1+\frac {\zeta }{d}}{2}\right )^{2}\frac { d[\overline {\pi }-\underline {\pi }]}{\zeta (w^{N}-\frac {w^{S}}{d})}<\overline {R}<\frac { [\overline {\pi }-\underline {\pi }]}{\frac {\zeta }{d}(w^{N}-\frac {w^{S}}{d})} \) . Otherwise, \(\frac {\partial R^{N}}{\partial \zeta }\geq 0\) and \(\frac {\partial R^{S}}{\partial \zeta }\leq 0\) .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Cohle, Z. Explaining the Current Innovative R&D Outsourcing to Developing Countries. J Ind Compet Trade 19, 211–234 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10842-018-0288-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10842-018-0288-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation