Skip to main content

Using Agent-Based Modelling in Studying Labour–Education Market System

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Agent-Based Modelling of Social Networks in Labour–Education Market System

Part of the book series: SpringerBriefs in Complexity ((BRIEFSCOMPLEXITY))

Abstract

We’re now ready for a discussion on how exactly one could build an agent-based model of labour–education market system (LEMS). This discussion will necessarily be quite abstract, because particular mechanisms built into the model (agents, their behaviour, interactions, other structures) depend heavily on the purpose of the model. I’ll focus on general approaches and mechanisms that you may find useful when building agent-based models of LEMS.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    See [126] for a more elaborate review of agent-based models of the education market.

  2. 2.

    Assuming that the agent-based model is implemented in some object-oriented language .

  3. 3.

    The two decisions may depend on distinct sets of factors, but this is not a problem from the mathematical point of view.

  4. 4.

    Strictly speaking, in case of private education institutions, the quantity side still plays a role here, as they may be reluctant to turn the output filter on to full extent if that would mean such large drop-out rate that would make them miss their financial targets.

  5. 5.

    There’s no mistake here—it is possible to introduce job heterogeneity without introducing firms. This might, for instance, reflect occupations or industries.

  6. 6.

    These two variants are equivalent; the difference is only in the side where random choice is implemented. In the first-applied-first-accepted approach, the programmer randomises the sequence of persons in the queue of sending applications. In the random choice approach, persons send applications in any order (e.g., in the order they are stored in the array of labour market participants), and randomness is shifted to the process of choosing an element from the list of applications received by the firm.

  7. 7.

    Besides leaving the reader somewhat disappointed by hiding the details of your model, you make it harder to replicate it. There is a strand of research on agent activation , which studies in which cases seemingly minor differences in the implementation details of the mechanism of agent behaviour cause substantial differences in model outputs (see, e.g., [15, 69, 70] if you’re interested). Thus, a replica of the model may produce results that are inconsistent with the original model also if the replica’s author incorrectly inferred the actual—but unspecified—activation scheme used in the original model.

  8. 8.

    In [105] and [240], the authors actually consider reservation wage to be constant and reflect the absolute minimum wage under which the person will never be ready to work. Instead, they impose a random decrease of the “satisficing” wage—the one the person would like to receive—with unemployment duration.

  9. 9.

    This setting does allow to model overall increase and decrease in labour demand without the need to specify which employees firms lay off in case of downsizing. A downside is that job search takes place every period, which might be too frequent for your purposes.

  10. 10.

    Amadeus is a product of Bureau Van Dijk company and contains internationally comparable financial data on around 21 million European companies. For a global version, consider Orbis, a product from the same provider with data on more than 160 million companies.

  11. 11.

    For instance, the YANG external network generator is used in [173, 270], but network generating packages in Java or other general-purpose programming languages can also be used—an attractive option if the model is also created in that language (or in a framework that uses that language).

  12. 12.

    A connected component is a subgraph of an undirected graph where each pair of vertices is connected by a path and there are no other vertices in the graph that are connected to any vertex of the connected component but aren’t in its vertex set. Thus, the connected components of a graph are isolated from each other—there is no edge between a vertex in one component and a vertex in any other component.

  13. 13.

    Inbreeding homophily of type i is defined as \(\mathrm{IH}_{i} \equiv (H_{i} - w_{i})/(1 - w_{i})\), where H i is the share of ties of type-i individuals with other type-i individuals and w i is the share of type-i individuals in the population [77]. It measures the preference to creating ties with same-type individuals relative to the maximum bias, which is (1 − w i ). The inbreeding homophily index is then \(\mathrm{IH} \equiv \sum _{i}w_{i} \times \mathrm{IH}_{i}\) [80].

  14. 14.

    Discussing learning and adaptation algorithms is beyond the scope of this book. You can find a short introduction to this field specifically for economic modelling in, e.g., [48]. For more details, see books on artificial intelligence.

References

  1. Abdou, M., Gilbert, N.: Modelling the emergence and dynamics of social and workplace segregation. Mind Soc. 8(2), 173–191 (2009). doi:10.1007/s11299-009-0056-3

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Albert, R., Barabási, A.L.: Statistical mechanics of complex networks. Rev. Mod. Phys. 74, 47–97 (2002). doi:10.1103/RevModPhys.74.47

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Axtell, R.: Effects of interaction topology and activation regime in several multi-agent systems. In: Moss, S., Davidsson, P. (eds.) Multi-Agent-Based Simulation. Lecture Notes in Computer Science, vol. 1979, pp. 33–48. Springer, Berlin/Heidelberg (2001). doi:10.1007/3-540-44561-7_3

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  4. Ballot, G.: Modeling the labor market as an evolving institution: model ARTEMIS. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 49(1), 51–77 (2002). doi:10.1016/S0167-2681(02)00058-6

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Ballot, G., Kant, J.D., Goudet, O.: Modeling both sides of the French labor market with adaptive agents under bounded rationality. In: EAEPE Annual Conference, Paris (2013)

    Google Scholar 

  6. Boccaletti, S., Latora, V., Moreno, Y., Chavez, M., Hwang, D.U.: Complex networks: structure and dynamics. Phys. Rep. 424(4–5), 175–308 (2006). doi:10.1016/j.physrep.2005.10.009

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Bramoullé, Y., Saint-Paul, G.: Social networks and labor market transitions. Labour Econ. 17(1), 188–195 (2010). doi:10.1016/j.labeco.2009.09.011

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Brenner, T.: Agent learning representation: advice on modelling economic learning. In: Tesfatsion, L., Judd, K.L. (eds.) Handbook of Computational Economics, Chap. 18, vol. 2, pp. 895–947. Elsevier, Amsterdam (2006). doi:10.1016/S1574-0021(05)02018-6

    Google Scholar 

  9. Camerer, C., Ho, T.H.: Experience-weighted attraction learning in coordination games: probability rules, heterogeneity, and time-variation. J. Math. Psychol. 42(2–3), 305–326 (1998). doi:10.1006/jmps.1998.1217

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Camerer, C., Ho, T.H.: Experienced-weighted attraction learning in normal form games. Econometrica 67(4), 827–874 (1999)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Chung, F., Lu, L.: Complex Graphs and Networks. Regional Conference Series in Mathematics, vol. 107. American Mathematical Society, Providence (2006)

    Google Scholar 

  12. Colman, A.M.: A Dictionary of Psychology, 4th edn. Oxford University Press, Oxford (2015)

    Google Scholar 

  13. Comer, K.W.: Who goes first? An examination of the impact of activation on outcome behaviour in agent-based models. Ph.D. thesis, George Mason University (2014)

    Google Scholar 

  14. Comer, K.W., Loerch, A.G.: The impact of agent activation on population behavior in an agent-based model of civil revolt. Procedia Comput. Sci. 20, 183–188 (2013). doi:10.1016/j.procs.2013.09.258

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Currarini, S., Jackson, M.O., Pin, P.: An economic model of friendship: homophily, minorities, and segregation. Econometrica 77(4), 1003–1045 (2009). doi:10.3982/ECTA7528

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. Dawid, H., Gemkow, S.: How do social networks contribute to wage inequality? Insights from an agent-based analysis. Ind. Corp. Change 23(5), 1171–1200 (2014). doi:10.1093/icc/dtt049

    Google Scholar 

  17. Dawid, H., Gemkow, S., Harting, P., Kabus, K., Wersching, K., Neugart, M.: Skills, innovation, and growth: an agent-based policy analysis. J. Econ. Stat. 228(2–3), 251–275 (2008)

    Google Scholar 

  18. Dawid, H., Gemkow, S., Harting, P., Neugart, M.: On the effects of skill upgrading in the presence of spatial labor market frictions: an agent-based analysis of spatial policy design. J. Artif. Soc. Soc. Simul. 12(4), 5 (2009)

    Google Scholar 

  19. Dawid, H., Gemkow, S., Harting, P., van der Hoog, S., Neugart, M.: The Eurace@ Unibi model: an agent-based macroeconomic model for economic policy analysis. Working papers in Economics and Management 05-2012, Bielefeld University (2012)

    Google Scholar 

  20. Dawid, H., Gemkow, S., Harting, P., Neugart, M.: Labor market integration policies and the convergence of regions: the role of skills and technology diffusion. J. Evol. Econ. 22(3), 543–562 (2012). doi:10.1007/s00191-011-0245-1

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. Dawid, H., Harting, P., Neugart, M.: Spatial labor market frictions and economic convergence: policy implications from a heterogeneous agent model. Working papers in Economics and Management 09-2013, Bielefeld University (2013)

    Google Scholar 

  22. Deissenberg, C., van der Hoog, S., Dawid, H.: EURACE: a massively parallel agent-based model of the European economy. Appl. Math. Comput. 204(2), 541–552 (2008). doi:10.1016/j.amc.2008.05.116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  23. Dorogovtsev, S.N., Mendes, J.F.F.: Evolution of networks. Adv. Phys. 51(4), 1079–1187 (2002). doi:10.1080/00018730110112519

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. Dosi, G., Fagiolo, G., Napoletano, M., Roventini, A.: Income distribution, credit and fiscal policies in an agent-based Keynesian model. J. Econ. Dyn. Control 37(8), 1598–1625 (2013). doi:10.1016/j.jedc.2012.11.008

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. Fagiolo, G., Dosi, G., Gabriele, R.: Matching, bargaining, and wage setting in an evolutionary model of labor market and output dynamics. Adv. Complex Syst. 7(2), 157–186 (2004). doi:10.1142/S0219525904000135

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Gemkow, S., Neugart, M.: Referral hiring, endogenous social networks, and inequality: an agent-based analysis. J. Evol. Econ. 21(4), 703–719 (2011). doi:10.1007/s00191-011-0219-3

    Article  Google Scholar 

  27. Gu, X., Blackmore, K.L.: A systematic review of agent-based modelling and simulation applications in the higher education domain. High. Educ. Res. Dev. 1–16 (2015). doi:10.1080/07294360.2015.1011088

    Google Scholar 

  28. Harland, K., Heppenstall, A.J.: Using agent-based models for education planning: is the UK education system agent based? In: Heppenstall, A.J., Crooks, A.T., See, L.M., Batty, M. (eds.) Agent-Based Models of Geographical Systems, pp. 481–497. Springer, Dordrecht (2012). doi:10.1007/978-90-481-8927-4_23

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  29. Henrickson, L.: Old wine in a new wineskin: college choice, college access using agent-based modeling. Soc. Sci. Comput. Rev. 20(4), 400–419 (2002). doi:10.1177/089443902237319

    Article  Google Scholar 

  30. Leombruni, R., Richiardi, M.: LABORsim: an agent-based microsimulation of labour supply – an application to Italy. Comput. Econ. 27(1), 63–88 (2006). doi:10.1007/s10614-005-9016-0

    Article  Google Scholar 

  31. Lewkovicz, Z., Thiriot, S., Caillou, P.: How detailed should social networks be for labor market’s models? In: Social Networks and Multiagent Systems Symposium, York (2011)

    Google Scholar 

  32. Maroulis, S., Bakshy, E., Gomez, L., Wilensky, U.: Modeling the transition to public school choice. J. Artif. Soc. Soc. Simul. 17(2), 3 (2014)

    Google Scholar 

  33. Martin, C.W., Neugart, M.: Shocks and endogenous institutions: an agent-based model of labor market performance in turbulent times. Comput. Econ. 33(1), 31–46 (2009). doi:10.1007/s10614-008-9149-z

    Article  Google Scholar 

  34. Moss, S., Edmonds, B.: Sociology and simulation: statistical and qualitative cross-validation. Am. J. Sociol. 110(4), 1095–1131 (2005)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  35. Neugart, M.: Labor market policy evaluation with ACE. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 67(2), 418–430 (2008). doi:10.1016/j.jebo.2006.12.006

    Article  Google Scholar 

  36. Newman, M.E.J.: Networks: An Introduction. Oxford University Press, New York (2010)

    Book  Google Scholar 

  37. Ng, T.S., Kang, Y.C.: The inquiry of labor market dynamics in knowledge economies: an agent-based approach. IEEE Trans. Syst. Man Cybern. Syst. 43(2), 416–427 (2013). doi:10.1109/TSMCA.2012.2195167

    Article  Google Scholar 

  38. Reardon, S.F., Kasman, M., Klasik, D., Baker, R.: Agent-based simulation models of the college sorting process. Working paper, Center for Education Policy Analysis, Stanford University (2014)

    Google Scholar 

  39. Riccetti, L., Russo, A., Gallegati, M.: An agent based decentralized matching macroeconomic model. J. Econ. Interac. Coord. 1–28 (2014). doi:10.1007/s11403-014-0130-8

    Google Scholar 

  40. Richiardi, M.: Toward a non-equilibrium unemployment theory. Comput. Econ. 27(1), 135–160 (2006). doi:10.1007/s10614-005-9019-x

    Article  Google Scholar 

  41. Silva, S.T., Valente, J.M., Teixeira, A.A.: An evolutionary model of industry dynamics and firms’ institutional behavior with job search, bargaining and matching. J. Econ. Interac. Coord. 7(1), 23–61 (2012). doi:10.1007/s11403-011-0085-y

    Article  Google Scholar 

  42. Simon, H.A.: Models of Man, Social and Rational: Mathematical Essays on Rational Human Behavior in a Social Setting. Wiley, New York (1957)

    Google Scholar 

  43. Takács, K., Squazzoni, F., Bravo, G.: The network antidote: an agent-based model of discrimination in labor markets. In: MKE 2012 Conference, Budapest (2012)

    Google Scholar 

  44. Tarvid, A.: Field of study choice and migration: effects of social networks. In: Koch, A., Mandl, P. (eds.) Modeling Social Phenomena in Spatial Context. Geosimulation Series, vol. 2, pp. 125–138. LIT Publisher, Münster (2013)

    Google Scholar 

  45. Tarvid, A.: The effectiveness of access restriction to higher education in decreasing overeducation. Econ. Anal. Policy 45, 11–26 (2015). doi:10.1016/j.eap.2014.12.003

    Article  Google Scholar 

  46. Tarvid, A.: Job satisfaction as a unified mechanism for agent behaviour in a labour market with referral hiring. Int. J. Comput. Econ. Econ. (2016, forthcoming)

    Google Scholar 

  47. Tassier, T., Menczer, F.: Emerging small-world referral networks in evolutionary labor markets. IEEE Trans. Evol. Comput. 5(5), 482–492 (2001). doi:10.1109/4235.956712

    Article  Google Scholar 

  48. Tassier, T., Menczer, F.: Social network structure, segregation, and equality in a labor market with referral hiring. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 66(3–4), 514–528 (2008). doi:10.1016/j.jebo.2006.07.003

    Article  Google Scholar 

  49. Tesfatsion, L.: Structure, behavior, and market power in an evolutionary labor market with adaptive search. J. Econ. Dyn. Control 25(3–4), 419–457 (2001). doi:10.1016/S0165-1889(00)00032-4

    Article  Google Scholar 

  50. Thiriot, S., Lewkovicz, Z., Caillou, P., Kant, J.D.: Referral hiring and labor markets: a computational study. In: Osinga, S., Hofstede, G.J., Verwaart, T. (eds.) Emergent Results of Artificial Economics. Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems, vol. 652, pp. 15–25. Springer, Berlin/Heidelberg (2011). doi:10.1007/978-3-642-21108-9_2

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  51. Van der Hoog, S., Dawid, H.: Bubbles, crashes and the financial cycle: insights from a stock-flow consistent agent-based macroeconomic model. Working papers in Economics and Management 01-2015, Bielefeld University (2015)

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Tarvid, A. (2016). Using Agent-Based Modelling in Studying Labour–Education Market System. In: Agent-Based Modelling of Social Networks in Labour–Education Market System. SpringerBriefs in Complexity. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-26539-1_3

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics