Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Understanding the Short Run Relationship Between Stock Market and Growth in Emerging Economies

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Journal of Quantitative Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Contemporaneous correlation coefficients between per capita growth and market capitalization to GDP ratio calculated for 35 countries reveal highest correlations for emerging economies. The paper explains this phenomenon in an extended Lucas (Econmetrica 46(6):1429–1445, 1978) asset pricing model with production, accumulation and growth with two separately added additional features, international borrowing by domestic firms and holding of domestic shares by foreign agents. It is shown that in the first scenario, growth enhancing productivity shock increases market capitalization ratio in the short run and in the second, a positive demand shock increases short run growth. The model is calibrated using quarterly Indian data.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Data Source: World Development Indicators (www.data.worldbank.org).

  2. In Table 1, *, ** and *** denote significance levels at 10%, 5% and 1% respectively.

  3. Implicitly the production function is \(y_t = \epsilon _t k_t l_t\), where \(l_t =1 \forall t\), that is, there is no labour-leisure choice and labour is supplied by the households inelastically at the unit level in each period.

  4. Output being a flow obtained through out the period is very costly to observe,but capital, being a stock, can be observed in one go.

  5. \(k_{t+1} = (1-\delta )k_t +i_t\) where the current capital stock and the realized values of the shocks are publicly known at the beginning of period t.

  6. This implicitly assumes that there is no recovery cost incurred by the lender.

  7. See “Appendix B”.

  8. Detailed derivations are relegated to the Appendix C.

  9. Data Source for Calibration: Reserve Bank of India.

  10. The model is initially calibrated using quarterly data. But then impulse responses based on quarterly Indian data are converted to annual levels, so that the behaviours of the relevant variables can be compared with the pattern that emerged from the worldwide annual dataset. This is also done while calibrating the model discussed in the next section.

  11. Although I deal with a serially correlated shocks while investigating the short run dynamics, I assume that each period the borrowing constraint binding restriction on the world interest rate must be valid, such that the firm remains a net borrower in each period. For this reason, as mentioned earlier, I consider only admissible ranges of the values of the TFP shock for which the restriction on the world interest rate holds true in each period for which the borrowing constrained equilibrium is valid throughout the entire short run time path of the firm.

  12. For \(\mu \) equal to 0.4, the correlation takes the value 0.56, for \(\mu \) equal to 0.5 it takes the value 0.44, for \(\mu \) equal to 0.6 it takes the value 0.38, for \(\mu \) equal to 0.7 it takes the value 0.36, for \(\mu \) equal to 0.8 it takes the value 0.30 and so on.

References

  • Bencivenga, V.R., and B.D. Smith. 1991. Financial intermediation and endogenous growth. The Review of Economic Studies 58 (2): 195–209.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bencivenga, Valerie R., Bruce D. Smith, and Ross M. Starr. 1995. Equity markets, transaction costs and capital accumulation. Policy Research Working Paper Series 1456, The World Bank.

  • Gorton, G., and G. Pennacchi. 1990. Financial intermediaries and liquidity creation. Journal of Finance 45 (1): 49–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harris, R.D.F. 1997. Stock markets and development: A re-assessment. European Economic Review 41 (1): 139–146.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J. 1969. A theory of economic history. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jacklin, C.J. 1987. Demand deposits, trading restrictions, and risk sharing. In Contractual arrangements for international trade, ed. E. Prescott, and N. Wallace, 26–47. Minneapolis, MN: University of Minnesota Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Japelli, T., and M. Pagano. 1994. Saving, growth, and liquidity constraints. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 109 (1): 83–109.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Khan, H., and J. Tsoukalas. 2013. The quantitative importance of news shocks in estimated DSGE models. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 44 (8): 1535–1561.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • King, G., and R. Levine. 1993. Finance and growth: schumpeter might be right. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 108 (3): 717–737.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levine, R. 1991. Stock markets, growth and tax policy. The Journal of Finance 46 (4): 1445–1465.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levine, R., and S. Zervos. 1996. Stock market development and long run growth. The World Bank Economic Review 10 (3): 323–339.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas Jr., R.E. 1978. Asset prices in an exchange economy. Econometrica 46 (6): 1429–1445.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nolan, C., and C. Thoenissen. 2009. Financial shocks and the US business cycles. Journal of Monetary Economics 56 (4): 596–604.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sarkar, A. 2016. Dynamic general equilibrium analysis of stock market behaviour in a growing economy. Doctoral Thesis, University of Durham.

  • Sarkar, A. 2018. Market capitalization and growth in a new Keynesian framework, Working Paper, IIT Guwahati.

  • Schumpeter, J. A. 1934 (1912). The theory of economic development. Trans. Redvers Opie. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

  • Smets, F., and R. Wouters. 2003. An estimated dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model of the Euro area. Journal of the European Economic Association. 1: 1123–1175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Agnirup Sarkar.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

The author wishes to thank, without implicating, two anonymous referees for helpful comments.

Appendices

A Household’s Optimization Conditions

The objective function of the household can be written as

$$\begin{aligned}&Max:E_{0}\sum _{t=0}^{\infty }\beta ^{t}u(c_{t}) \end{aligned}$$
(34)
$$\begin{aligned}&s.t.:\int _{0}^{1}p_{t}^{z}(i)\left( z_{t+1}(i)-z_{t}(i)\right) di+c_{t}=\int _{0}^{1}d_{t}(i)z_{t}(i)di \end{aligned}$$
(35)

as in (5) and (6).

The Lagrange function is formed as:

$$\begin{aligned} N_{t}= & {} \sum _{t=0}^{\infty }\beta ^{t}u(c_{t})+\omega _{t}\left[ \int _{0}^{1}d_{t}(i)z_{t}(i)di-\int _{0}^{1}p_{t}^{z}(i)\left[ z_{t+1}(i)-z_{t}(i)\right] -c_{t}\right] \nonumber \\&+\omega _{t+1}\left[ \int _{0}^{1}d_{t+1}(i)z_{t+1}(i)di \right. \nonumber \\&\left. -\int _{0}^{1}p_{t+1}^{z}(i)\left[ z_{t+2}(i)-z_{t+1}(i)\right] di-c_{t+1}\right] \end{aligned}$$
(36)

where \(\omega _{t}\) is the Lagrange Multiplier for period t.

Since households and firms are all identical, the i subscript can be ignored. Choice variables for the household are \(c_{t}\) and \(z_{t+1}\).

First Order Condition with respect to \(c_{t}\) gives

$$\begin{aligned} \omega _{t}=\beta ^{t}u'(c_{t}) \end{aligned}$$
(37)

First Order Condition with respect to \(z_{t+1}\) gives

$$\begin{aligned} \omega _{t}p_{t}^{z}=\omega _{t+1}[d_{t+1}+p_{t+1}^{z}] \end{aligned}$$
(38)

Combining the two First Order Conditions I get

$$\begin{aligned} u^{\prime }(c_{t})p_{t}^{z}=\beta E_{t}u^{\prime }(c_{t+1})\left( d_{t+1}+p_{t+1}^{z}\right) \end{aligned}$$
(39)

which is Eq. (8) in Section 2.

B Expression for Asset Price

In equilibrium,

$$\begin{aligned} c_{t}=d_{t} \end{aligned}$$

This is in line with Lucas (1978). Taking into account this assumption as well as the assumption of a logarithmic utility function, i.e. \(u(c_{t})=\ln c_{t}\), the stock Euler equation in (8) becomes

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{p_{t}^{z}}{c_{t}}= & {} \beta E_{t}\left( \frac{c_{t+1}+p_{t+1}^{z}}{ c_{t+1}}\right) \end{aligned}$$
(40)
$$\begin{aligned}= & {} \beta \left[ 1+E_{t}\left( \frac{p_{t+1}^{z}}{c_{t+1}}\right) \right] \nonumber \\= & {} \beta \left[ 1+\beta \left\{ 1+E_{t}\left( \frac{p_{t+2}^{z}}{c_{t+2}} \right) \right\} \right] \nonumber \\= & {} \beta \left[ 1+\beta +\beta ^{2}+\cdots +E_{t}\left\{ \lim _{n\rightarrow \infty }\beta ^{n-1}\left( \frac{p_{t+n}^{z}}{c_{t+n}}\right) \right\} \right] \nonumber \\= & {} \frac{\beta }{1-\beta }+\beta E_{t}\left\{ \lim _{n\rightarrow \infty }\beta ^{n-1}\left( \frac{p_{t+n}^{z}}{c_{t+n}}\right) \right\} \end{aligned}$$
(41)

If the asset price is bounded (i.e. it cannot go to a value such that it would cost more than the household’s total income to buy a single asset), it is straight forward to see that the limit term in Eq. (8) goes to zero. This means that the equilibrium asset price becomes

$$\begin{aligned} p_{t}^{z}=\frac{\beta }{1-\beta }c_{t} \end{aligned}$$
(42)

Market Capitalization Ratio and Per Capita Growth with Borrowing

In the borrowing constrained model, the maximization problem of the firm can be expressed formally as in Eqs. (24) and (25).

In order to solve the above maximization problem, I set up the Lagrange function as in Eq. (26).

At time t, the choice variables of the firm are its investment \(k_{t+1}\) and the amount it decides to borrow i.e. \(b_{t}\).

The first order conditions to the Lagrangian problem with respect to \(k_{t+1} \) and \(b_{t}\) implies

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\lambda _{t}}{r^{\prime }}-1+m_{t,t+1}\left[ \epsilon _{t+1}+\left( 1-\delta \right) \right] =0 \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} 1-\lambda _{t}-E_{t}m_{t,t+1}r^{\prime }=0 \end{aligned}$$

respectively.

Combining these first order conditions by equating \(\lambda _{t}\), I have

$$\begin{aligned}&E_{t}m_{t,t+1}\left[ {\epsilon _{t+1}-\delta }\right] =\left[ 1-\frac{1}{r^{\prime }}\right] \\&\frac{1}{c_{t}}\left[ 1-\frac{1}{r^{\prime }}\right] =\beta E_{t}{c_{t+1}}\left[ \epsilon _{t+1}-\delta \right] \end{aligned}$$

From the equilibrium resource constraint

$$\begin{aligned} \epsilon _{t}k_{t}+b_{t}=c_{t}+\left[ k_{t+1}-(1-\delta )k_{t}\right] +r^{\prime }b_{t-1} \end{aligned}$$
(43)

In the borrowing constrained equilibrium, where \(b_{t}=\frac{k_{t+1}}{ r^{\prime }}\), this resource constraint becomes

$$\begin{aligned} c_{t}+k_{t+1}\left[ 1-\frac{1}{r^{\prime }}\right] =k_{t} \left[ {\epsilon _{t}-\delta } \right] \end{aligned}$$

which can be expressed as

$$\begin{aligned} {\epsilon _{t+1}-\delta }= \frac{c_{t+1}+k_{t+2}\left[ 1-\frac{1}{r^{\prime }} \right] }{k_{t}} \end{aligned}$$
(44)

Using the above relationship from (44) in the equilibrium resource constraint in (43), I have

$$\begin{aligned}&\left. \frac{k_{t+1}}{c_{t}}-\frac{1}{r^{\prime }}\right) =\beta E_{t}\left. \left( 1+\frac{k_{t+2}}{c_{t+1}}- \frac{1}{r^{\prime }}\right) \right) \nonumber \\&\frac{k_{t+1}}{c_{t}}=\frac{\beta }{1-\beta }\left( \frac{1}{ r^{\prime }-1}\right) \end{aligned}$$
(45)

Plugging in the relation from (45) in the equilibrium resource constraint in (43),the borrowing constrained equilibrium consumption \(c_{t}\) and capital accumulation \(k_{t+1}\) can be solved as

$$\begin{aligned} c_{t}=\left( 1-\beta \right) \left( {\epsilon _{t}- -\delta }{\psi _{t}}\right) k_{t} \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} k_{t+1}=\beta \left( \frac{r^{\prime }}{r^{\prime }-1}\right) \left( \epsilon _{t}-\delta \right) k_{t} \end{aligned}$$

The equilibrium market capitalization ratio is given by

$$\begin{aligned} mk_{t}=\frac{p_{t}^{z}}{y_{t}}=\left( \frac{\beta }{1-\beta }\right) \frac{ c_{t}}{y_{t}}=\frac{p_{t}^{z}}{y_{t}}=\beta \left( 1 - \frac{\delta }{\epsilon _t}\right) \end{aligned}$$

which is (23) and the equilibrium output growth is given by

$$\begin{aligned} yg_{t}=\frac{\epsilon _{t}k_{t}}{\epsilon _{t-1}k_{t-1}}=\beta \left( \frac{\epsilon _{t}}{\epsilon _{t-1}}\right) \left( \frac{r^{\prime }}{r^{\prime }-1}\right) \left( \epsilon _{t-1}-\delta \right) \end{aligned}$$

which is (24).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Sarkar, A. Understanding the Short Run Relationship Between Stock Market and Growth in Emerging Economies. J. Quant. Econ. 18, 383–402 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40953-019-00183-x

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40953-019-00183-x

Keywords

Navigation