Skip to main content
Log in

Dynamics of Political Budget Cycle

  • Research Paper
  • Published:
Italian Economic Journal Aims and scope Submit manuscript

A Correction to this article was published on 04 March 2019

This article has been updated

Abstract

The strategic manipulation of fiscal policy in the context of winning elections is a hotly debated issue in economics and political economy. This paper is a theoretical analysis of the manipulation of fiscal policy by an electorally motivated incumbent politician who derives utility from voting support and dis-utility from primary deficit. The incumbent could be one of the following two types: opportunistic or partisan. Using the method of optimal control, the paper derives the equilibrium time paths of both voting support and primary deficit by the incumbent in a dynamic model of finite time horizon under complete information. The level of voting support obtained in case of both types of incumbents is found to be positive and rising over time. Thus, the opportunistic and partisan budgetary cycles follow a similar time pattern, although the cyclicality in case of former is more pronounced than in case of latter in the period closer to the election year. Besides, an opportunistic incumbent is more likely to face rejection when there is sufficiently strong anti-incumbency. Thus, in case of anti-incumbency with opportunism, primary deficit and voting support fall over time. An opportunistic incumbent is also likely to find it costlier to run a primary deficit higher than a specified threshold level than a partisan one. This implies that per unit votes garnered by raising the primary deficit in excess of the threshold level are lower when the incumbent is opportunistic than when she/he is partisan. Numerical simulations corroborate these analytical results.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Change history

  • 04 March 2019

    The original version of this article contained the Appendix. The Appendix has been removed and published online as electronic supplementary material.

Notes

  1. In fact, ‘some’, deficit in the economy is claimed to be good if an economy is spending on productive investment activities. However, a large magnitude of expenditure today entails higher future tax, which voters might not like and, hence, expenditure has to be contained below a certain threshold level. In India, for instance, it has been decided to maintain the aggregate fiscal deficit at 3% of gross domestic product (GDP) under the Fiscal Responsibility and Budget Management Act (FRBM Act-2003).

  2. In this paper, however, the only component that is assumed to be politically manipulated is the primary deficit and not interest payments (Cafiso 2012a, b).

  3. While the FRBM Act was passed in 2003, it started having an impact only a few years later.

  4. The analysis in this paper refers to the primary deficit throughout, where positive and negative values represent primary surplus and primary deficit respectively.

  5. The national level elections refer to either parliamentary or presidential elections depending on whether the country follows a parliamentary or presidential form of government.

  6. This is the time path of the fiscal policy variable (and the associated voting support) that maximizes the pay-off for the incumbent government over an election cycle.

  7. It is stated that, “one candidate may be particularly able (or unable) to cope with a shock in the price of oil, or to enact the effective labor market legislation, or to negotiate with trade unions (Persson and Tabellini 1990. pp. 80).”

  8. The opportunistic behavior of different partisan politicians may be different. Adjusting the party’s standing position toward the ‘middle’ might be the most effective opportunistic policy for a partisan politician.

  9. Visible good refers to public provision of the good that is perceived to provide direct or visible benefits to the citizen-voter—for example, providing solar panels as a public good provision.

  10. Note that, as more and more voting support is rendered to the incumbent, there will be more withdrawal (friction) of the citizen-voters over the electoral term, which may also be due to the presence of an alternative party in the political arena. It is this parameter of friction that captures the notion of anti-incumbency later in the analysis.

  11. The specific conditions on parameters are derived such that they satisfy the thresholds specified in Sect. 3.2. Accordingly, these restrictions are also consistent with the necessary conditions in Eqs. (16) and (17).

  12. Again, the parametric restrictions utilized here are consistent with the necessary conditions in Eqs. (16) and (17).

  13. From eq. (18), the part of the last term \( e^{{ - \frac{\rho }{\epsilon }t + \frac{\alpha - \delta \gamma }{\delta \epsilon }(t - T)}} \) can be written as \( e^{{ - \frac{\rho }{\epsilon }t}} .e^{{\frac{\alpha - \delta \gamma }{\delta \epsilon }(t - T)}} \) where, as \( t \to T \) and small enough \( \epsilon \), we have \( e^{{ - \frac{\rho }{\epsilon }t}} \to 0 \) and \( {{ \frac{\alpha - \delta \gamma }{\delta \epsilon }(t - T)}}\to 1 \).

  14. Here, the line of argument follows the ones in Proposition 2 and 3.

  15. While no explicit thresholds on parameters are required, suffice is to say that the regularity condition in Eq. (16) is met.

References

  • Aidt TS, Veiga FJ, Veiga LG (2011) Election results and opportunistic policies: a new test of the rational political business cycle model. Public Choice 148(1):21–44

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A (1987) Macroeconomic policy in a two-party system as a repeated game. Q J Econ 102(3):651–678

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A (1988) Macroeconomics and politics. NBER Macroecon Ann 3:13–52

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Perotti R (1995a) Fiscal expansions and adjustments in OECD countries. Econ Policy 10(21):205–248

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Perotti R (1995b) The political economy of budget deficits. Staff Papers 42(1):1–31

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Rosenthal H (1995) Partisan politics, divided government, and the economy. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Sachs J (1988) Political parties and the business cycle in the United States, 1948–1984. J Money Credit Bank 20(1):63–82

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Cohen GD, Roubini N (1993) Electoral business cycle in industrial democracies. Eur J Polit Econ 9(1):1–23

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Block SA (2002) Political business cycles, democratization, and economic reform: the case of Africa. J Dev Econ 67(1):205–228

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brender A, Drazen A (2005) Political budget cycles in new versus established democracies. J Monet Econ 52(7):1271–1295

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brender A, Drazen A (2013) Elections, leaders, and the composition of government spending. J Pub Econ 97:18–31

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cafiso G (2012a) Debt developments and fiscal adjustment in the EU. Intereconomics 47(1):61–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cafiso G (2012b) A guide to public debt equations. SSRN Working Paper

  • Chiang A (1992) Elements of dynamic optimization. McGraw-Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Chortareas G, Logothetis V, Papandreou AA (2016) Political budget cycles and reelection prospects in greece’s municipalities. Eur J Polit Econ 43:1–13

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cukierman A, Meltzer AH (1986) A positive theory of discretionary policy, the cost of democratic government and the benefits of a constitution. Econ Inq 24(3):367–388

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drazen A (2000) The political business cycle after 25 years. NBER Macroecon Ann 15:75–117

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drazen A, Eslava M (2010) Electoral manipulation via voter-friendly spending: theory and evidence. J Dev Econ 92(1):39–52

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Election Guide (2018) Year of election. http://www.electionguide.org/elections/past/. Accessed 27 June 2018

  • Fair RC (1978) The effect of economic events on votes for president. Rev Econ Stat 60(2):159–173

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frey BS, Schneider F (1978) An Empirical study of politico–economic interaction in the United States. Rev Econ Stat 65(01):174–183

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hibbs DA (1977) Political parties and macroeconomic policy. Am Polit Sci Rev 71(04):1467–1487

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hibbs DA (1989) The American political economy. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Kalecki M (1943) Political aspects of full employment. Polit Q 14(4):322–330

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klomp J, De Haan J (2013a) Do political budget cycles really exist? Appl Econ 45(3):329–341

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klomp J, De Haan J (2013b) Political budget cycles and election outcomes. Pub Choice 157(1–2):245–267

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kramer GH (1971) Short-term fluctuations in US voting behavior, 1896–1964. Am Polit Sci Rev 65(01):131–143

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindbeck A (1976) Stabilization policy in open economies with endogenous politicians. Am Econ Rev 66(2):1–19

    Google Scholar 

  • IMF Fiscal Monitor-2017 (2018) Primary surplus or deficit. https://www.imf.org/~/media/Files/Publications/fiscal-monitor/2017/October/data/FiscalMonitorDatabaseOct2017.ashx. Accessed 25 June 2018

  • Nordhaus WD (1975) The political business cycle. Rev Econ Stud 42(2):169–190

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson T, Tabellini GE (1990) Macroeconomic policy, credibility and politics. Taylor and Francis, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson T, Tabellini GE (2002) Political economics: explaining economic policy. The MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogoff K (1990) Equilibrium political budget cycles. Am Econ Rev 80(1):21–36

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogoff K, Sibert A (1988) Elections and macroeconomic policy cycles. Rev Econ Stud 55(1):1–16

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schuknecht L (1996) Political business cycles and fiscal policies in developing countries. Kyklos 49(2):155–170

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shi M, Svensson J (2006) Political budget cycles: do they differ across countries and why? J Pub Econ 90(8):1367–1389

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tufte ER (1975) Determinants of the outcomes of mid-term congressional elections. Am Polit Sci Rev 69(03):812–826

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Westen D (2008) The political brain: the role of emotion in deciding the fate of the nation. PublicAffairs, New York

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We would like to thank the participants at the IGC-ISI Summer School Workshop July 12–16, 2014, the Winter School, December 5–17, 2014 at the Delhi of School of Economics, University of Delhi and the conference on ‘Papers in Public Economics and Policy’ at National Institute of Public Finance and Policy (NIPFP), New Delhi, on March 12–13, 2015. We also benefitted by comments from Prof. Chetan Ghate and Prof. Dilip Mookherjee at the IGC-ISI workshop and Dr. Mausumi Das at the Winter School. We are grateful to Dr. Bodhisattva Sengupta and two anonymous referees for their insightful and valuable comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ganesh Manjhi.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (PDF 2442 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Manjhi, G., Mehra, M.K. Dynamics of Political Budget Cycle. Ital Econ J 5, 135–158 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40797-019-00084-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40797-019-00084-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation