Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Enhanced oil recovery as a stepping stone to carbon capture and sequestration

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Mineral Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Environmental concerns about carbon emissions coupled with the oil industry’s need to secure additional CO2 for enhanced oil recovery (CO2-EOR) projects have sparked interest in the potential that CO2-EOR may have in jumpstarting carbon capture and sequestration (CCS). However, existing studies on the viability of coupling CO2-EOR with CCS have generally placed more focus on either the engineering or economic aspects of the problem. Most engineering studies focus on the technical aspects of the CO2-EOR project to produce the maximum amount of oil, while simultaneously storing the most CO2 during the production process with the economics as an afterthought, while most economic studies found have focused on a singular aspect of the issue such as impacts of exogenously varying injection rates. Furthermore, modelling efforts have stopped at the end of the productive life of the field. We build a unique two-stage dynamic optimization model, which simultaneously addresses engineering and economic policy aspects, to study the viability of coupling CO2-EOR transitioning into CCS. Our model includes a carbon tax for emissions, which becomes a subsidy for full scale sequestration after oil production has ceased; this allows us to explore the transition from CO2-EOR, our first stage, to sole CO2 sequestration in our second stage for a single field. We maximize the operator’s profits across both stages, while tracking the responsiveness of oil production and total carbon movements to both price and policy changes. We pair our optimization model with a reservoir simulation model, allowing us to mimic actual field behavior, giving our work a more realistic representation of both production and sequestration profiles. Our results suggest that small increases in the level of carbon tax can have large and discontinuous impacts on net sequestration. This stems from the observed transition from limited natural sources of CO2 to more expensive captured CO2 resulting from the implemented policy. With appropriate taxes, total volumes of captured CO2 sequestered across both stages are equivalent to 30 to 40% of the emissions from the use of the oil produced. With the credits oil producers receive from sequestering CO2, which equate to the tax, relatively high carbon taxes incentivize additional sequestration without significantly impacting the supply of oil. This, alongside maintaining a steady stream of profits, is a win-win situation for energy security and the climate.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. CO2 behaves like a fluid at reservoir temperatures and pressures (Leach et al. 2011).

References

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Dana M. Abdulbaqi.

Additional information

We thank Editor Magnus Ericsson for the invitation to contribute to this special issue and to the anonymous referee for valuable comments that substantially helped us clarify our exposition in the paper. The views in this paper are solely those of the authors and do not reflect the views of Saudi Aramco, the Colorado School of Mines, or Luleo Technical University.

The authors of this article are pleased to pay tribute to Dr. Marian Radeztki, an icon in the field of Mineral Economics. As homo economicus, we humans have learned to rip and suck mineral and energy resources from the Earth to make our lives more productive and comfortable. Marian has spent a lifetime studying this process. His wit and sarcastic turn of phrase, his institutional and technical knowledge, and his well-reasoned and supported arguments entertain and enlighten us about how these resource markets work. With each bout of “We are running out.” Marian, ever the myth buster, responds with “No—we aren’t.” We thank him for his past insights and wish him many more years of being right.

Appendix: Model Setup and Optimality Conditions

Appendix: Model Setup and Optimality Conditions

The ordinary control theory formulation does not consider dynamic problems with more than a single optimization phase. The challenge arises in our two-stage setup in the selection of the transition point from one stage to the next, in addition to the selection of the optimal paths for the control and state variables in each stage of the optimization. We now present the setup and optimality conditions of our two-stage model that considers a price-taking producer that seeks to maximize the present value of profits with respect to a policy that could potentially make sole sequestration profitable. Our first integral in the objective function represents profits from CO2-EOR, while the second represents profits generated by CCS. We assume that the transition from one stage to the next does not require any additional capital cost outside of shutting in producing wells. Our objective function (Eq. 11 from the text), associated constraints, and optimality or first-order conditions are listed below:

Objective function:

$$ \max \pi ={\int}_0^{T_1}{e}^{- rt}\left(\left[{p}_o-\beta \tau \right]{q}_p^o(t)-{w}_{CAP}{q}_{CAP}^c(t)-\left({w}_{NR}+\tau \right){q}_{NR}^c(t)-{w}_R{q}_R^c(t)+\tau {q}_S^c(t)-{F}_1\right) dt+{\int}_{T_1}^{T_2}{e}^{- rt}\left(\tau {q}_S^c(t)-{w}_{INJ}{q}_i^c(t)-{F}_2\right) dt $$

Substituting in the relationships between oil production and CO2 injection and sequestration yields:

$$ \mathit{\max}\pi ={\int}_0^{T_1}{e}^{- rt}\left(\left[{p}_o-\beta \tau \right]\delta \left({q}_i^c(t)\right)R(t)-{w}_{CAP}{q}_{CAP}^c(t)-\left({w}_{NR}+\tau \right)\left({q}_i^c(t)\delta \left({q}_i^c(t)\right)R(t)-{q}_{CAP}^c(t)\right)-{w}_R\left({q}_i^c(t)-{q}_i^c(t)\delta \left({q}_i^c(t)\right)R(t)\right)+\tau {q}_i^c(t)\delta \left({q}_i^c(t)\right)R(t)-{F}_1\right) dt+{\int}_{T_1}^{T_2}{e}^{- rt}\left(\tau {q}_i^c(t)-{w}_{INJ}{q}_i^c(t)-{F}_2\right) dt $$
(12)

Subject to the following constraints that will differ across each stage:

$$ 0\le t\le {T}_1 $$
$$ \dot{R(t)}=-{q}_p^o(t)=-\delta \left({q}_i^c(t)\right)R(t) $$
(13)
$$ \dot{X(t)}=-{q}_{NR}^c(t)=-\left({q}_s^c(t)-{q}_{CAP}^c(t)\right)={q}_{CAP}^c(t)-{q}_i^c(t)\delta \left({q}_i^c(t)\right)R(t) $$
(14)
$$ \dot{S(t)}={q}_s^c(t)={q}_i^c(t)\delta \left({q}_i^c(t)\right)R(t) $$
(15)
$$ R(0)=1\ \mathrm{million}\ \mathrm{rb}\ \mathrm{of}\ \mathrm{oil}\&R\left({T}_1\right)\ge 0 $$
(16)
$$ X(0)=1\ \mathrm{million}\ \mathrm{rb}\ \mathrm{of}\ {\mathrm{CO}}_2\&X\left({T}_1\right)\ge 0 $$
(17)
$$ S(0)=0\ \mathrm{million}\ \mathrm{rb}\ \mathrm{of}\ {\mathrm{CO}}_2\kern0.5em \&S\left({T}_1\right)\ge 0 $$
(18)
$$ 0\le {q}_i^c(t)\le 1\ \mathrm{million}\ \mathrm{reservoir}\ \mathrm{barrels}/\mathrm{year} $$
(19)

Transversality conditions for our first stage:

$$ {H}_1\left({T}_1\right)=0 $$
(20)
$$ {\lambda}^R\left({T}_1\right)\ge 0\kern0.5em R\left({T}_1\right)\ge 0\kern0.5em {\lambda}^R\left({T}_1\right)\times R\left({T}_1\right)=0 $$
(21)
$$ {\lambda}^X\left({T}_1\right)\ge 0\kern0.5em X\left({T}_1\right)\ge 0\kern0.5em {\lambda}^X\left({T}_1\right)\times X\left({T}_1\right)=0 $$
(22)
$$ {\lambda}^S\left({T}_1\right)\ge 0\kern0.5em S\left({T}_1\right)\ge 0\kern0.5em {\lambda}^S\left({T}_1\right)\times S\left({T}_1\right)=0 $$
(23)

Moving to our second stage:

$$ {T}_1\le t\le {T}_2 $$
$$ \dot{S(t)}={q}_s^c\left({q}_i^c(t)\right)={q}_i^c(t) $$
(24)
$$ S\left({T}_1\right)=S\left({T}_1\right)\ \mathrm{from}\ \mathrm{stage}\ 1\kern0.5em \&S\left({T}_2\right)\le S\left({T}_1\right)+1.2\times {\int}_0^{T_1}\left({q}_p^o(t)\right) dt $$
(25)
$$ 0\le {q}_i^c(t)\le 1\ \mathrm{million}\ \mathrm{reservoir}\ \mathrm{barrels}/\mathrm{year} $$
(26)

The upper bound on sequestration for S(T2) in Eq. 25 serves as our terminal conditions with free terminal time (T2) and eliminates the need to identify transversality conditions for our second stage. This upper bound on sequestration also provides the link between the first and second stage of the model.

Modelling stage 1

$$ 0\le t\le {T}_1 $$

The current value Hamiltonian for period 1 is as follows:

$$ {H}_1(t)=\left[{p}_o-\beta \tau \right]\delta \left({q}_i^c(t)\right)R(t)-{w}_{CAP}{q}_{CAP}^c(t)-\left({w}_{NR}+\tau \right)\left({q}_i^c(t)\delta \left({q}_i^c(t)\right)R(t)-{q}_{CAP}^c(t)\right)-{w}_R\left({q}_i^c(t)-{q}_i^c(t)\delta \left({q}_i^c(t)\right)R(t)\right)+\tau {q}_i^c(t)\delta \left({q}_i^c(t)\right)R(t)-{F}_1-{\lambda}^R\left(\mathrm{t}\right)\delta \left({q}_i^c(t)\right)R(t)+{\lambda}^X(t){q}_{CAP}^c(t)-{\lambda}^X(t){q}_i^c(t)\delta \left({q}_i^c(t)\right)R(t)+{\lambda}^S(t){q}_i^c(t)\delta \left({q}_i^c(t)\right)R(t) $$
(27)

Optimality conditions for stage 1

$$ \frac{\partial {H}_1(t)}{\partial {q}_i^c(t)}=\left[p-\beta \tau \right]{\delta}^{\prime}\left({q}_i^c(t)\right)R(t)-\left({w}_{NR}+\tau \right){q}_i^c(t){\delta}^{\prime}\left({q}_i^c(t)\right)R(t)-\left({w}_{NR}+\tau \right)\delta \left({q}_i^c(t)\right)R(t)-{w}_r+{w}_r{q}_i^c(t){\delta}^{\prime}\left({q}_i^c(t)\right)R(t)+{w}_r\delta \left({q}_i^c(t)\right)R(t)+\tau {q}_i^c(t){\delta}^{\prime}\left({q}_i^c(t)\right)R(t)+\tau \delta \left({q}_i^c(t)\right)R(t)-{\delta}^{\prime}\left({q}_i^c(t)\right)R(t)-{\lambda}^X(t){q}_i^c(t){\delta}^{\prime}\left({q}_i^c(t)\right)R(t)-{\lambda}^X(t)\delta \left({q}_i^c(t)\right)R(t)+{\lambda}^S(t){q}_i^c(t){\delta}^{\prime}\left({q}_i^c(t)\right)R(t)+{\lambda}^S(t)\delta \left({q}_i^c(t)\right)R(t)=0 $$
(28)

with

$$ {\delta}^{\hbox{'}}\left({q}_i^c(t)\right)=\frac{\partial \left({\delta}_w+{\delta}_1{q}_i^c(t)-{\delta}_2{q}_i^c{(t)}^2\right)}{\partial {q}_i^c}={\delta}_1(t)-2{\delta}_2(t){q}_i^c $$
(29)
$$ \frac{\partial {H}_1(t)}{\partial {q}_{CAP}^c(t)}=-{w}_{CAP}+\left({w}_{NR}+\tau \right)+{\lambda}^X(t)=0 $$
(30)
$$ \dot{R(t)}=\frac{\partial {H}_1(t)}{\partial {\lambda}^R(t)}=-\delta \left({q}_i^c(t)\right)R(t) $$
(31)
$$ \dot{X(t)}=\frac{\partial {H}_1(t)}{\partial {\lambda}^X(t)}={q}_{CAP}^c(t)-{q}_i^c(t)\delta \left({q}_i^c(t)\right)R(t) $$
(32)
$$ \dot{S(t)}=\frac{\partial {H}_1(t)}{\partial {\lambda}^S(t)}={q}_i^c(t)\delta \left({q}_i^c(t)\right)R(t) $$
(33)
$$ \dot{\lambda^R(t)}=-\frac{\partial {H}_1(t)}{\partial R(t)}+r{\lambda}^R(t) $$
(34)

Substituting in for \( \frac{\partial {H}_1(t)}{\partial R(t)} \), we get the following:

$$ \dot{\lambda^R(t)}=r{\lambda}^R(t)-\left[\left(p-\beta \tau \right)-\left({w}_{NR}+\tau \right){q}_i^c(t)+{w}_r{q}_i^c(t)-{\lambda}^R(t)-{\lambda}^X(t){q}_i^c(t)+{\lambda}^S(t){q}_i^c(t)\right]\delta \left({q}_i^c(t)\right) $$
(35)

The above expression suggests that the user cost for oil is a complicated expression depending on the interactions of price, tax, CO2 injection, and the shadow values of the other constraint. Our simulations show that the user cost falls.

For our natural CO2, its shadow value follows:

$$ \dot{\lambda^X(t)}=-\frac{\partial {H}_1(t)}{\partial X(t)}+r{\lambda}^X(t)=r{\lambda}^X(t)\overset{\mathrm{yields}}{\to }\ {\lambda}^X(t)={\lambda}^X(0){e}^{rt} $$
(36)

We will see a growth in the shadow value of our natural CO2 stock until it reaches the switch point to captured sources. The switch point to captured sources occurs at the difference in price between both sources. As such, we will see a growth in λX(t) at the rate of r until it reaches a value equal to the difference in price of both captured and natural sources of CO2 (λX(0)erT = w CAP  − (w NR  + τ)). After this point, λX(t) will remain constant as we no longer make use of natural CO2 and make sole use of CO2 from captured sources. Captured sources can be viewed as a backstop technology. Since our prices and costs are held constant, we will observe our shadow price rise to the value that induces a switch from one source to the next.

Similarly, the shadow price for sequestration is as follows:

$$ \dot{\lambda^S(t)}=-\frac{\partial {H}_1}{\partial S(t)}+r{\lambda}^S(t)=r{\lambda}^S(t)\overset{\mathrm{yields}}{\to}\kern0.5em {\lambda}^S(t)={\lambda}^S(0){e}^{rt} $$
(37)

We will see a growth in the shadow value of our sequestration capacity until it equals the marginal cost of sequestration in our second stage.

Modelling stage 2

$$ {T}_1\le t\le {T}_2 $$

The current value Hamiltonian for period 2 is as follows:

$$ {H}_2(t)=\tau {q}_i^c(t)-{w}_{INJ}{q}_i^c(t)-{F}_2+{\lambda}^{S2}(t){q}_i^c(t) $$
(38)

Optimality conditions for stage 2

$$ \frac{\partial {H}_2(t)}{\partial {q}_i^c(t)}=\tau -{w}_{INJ}+{\lambda}^{S2}(t)=0 $$
(39)
$$ \dot{S(t)}=\frac{\partial {H}_2(t)}{\partial {\lambda}^{S2}(t)}={q}_i^c(t) $$
(40)
$$ \dot{\lambda^{S2}(t)}=-\frac{\partial H}{\partial S(t)}+r{\lambda}^{S2}(t)=r{\lambda}^{S2}(t)\overset{\mathrm{yields}}{\to}\kern0.5em {\lambda}^{S2}(t)={\lambda}^{S2}(0){e}^{rt} $$
(41)

The marginal cost of sequestration at the beginning of our second stage is \( {\lambda}^{S_2}(0){e}^{rt}={w}_{INJ}-\tau \). This value grows as pore space increases until we hit the capacity constraint of the reservoir.

The complementarity model includes Eqs. 28 and 30 and discretized versions of Eqs. 3133 and 3537 for stage 1 and Eq. 39 and discretized versions of Eqs. 40 and 41 for stage 2.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Abdulbaqi, D.M., Dahl, C.A. & AlShaikh, M.R. Enhanced oil recovery as a stepping stone to carbon capture and sequestration. Miner Econ 31, 239–251 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s13563-018-0151-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s13563-018-0151-1

Keywords

Navigation