Skip to main content
Log in

Riskiness in gambles that belong to the same location-scale family and with well-defined means and variances

  • Published:
Mathematics and Financial Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper investigates the orderings of gambles with well-defined means and variances that belong to the same location-scale family under: (i) the index of riskiness analyzed by Aumann and Serrano (AS) and (ii) the measure of riskiness proposed by Foster and Hart (FH). For both measures we study the characteristics and properties of the representation on the (mean, variance) plane of the curves that include gambles with the same level of riskiness. Our analysis applies to gambles with truncated normal distributions and beta distributions. We also discuss the relationships between different riskiness measures derived from the AS and FH measures.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. As it is explained in Sect. 4 beta distributions contain a lot of continuous distributions with bounded outcomes.

  2. See the acknowledgements on initial developments and application of \(R^{AS}\) in footnote on page 810 of \(\left[ AS\right] \).

  3. See footnote 16 of \(\left[ AS\right] \).

  4. By relaxing the third condition for existence of \(R^{AS}\) included in \(\left[ AS\right] \), Schulze [10] is able to extend applicability of \(R^{AS}\) to several types of gamble with continuous distributions and to compute \(R^{AS}\) for many of those gambles.

  5. Schulze [11] introduces a class of risk measures, the dual risk measures, that order gambles in the same way; he points out that \(R^{AS}\) is one of those measures. Another dual risk measure is the measure \((e^{-\frac{1}{R^{AS}}})^{t}\), with \(t>0\), studied by Schnytzer and Westreich [9].

  6. \(\left[ FH\right] \) make no restrictions on the random variable \(g_{t}\) and no assumptions about the underlying probability distribution on the space of processes from which the process \(\left( g_{t}\right) _{t=0,1,...}\) is drawn.

  7. Foster and Hart [3] provide an axiomatic characterization of \(R^{FH}\).

  8. It is not difficult to get these results from (4).

  9. It is not difficult to get these results from \( {\displaystyle \int } \log (1+\frac{\mu +\sigma x}{V})f(x)dx=0\), where x and f(x) denote, respectively, the outcomes and probability density function of the normalized gamble \(\tilde{X}\) corresponding to the LS family considered.

  10. Beta distributions are useful in numerous different situations. A gamble with beta distribution is obtained from transformations of other gambles and from combinations of gambles that do not have beta distributions. Beta distributions are also used as prior probabilities in Bayesian inference for some distributions, as the binomial distribution. Comprehensive analyses on the theory and applications of beta distributions may be found in [4].

  11. It can be considered that c is the initial investment required in a gamble with uniform distribution and that the worst result in that gamble would be to lose that initial investment.

  12. There is \(\varepsilon \) such that, for \(\sigma \in (0,\varepsilon )\), the iso-\(R^{AS}\)-riskiness \(\frac{1}{1.274}\) is above iso-\(R^{FH}\)-riskiness 1 since from Sections 3.1 and 3.2 it is known that the first derivatives of both iso-R-riskiness curves at the origin are 0 and that the second derivative at the origin of iso-\(R^{AS}\)-riskiness \(\frac{1}{1.274}\) is greater than the second derivative of iso-\(R^{FH}\)-riskiness 1.

References

  1. Aumann, R.J., Serrano, R.: An economic index of riskiness. J. Polit. Econ. 116, 810–836 (2008)

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  2. Foster, D.P., Hart, S.: An operational measure of riskiness. J. Polit. Econ. 117(5), 785–814 (2009)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Foster, D.P., Hart, S.: A wealth requirement axiomatization of riskiness. Theor. Econ. 8, 591–620 (2013)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  4. Gupta, A.K., Nadarajah, S. (eds.): Handbook of Beta-Distributions and Its Applications. Marcel Dekker, New York (2004)

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  5. Hellmann, T., Riedel, F.: A dynamic extension of the Foster–Hart measure of riskiness. J. Math. Econ. 59, 66–70 (2015)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  6. Homm, U., Pigorsch, C.: An operational interpretation and existence of the Aumann–Serrano index of riskiness. Econ. Lett. 114, 265–267 (2012)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  7. Meyer, J.: Two-moment decision models and expected utility maximization. Am. Econ. Rev. 77, 421–430 (1987)

    Google Scholar 

  8. Riedel, F., Hellmann, T.: The Foster–Hart measure of riskiness for general gambles. Theor. Econ. 10(1), 1–9 (2015)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  9. Schnytzer, A., Westreich, S.: A global index of riskiness. Econ. Lett. 118, 493–496 (2013)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  10. Schulze, K.: Existence and computation of the Aumann–Serrano index of riskiness and its extension. J. Math. Econ. 50(1), 219–224 (2014a)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  11. Schulze, K.: General dual measures of riskiness. Theor. Decis. 78(2), 289–304 (2014b)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to José M. Usategui.

Additional information

The authors thank an anonymous referee for helpful comments and suggestions. Financial support from Spain’s Ministerio de Economía y Competitividad and FEDER, UE (ECO2015-64467-R) and from the Departamento de Educación, Universidades e Investigación, Gobierno Vasco (IT-783-13) is gratefully acknowledged.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Proof of Proposition 1

i) The S-curve goes through the origin since the origin may be considered as a gamble with maximum loss of 0 and a riskiness of 0. Now consider that g is in the S-curve: \(E\left[ \log \left( 1+\frac{g}{L(g)}\right) \right] =0\). Gamble h such that \(\mu _{h}=\mu _{g}+\gamma \), with \(0<\gamma <L(g)\), and \(\sigma _{h}=\sigma _{g}\) is above gamble g on the (\(\mu ,\sigma \)) plane. Moreover, as \(h=g+\gamma \) and \(L(h)=L(g)-\gamma >0\) it emerges that \(E\left[ \ln \left( 1+\frac{h}{L(h)}\right) \right] =E\left[ \log \left( 1+\frac{g+\gamma }{L(g)-\gamma }\right) \right] >E\left[ \log \left( 1+\frac{g}{L(g)}\right) \right] =0\). By contrast, if \(\gamma <0\) and \(-\gamma <\mu _{g}\) then \(E\left[ \ln \left( 1+\frac{h}{L(h)}\right) \right] <0\). To get a gamble on the S-curve with a mean equal to \(\mu _{h}\) a gamble j with standard deviation other than \(\sigma _{h}\) is required, that is, a gamble j such that \(\mu _{j}=\mu _{h}=\mu _{g}+\gamma \) and \(\sigma _{j}=\delta \sigma _{h}=\delta \sigma _{g}\), with \(\delta \ne 1\). In that case \(j=\delta h+(1-\delta )\mu _{h}\), \(L(j)=\delta L(h)-(1-\delta )\mu _{h}\) and it follows that:

$$\begin{aligned} E\left[ \log \left( 1+\frac{j}{L(j)}\right) \right] =E\left[ \log \left( 1+\frac{\delta h+(1-\delta )\mu _{h}}{\delta L(h)-(1-\delta )\mu _{h}}\right) \right] \end{aligned}$$
(8)

The expression in (8) is higher than \(E\left[ \log \left( 1+\frac{h}{L(h)}\right) \right] \) if \(\delta <1\) and lower than \(E\left[ \log \left( 1+\frac{h}{L(h)}\right) \right] \) if \(\delta >1\). Gamble j will also belong to the S-curve if and only if \(\delta =\delta (\gamma )\) with \(\delta (\gamma )\) such that:

$$\begin{aligned}&E\left[ \log \left( 1+\frac{\delta (\gamma )h+(1-\delta (\gamma ))\mu _{h}}{\delta (\gamma )L(h)-(1-\delta (\gamma ))\mu _{h}}\right) \right] =E\left[ \log \left( 1+\frac{\delta (\gamma )(g+\gamma )+(1-\delta (\gamma ))(\mu _{g} +\gamma )}{\delta (\gamma )(L(g)-\gamma )-(1-\delta (\gamma ))(\mu _{g}+\gamma )}\right) \right] \nonumber \\&\quad =E\left[ \log \left( 1+\frac{\delta (\gamma )g+\gamma +(1-\delta (\gamma ))\mu _{g}}{\delta (\gamma )L(g)-\gamma -(1-\delta (\gamma ))\mu _{g}}\right) \right] =0\text {.} \end{aligned}$$
(9)

The set of gambles belonging to the S-curve is obtained in this case from the set of values of \(\gamma \) and \(\delta (\gamma )\) such that \(-\mu _{g}<\gamma <\delta (\gamma )L(g)-(1-\delta (\gamma ))\mu _{g}\) and (9) is fulfilled. From the foregoing it follows that if \(\gamma >0\) then \(\delta (\gamma )>1\) and if \(\gamma <0\) then \(\delta (\gamma )<1\). As a consequence, the S-curve is increasing.

ii) In i) it is shown that \(E\left[ \log \left( 1+\frac{g}{L(g)}\right) \right] \) decreases when the mean of the gamble decreases and its standard deviation remains unchanged. This implies that part A of iso-\(R^{FH} \)-riskiness V lies on the (\(\mu ,\sigma \)) plane below the S-curve as \(E\left[ \log \left( 1+\frac{g}{L(g)}\right) \right] <0\) for gambles in that part of iso-\(R^{FH}\)-riskiness V. Moreover, part B of iso-\(R^{FH} \)-riskiness V lies on the (\(\mu ,\sigma \)) plane above (and on) the S-curve as \(E\left[ \log \left( 1+\frac{g}{L(g)}\right) \right] \ge 0\) for gambles in that part of iso-\(R^{FH}\)-riskiness V.

iii) The indifference curve through the origin of a decision maker with a logarithmic utility and wealth V runs towards the straight line \(\mu =\tilde{L}\sigma -V\) without reaching that line, because that indifference curve is defined only for gambles with maximum losses lower than V. The point on the straight line \(\mu =\tilde{L}\sigma -V\) that belongs to the frontier of that indifference curve is the intercept point between the S-curve and the straight line \(\mu =\tilde{L}\sigma -V\), as at that point the maximum loss is V and, hence, FH-riskiness is equal to V. That intercept point belongs to part B of iso-\(R^{FH}\)-riskiness V, so it follows that each iso-\(R^{FH}\)-riskiness is continuous on the (\(\mu ,\sigma \)) plane. \(\square \)

1.2 Proof of Proposition 2

From \(\left[ RiH\right] \) it follows that for a beta-distributed gamble g with shape parameters \(\alpha \) and \(\beta \): \(E\left[ \log \left( 1+\frac{g}{L(g)}\right) \right] =0\Leftrightarrow \log (M(g)+L(g))+E\log Z=\log (L(g))\), where Z is the gamble beta-distributed between 0 and 1 with shape parameters \(\alpha \) and \(\beta \). It emerges that:

$$\begin{aligned}&\log (M(g)+L(g))+E\log Z=\log (L(g))\Leftrightarrow \log \left( \frac{M(g)+L(g)}{L(g)}\right) =-E\log Z\\&\quad \Leftrightarrow \log \left( \frac{(\alpha +\beta )\kappa \sigma _{g}}{\alpha \kappa \sigma _{g}-\mu _{g}}\right) =-E\log Z\Leftrightarrow \frac{(\alpha +\beta )\kappa \sigma _{g}}{\alpha \kappa \sigma _{g}-\mu _{g}}=e^{-E\log Z}\\&\quad \Leftrightarrow \mu _{g}=\kappa \sigma _{g}\left( \alpha -\frac{\alpha +\beta }{e^{-E\log Z}}\right) \end{aligned}$$

Hence, for beta-distributed gambles with shape parameters \(\alpha \) and \(\beta \) the S-curve on the (\(\mu ,\sigma \)) plane is the straight line \(\mu =\kappa \sigma (\alpha -\frac{\alpha +\beta }{e^{-E\log Z}})\). Taking into account the pdf of a beta distribution between 0 and 1 with shape parameters \(\alpha \) and \(\beta \) it follows that:

$$\begin{aligned} E\log Z=\int _{0}^{1}\frac{(x)^{\alpha -1}(1-x)^{\beta -1}\log x}{\int _{0} ^{1}(x)^{\alpha -1}(1-x)^{\beta -1}dx}dx\text {.} \end{aligned}$$

\(\blacksquare \)

1.3 Comparison of iso-\(R^{AS}\)-riskiness and iso-\(R^{FH}\)-riskiness curves in gambles with uniform distributions: Analysis and simulations

From the analysis in Section 3.2 it follows that for any gamble g belonging to part A of iso-\(R^{FH}\)-riskiness V it is required that \(\mu _{g} -\sqrt{3}\sigma _{g}>-V\). Moreover, part A of that iso-\(R^{FH}\)-riskiness may be written as \(E\left[ \log (V+g)\right] =\log V\). Since \(\int \log (V+x)dx=(V+x)\log \left( V+x\right) -x-V\log (\frac{1}{V})\), it follows that:

$$\begin{aligned}&E\left[ \log (V+g)\right] \nonumber \\&\quad =\int _{\mu -\sqrt{3}\sigma }^{\mu +\sqrt{3}\sigma } \log (V+x)\frac{1}{2\sqrt{3}\sigma }dx\nonumber \\&\quad =\frac{(\mu +\sqrt{3}\sigma +V)\log (\mu +\sqrt{3}\sigma +V)-(\mu -\sqrt{3} \sigma +V)\log (\mu -\sqrt{3}\sigma +V)-2\sqrt{3}\sigma }{2\sqrt{3}\sigma }\nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(10)

From (10) it emerges that the slope at point (\(\mu ,\sigma \)) in part A of iso-\(R^{FH}\)-riskiness V is:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d\mu }{d\sigma }&=\frac{\left( \mu +V\right) \left[ \log \left( V+\mu +\sqrt{3}\sigma \right) -\log \left( V+\mu -\sqrt{3}\sigma \right) \right] -2\sqrt{3}\sigma }{\sigma \left[ \log \left( V+\mu +\sqrt{3} \sigma \right) -\log \left( V+\mu -\sqrt{3}\sigma \right) \right] }\nonumber \\&\quad =\frac{\mu +V}{\sigma }-\frac{2\sqrt{3}}{\log \left( V+\mu +\sqrt{3} \sigma \right) -\log \left( V+\mu -\sqrt{3}\sigma \right) }\text {.} \end{aligned}$$
(11)

Hence, it follows from (11) that:

$$\begin{aligned}&\lim _{\mu \rightarrow \sqrt{3}\sigma -V}\left( \frac{d\mu }{d\sigma }\right) \\&\quad =\lim _{\mu \rightarrow \sqrt{3}\sigma -V}\left( \frac{\left( \mu +V\right) (\log \left( V+\mu +\sqrt{3}\sigma \right) -\log \left( V+\mu -\sqrt{3} \sigma \right) )-2\sqrt{3}\sigma }{\sigma \left( \log \left( V+\mu +\sqrt{3} \sigma \right) -\log \left( V+\mu -\sqrt{3}\sigma \right) \right) }\right) =\sqrt{3}\text {.} \end{aligned}$$

Since part A of any iso-\(R^{FH}\)-riskiness is increasing and convex, it can be concluded that the slope at any point in part A of an iso-\(R^{FH} \)-riskiness is lower than \(\sqrt{3}\).

From (10) it can also be proved that (\(\mu =(\frac{e}{2}-1)V=0.359V,\sigma =\frac{eV}{2\sqrt{3}}=0.785V\)) is the intercept point between the S-curve and the straight line \(\mu =\sqrt{3}\sigma -V\) that belongs to the frontier of part A of iso-\(R^{FH}\)-riskiness V, a result already obtained in Section 5.2, since it follows that:

$$\begin{aligned}&\lim _{\mu \rightarrow \sqrt{3}\sigma -V}\frac{(\mu +\sqrt{3}\sigma +V)\log (\mu +\sqrt{3}\sigma +V)-(\mu -\sqrt{3}\sigma +V)\log (\mu -\sqrt{3}\sigma +V)-2\sqrt{3}\sigma }{2\sqrt{3}\sigma }\\&\quad =\frac{1}{2\sqrt{3}\sigma }\left[ 2\sqrt{3}\sigma \log (2\sqrt{3}\sigma )-2\sqrt{3}\sigma \right] =\log (V)\text {.} \end{aligned}$$

Hence, at that limiting point it is:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{2\sqrt{3}\sigma }{e}=V\Leftrightarrow \sigma =\frac{eV}{2\sqrt{3}}=0.785V \end{aligned}$$

and \(\mu =(\frac{e}{2}-1)V=0.359V\).

We now study the positions of the iso-\(R^{AS}\)-riskiness curves with respect to the iso-\(R^{FH}\)-riskiness V. Using (5) to substitute \(\mu \) from the iso-AS-riskiness \(\frac{1}{a}\) into part A of the iso-\(R^{FH}\)-riskiness V it follows from (10) and from \(E\left[ \log (V+g)\right] =\log V\) that:

$$\begin{aligned}&\left( -\sqrt{3}\sigma +\frac{1}{a}\log \left( \frac{-1+e^{2a\sigma \sqrt{3}} }{2a\sigma \sqrt{3}}\right) +\sqrt{3}\sigma +V\right) \\&\qquad \times \log \left( -\sqrt{3}\sigma +\frac{1}{a}\log \left( \frac{-1+e^{2a\sigma \sqrt{3}}}{2a\sigma \sqrt{3}}\right) +\sqrt{3}\sigma +V\right) \\&\qquad -\left( -\sqrt{3}\sigma +\frac{1}{a}\log \left( \frac{-1+e^{2a\sigma \sqrt{3}} }{2a\sigma \sqrt{3}}\right) -\sqrt{3}\sigma +V\right) \\&\qquad \times \log \left( -\sqrt{3}\sigma +\frac{1}{a}\log \left( \frac{-1+e^{2a\sigma \sqrt{3}}}{2a\sigma \sqrt{3}}\right) -\sqrt{3}\sigma +V\right) \\&\qquad -2\sqrt{3}\sigma =2\sqrt{3}\sigma \log (V) \end{aligned}$$

Let:

$$\begin{aligned}&G(V,a,\sigma )\equiv \left( \frac{1}{a}\log \left( \frac{-1+e^{2a\sigma \sqrt{3}} }{2a\sigma \sqrt{3}}\right) +V\right) \log \left( \frac{1}{a}\log \left( \frac{-1+e^{2a\sigma \sqrt{3}}}{2a\sigma \sqrt{3}}\right) +V\right) \\&\qquad -\left( \frac{1}{a}\log \left( \frac{-1+e^{2a\sigma \sqrt{3}}}{2a\sigma \sqrt{3} }\right) -2\sqrt{3}\sigma +V\right) \log \left( \frac{1}{a}\log \left( \frac{-1+e^{2a\sigma \sqrt{3}}}{2a\sigma \sqrt{3}}\right) -2\sqrt{3}\sigma +V\right) \\&\qquad -2\sqrt{3}\sigma (1+\log (V)) \end{aligned}$$

The sign of \(G(V,a,\sigma )\) must be studied to check the positions of the iso-\(R^{AS}\)-riskiness curves with respect to part A of the iso-\(R^{FH} \)-riskiness V. If \(G(V,a,\sigma )>0\) (\(<0\)) then the iso-AS-riskiness \(\frac{1}{a}\) is above (below) part A the iso-\(R^{FH}\)-riskiness V for that level of \(\sigma \). Simulations are used below to show that all iso-\(R^{AS}\)-riskiness curves with levels of riskiness higher than V are below the iso-\(R^{FH}\)-riskiness V (except at the origin) and that all iso-\(R^{AS}\)-riskiness curves with levels of riskiness lower than V are above part A of the iso-\(R^{FH}\)-riskiness V or intercept it from above.

Consider the iso-\(R^{FH}\)-riskiness 1 (the results would be similar for any other iso-\(R^{FH}\)-riskiness). Part A of that iso-\(R^{FH}\)-riskiness is defined for \(0<\sigma <0.785\). Moreover, if \(a=1\) then:

$$\begin{aligned} G(1,1,\sigma )= & {} \left( \log \left( \frac{-1+e^{2\sigma \sqrt{3}}}{2\sigma \sqrt{3} }\right) +1\right) \log \left( \log \left( \frac{-1+e^{2\sigma \sqrt{3}}}{2\sigma \sqrt{3} }\right) +1\right) \\&-\left( \log \left( \frac{-1+e^{2\sigma \sqrt{3}}}{2\sigma \sqrt{3}}\right) -2\sqrt{3}\sigma +1\right) \\&\quad \times \log \left( \log \left( \frac{-1+e^{2\sigma \sqrt{3}}}{2\sigma \sqrt{3}}\right) -2\sqrt{3}\sigma +1\right) -2\sqrt{3}\sigma \end{aligned}$$

Giving values of between 0 and 0.785 to \(\sigma \) it is obtained that \(G(1,1,0)=0\) and that \(G(1,1,\sigma )\) decreases with \(\sigma \). Hence, all iso-\(R^{AS}\)-riskiness with levels of AS-riskiness of 1 or more are below iso-\(R^{FH}\)-riskiness 1.

At the iso-\(R^{AS}\)-riskiness curve that goes through the point (\(\mu =0.359,\sigma =0.785\)) it follows from Section 5 that:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{1}{2\sqrt{3}a\sigma }(e^{a(\sqrt{3}\sigma -\mu )}-e^{-a(\sqrt{3}\sigma +\mu )})=1\Rightarrow a=1.274 \end{aligned}$$

Hence, the iso-\(R^{AS}\)-riskiness curve that runs through the point (\(\mu =0.359,\sigma =0.785\)) is the iso-\(R^{AS}\)-riskiness \(\frac{1}{1.274}\). The curvature at the origin of that iso-\(R^{AS}\)-riskiness (1.274) is greater than the curvature at the origin (1) of the iso-\(R^{FH}\)-riskiness 1. Hence, that iso-\(R^{AS}\)-riskiness \(\frac{1}{1.274}\) is above iso-\(R^{FH}\)-riskiness 1 at least for small values of \(\sigma \) .Footnote 12 It emerges that:

$$\begin{aligned} G(1,1.274,\sigma )= & {} \left( \frac{1}{1.274}\log \left( \frac{-1+e^{2(1.274)\sigma \sqrt{3}}}{2(1.274)\sigma \sqrt{3}}\right) +1\right) \\&\times \log \left( \frac{1}{1.274}\log \left( \frac{-1+e^{2(1.274)\sigma \sqrt{3}}}{2(1.274)\sigma \sqrt{3}}\right) +1\right) \\&-\left( \frac{1}{1.274}\log \left( \frac{-1+e^{2(1.274)\sigma \sqrt{3}} }{2(1.274)\sigma \sqrt{3}}\right) -2\sqrt{3}\sigma +1\right) \\&\times \log \left( \frac{1}{1.274} \log \left( \frac{-1+e^{2(1.274)\sigma \sqrt{3}}}{2(1.274)\sigma \sqrt{3}}\right) \right. \\&-2\sqrt{3}\sigma +1)-2\sqrt{3}\sigma \end{aligned}$$

Giving values of between 0 and 0.785 to \(\sigma \) it is obtained that \(G(1,1.274,\sigma )>0\) (and that \(G(1,1.274,\sigma )\) increases for \(\sigma <0.6725\) and decreases for \(\sigma >0.6725\)). Hence, all iso-\(R^{AS} \)-riskiness with levels of AS-riskiness of \(\frac{1}{1.274}\) or less are above part A of iso-\(R^{FH}\)-riskiness 1. However, those iso-\(R^{AS}\)-riskiness will intercept part B of iso-\(R^{FH}\)-riskiness 1 from above because the slope of any iso-\(R^{AS}\)-riskiness curve is lower than \(\sqrt{3}\) for any \(\sigma \) (and \(\sqrt{3}\) is the slope for any \(\sigma \) in part B of any iso-\(R^{FH}\)-riskiness curve).

Finally, consider any iso-\(R^{AS}\)-riskiness with a level of AS-riskiness between \(\frac{1}{1.274}\) and 1. From Sections 3.1 and 3.2 it is known that the first derivatives of all iso-\(R^{AS}\)-riskiness curves and of all iso-\(R^{FH}\)-riskiness curves at the origin are 0 and that the second derivatives at the origin of iso-\(R^{AS}\)-riskiness V and of iso-\(R^{FH} \)-riskiness V are \(\frac{1}{V}\). Hence, all iso-\(R^{AS}\)-riskiness curves with levels of riskiness lower than 1 are above the iso-\(R^{FH}\)-riskiness 1 at least for low values of \(\sigma \). Moreover, from the previous paragraph it follows that all iso-\(R^{AS}\)-riskiness curves with levels of riskiness higher than \(\frac{1}{1.274}\) are below part A of iso-\(R^{FH}\)-riskiness 1 at least for values of \(\sigma \) a little lower than 0.785. It can be concluded that any iso-\(R^{AS}\)-riskiness with a level of AS-riskiness between \(\frac{1}{1.274}\) and 1 will intercept part A of iso-\(R^{FH}\)-riskiness 1.

All simulations show that an iso-\(R^{AS}\)-riskiness with level of AS-riskiness between \(\frac{1}{1.274}\) and 1 intercepts iso-\(R^{FH}\)-riskiness 1 only once and that any of such iso-\(R^{AS}\)-riskiness intercepts part A of iso-\(R^{FH}\)-riskiness 1 from above. Hence, for an iso-\(R^{AS}\)-riskiness V with \(\frac{1}{1.274}<V<1\) it is obtained that \(G(1,V,\sigma )>0\) (\(<0\)) for \(\sigma \) higher (lower) than the value of \(\sigma \) such that \(G(1,V,\sigma )=0\). For instance, if \(V=\frac{1}{1.2}=0.833\,33\) then \(G(1,0.8333,\sigma )=0\Rightarrow \sigma =0.7271\) and if \(V=\frac{1}{1.1}=0.909\,09\) then \(G(1,0.909,\sigma )=0\Rightarrow \sigma =0.5697\). As expected \(\sigma \) decreases at the intercept point between an iso-\(R^{AS}\)-riskiness and iso-\(R^{FH}\)-riskiness 1 when the level of AS-riskiness of that iso-\(R^{AS}\)-riskiness increases. \(\blacksquare \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Chamorro, A., Usategui, J.M. Riskiness in gambles that belong to the same location-scale family and with well-defined means and variances. Math Finan Econ 12, 475–493 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11579-018-0212-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11579-018-0212-9

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation