Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Electricity in Quebec before Nationalization, 1919 to 1939

  • Published:
Atlantic Economic Journal Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

History books tend to depict the early days of the electrical industry as one of monopoly where consumers were being gouged. The province of Quebec in Canada was no exception. With the use of wide-ranging data over time, we observe a different portrait: electrical firms in Quebec increased production faster than elsewhere while prices fell consistently. The main reason for this divergence between facts and history books is most likely the choice of comparing Quebec’s private industry with Ontario’s nationalized industry, which priced electricity at the average cost.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Troesken (2006) explains this franchise in the case of electricity for the United States.

  2. Emmons (1993) indicated that private monopolies, private firms in competition, public monopolies and public firms in competition all had different price levels in spite of sharing a common downward trend.

  3. It is also worth pointing out that electrical appliances, which were complements to electricity services (Fouquet 2008), were expensive, and the relatively poorer Quebeckers tended to acquire the less expensive wood- and coal-burning home appliances (Marchand 1988), which created pressures on electricity companies to reduce prices in order to increase adoption rates (Gelly 2010).

  4. Firewood represented 15.6% and 44.6% of fuel and light expenditures for French households in Montreal and Quebec City (“British” households in Montreal reported expenditures equal to 5.6% of all expenditures on fuel and light). Overall, “British” families in Canada expended 10.5% of their fuel and light budget on firewood as opposed to 23.9% for “French” families (Dominion Bureau of Statistics 1941).

  5. This was largely a result of the fact that Quebec had greater population density in cities. The largest two cities of the province of Quebec (Montreal and Quebec City) accounted for 31.0% and 33.0% of the province’s population in 1921 and 1931 as opposed to 21.7% and 22.9% for Ontario’s two largest cities, Toronto and Hamilton (Dominion Bureau of Statistics, 1932).

  6. MLHP represented a minor share of total electricity output (4%) in Quebec, and 30% of the electricity it distributed was bought from SWP. Its power sites were in the Upper Saint-Lawrence region. SWP was located in central Quebec (the Maurice region) and was the largest single producer with numerous distribution subsidiaries, which notably served Quebec City and Trois-Rivières. GP was an imported producer, but it sold most of its output to local distributors, the pulp and paper industry that was prominent in the region and the neighboring province of Ontario. As for SP, originally known as the Duke-Price Power Co., its output was largely oriented toward the aluminum and pulp and paper industries. However, it did consolidate with other regional companies, which allowed it to become the main distributor for many localities of the Saguenay and Lac Saint-Jean region. SCP was the smallest of them and operated largely in the eastern townships in south-central Quebec (Dales 1957; Dupré et al. 1996; Hogue et al. 1979).

  7. The Directory reported the population of the different municipalities (with the exception of one, Shipton in the eastern townships, which was linked to the municipality of Danville for distribution), which allowed us to arrive at this figure. The Directory reports one cooperative, operating in Rimouski, which served 0.1% of Quebec’s population.

  8. Dupré et al. (1996) have analyzed the regulations of the Quebec Electricity Commission (1935–1937) and the Provincial Electricity Board (after 1937) and found that, as Stigler and Friedland (1962) and Peltzman (1976) did, the regulatory boards were largely ineffective.

  9. The exception was self-generators for large industries.

  10. It is worth pointing out that in an earlier version of his work, Emmons (1991) found a much larger price differential (28%), half of which could be explained by capital cost advantage. The refinements in Emmons’ work from his 1991 version to the 1997 version led to a reduction in the price advantage estimate to this much lower figure.

  11. While it is beyond the scope of this paper to determine this, there is the possibility that lower rates for larger power consumers increased their productivity, which allowed them to offer higher wages. Thus, workers would have benefitted though this channel instead of through lower prices.

  12. Historian Keith Fleming, who studied HEPC extensively, summarized the fixation of rates as follows:

    Rates charged by the municipalities had to be sufficient to cover the cost per horsepower incurred by the HEPC (…). Also to be considered in the final price were the municipality’s proportionate share of transmission costs, operation and maintenance costs, interest charges on any money borrowed for installation, depreciation reserves, a reserve fund for obsolescence and contingencies and sinking fund reserves for the amortization of local commission’s debts. Ultimately, a higher power cost resulting from longer transmission distances, smaller population density and lighter power load had to be borne solely by the contracting municipality (Fleming 1983, p. 486).

  13. The Murray and Flood report came from an association of electricity manufacturers. However, the statistics from the Dominion Bureau of Statistics’ Central Electric Stations series point in the same direction. In 1923, the generation of 1000 kWh cost $4.74 as opposed to $7.15 in Ontario. In fact, this is probably a conservative estimate. Until 1932, the Dominion Bureau of Statistics did not publish data regarding interprovincial trade of electricity, so we have to divide expenses over electricity generated rather than electricity generated and distributed. This is a problem because Ontario tended to buy substantial quantities of electricity from Quebec, which it then distributed at a cost (Quebec imported a few hundred thousand kWh from the United States). After 1933, this is not a problem, as we can divide over electricity distributed and generated (pages have been lost in the 1932 edition, meaning we have to jump to 1933). In 1933, the cost per 1000 kWh serviced in the province of Quebec stood at $1.43 as opposed to $6.13 in Ontario.

  14. Moreover, the quality of transmission inferior in Ontario than in Quebec, which probably worsened the shortfall. Indeed, Dominion Bureau of Statistics (1940) data suggest that losses of energy in Quebec in 1939 represented 6.95% of total consumption compared with 16.63% in Ontario.

  15. The rest of Canada is defined here as Canada minus Ontario and Quebec.

  16. Especially if the price schedule were fixed in the franchise contract.

  17. The franchise acquired by the new firm, the Public Service Corporation of Quebec, only extended to electricity. QRLHP had managed to retain only its franchise for gas and tramways.

  18. City dwellers were well-connected to electricity by 1931. In Montreal, it was estimated that between 89% and 99% of households were connected (Gelly 2010).

  19. Quebec had some of the lowest rates in Canada. For example, the Dominion Bureau of Statistics for 1939 places Quebec in second position (slightly behind Manitoba) for the lowest rates (as proxied by revenues per 1000 kWh) for large power customers. This result is more or less in line with the points made by Peltzman (1971) and Kitchens and Jaworski (2017), who argue that public and private ownership influence rate setting across different consumer classes since private firms tend to be better able to price discriminate.

  20. Large power only accounted for 63.8% of revenues in Quebec (Dominion Bureau of Statistics 1939), so that, at $30,177 of revenue per large power customer, Quebec was more three times above the Canadian average.

References

  • Armentano, D. (1996). Antitrust and monopoly: Anatomy of a policy failure. Oakland: Independent Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bellavance, C. (1998). L’État, la ‘houille blanche’ et le grand capital: L’aliénation des ressources hydrauliques du domaine public québécois au début du XXe siècle. Revue d’histoire de l’Amérique française, 51(4), 487–520.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bellavance, C., Levasseur, R., & Rousseau, Y. (1999). De la lutte antimonopoliste à la promotion de la grande entreprise. L’essor de deux institutions: Hydro-Québec et Desjardins, 1920–1965. Recherches sociographiques, 40(3), 551–578.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Biss, I. (1936). The contracts of the hydro-electric power commission of Ontario. Economic Journal, 46(183), 549–554.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bliss, M. (1987). Northern Enterprise: Five centuries of Canadian business. Toronto: McClelland and Stewart.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boutet, D. (1999). Le mouvement d’opposition au monopole de l’électricité à Québec dans l’entre-deux-guerres. MA thesis: Université du Québec à Trois-Rivières. Available online at http://depot-e.uqtr.ca/3358/1/000658919.pdf.

  • Bradley Jr., R. (1996). The origins of political electricity: Market failure or political opportunism? Energy Law Journal, 17(1), 59–102.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brown, M., and Macdonald, R. (2015). Provincial convergence and divergence in Canada, 1926 to 2011. Ottawa: Statistics Canada. Available online at http://www.statcan.gc.ca/pub/11f0027m/11f0027m2015096-eng.htm.

  • Bureau of Labor Statistics. (1939). Changes in retail prices of electricity, 1923–1938. United States Department of Labor. Available online at https://fraser.stlouisfed.org/title/4172.

  • Clark, G. (2017). What were the British earnings and prices then. Measuring Worth, Available online at http://www.measuringworth.com/ukearncpi/.

  • Coursey, D., Isaac, M., & Smith, V. (1984). Natural monopoly and contested markets: some experimental results. Journal of Law & Economics, 27(1), 91–113.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dales, J. H. (1953). Fuel, power and industrial development in central Canada. American Economic Review, 43(2), 181–198.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dales, J. H. (1957). Hydroelectricity and industrial development: Quebec, 1898–1940. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz, H. (1968). Why regulate utilities? Journal of Law & Economics, 11(1), 55–65.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Department of the Interior. (1923). Central electric stations in Canada, Part II: Directory, Nov. 1, 1922. Ottawa: Department of the Interior, Government of Canada.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dominion Bureau of Statistics. (Editions from 1919 to 1940). Census of industry: Central electric stations in Canada. Ottawa: Department of Trade and Commerce.

  • Dominion Bureau of Statistics. (1927). Index numbers of rates for electricity for residence lighting and tables of monthly bills, 1913, 1924, 1925, 1926. Ottawa: Government of Canada.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dominion Bureau of Statistics. (1938). Domestic rates for manufactured & natural fuel gas, 1913–1937. Ottawa: Government of Canada.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dominion Bureau of Statistics. (1940). Index numbers of cost of electricity for domestic service, commercial light and small power. Ottawa: Government of Canada.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dominion Bureau of Statistics. (1941). Family income and expenditure in Canada, 1937–1938: A study of urban wage-earner families, including data on physical attributes. Ottawa: Government of Canada. Available online at http://publications.gc.ca/collections/collection_2017/statcan/CS62-D-66-1941-eng.pdf.

  • Dorion, M. (2000). L’électrification du monde rural québécois. Revue d’histoire de l’Amérique française, 54(1), 3–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dupré, R., & Patry, M. (1998). Hydroelectricity and the state in Quebec and Ontario: Two different historical paths. In G. Zaccour (Ed.), Deregulation of electric utilities (pp. 119–147). Boston: Kluwer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Dupré, R., Patry, M., & Joly, P. (1996). The politics and regulation of hydroelectricity: The case of Quebec in the thirties. Montreal: CIRANO.

    Google Scholar 

  • Emery, H., & Levitt, C. (2002). Cost of living, real wages and real incomes in thirteen Canadian cities, 1900–1950. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d’Économique, 35(1), 115–137.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Emmons, W. (1991). Private and public responses to market failure in the US electric power industry, 1882–1942. Journal of Economic History, 51(2), 452–454.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Emmons, W. (1993). Franklin D. Roosevelt, electric utilities, and the power of competition. Journal of Economic History, 53(4), 880–907.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Emmons, W. (1997). Implications of ownership, regulation, and market structure for performance: evidence from the US electric utility industry before and after the new deal. Review of Economics and Statistics, 79(2), 279–289.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Evenden, M. (2009). Mobilizing rivers: Hydro-electricity, the state, and world war II in Canada. Annals of the Association of American Geographers, 99(5), 845–855.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Faucher, A. (1992). La question de l’électricité au Québec durant les années trente. L’Actualité Économique, 68(3), 415–432.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fleming, K. (1983). The uniform rate and rural electrification issues in Ontario politics, 1919–1923. Canadian Historical Review, 64(4), 494–518.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fleming, K. (1992). Power at cost: Ontario hydro and rural electrification, 1911–1958. Montreal: McGill-Queen’s University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fleury, J.-L. (2004). Les porteurs de lumières: l’histoire de la distribution de l’électricité au Québec. Montréal: Éditions Multimondes.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fouquet, R. (2008). Heat, power and light: Revolutions in energy services. London: Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gelly, A. (2003). A precipitous decline, steam as motive power in Montreal: a case study of the Lachine Canal industries. IA: The Journal of the Society for Industrial Archeology, 29(1), 65–85.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gelly, A. (2010). Vapeur, thermoélectricité et hydroélectricité comme force mortice le long du corridor industriel du canal de Lachine, des années 1850 à la Seconde Guerre Mondiale. PhD thesis, Department of History, Laval University. Available online at http://theses.ulaval.ca/archimede/fichiers/27029/27029.pdf.

  • Geloso, V. (2017). Rethinking Canadian economic growth and development since 1900. London: Palgrave MacMillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hannah, L. (1979). Electricity before nationalisation: A study of the development of the electrical supply industry in Britain to 1948. London: McMillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hillman, A. (2015). Rent-seeking as political economy. In A. Hillman & R. Congleton (Eds.), Companion to the political economy of rent-seeking (pp. 10–18). London: Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hogue, C., Bolduc, A., & Larouche, D. (1979). Québec: un siècle d’électricité. Montréal: Libre Expression.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kitchens, C., & Jaworski, T. (2017). Ownership and the price of residential electricity: evidence from the United States, 1935–1940. Explorations in Economic History, 64, 53–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krueger, A. (1974). The political economy of the rent-seeking society. American Economic Review, 64(3), 291–303.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liebowitz, S. (1999). Winners, losers and Microsoft. Oakland: Independent Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • MacFayden, J. (2016). Hewers of wood: A history of wood energy in Canada. In R. W. Sandwell (Ed.), Powering up Canada: The history of power, fuel, and energy from 1600 (pp. 129–161). Montreal and Kingston: McGill-Queen’s University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marchand, S. (1988). L'impact des innovations technologiques sur la vie quotidienne des Québécoises du début du XXe siècle (1910-1940). Material Culture Review/Revue de la culture matérielle, 28(Fall), 1–14.

    Google Scholar 

  • McKenzie, R., & Lee, D. (2008). In defense of monopoly: How market power fosters creative production. Ann Harbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ministère de l’Industrie et du Commerce. (From 1918–1944). Quebec Statistical Year Book. Québec: Ministère de l’Industrie et du Commerce.

  • Montreal Light, Heat and Power (MHLP). (1934). Diminution et révision des tarifs d’électricité: annonce de la quinzième diminution. L’Ordre, September, 7, 3.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murray, W. S., & Flood, H. (1922). Government owned and controlled compared with privately owned and regulated electric utilities in Canada and the United States. New York: National Electric Light Association.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelles, H. V. (1974 [2005]). The Politics of Development: Forests, Mines, and Hydro-Electric Power in Ontario, 1849–1941. Kingston and Montreal: McGill-Queen’s University Press.

  • Neufeld, J. (1987). Price discrimination and the adoption of the electricity demand charge. Journal of Economic History, 47(3), 693–709.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Officer, L. (2017). Exchange rates between the United States dollar and forty-one currencies. Measuring Worth, Available online at http://www.measuringworth.com/exchangeglobal/.

  • Officer, L., and Williamson, S.H. (2017). The annual consumer price index for the United States, 1774–2015. Measuring Worth, Available online at http://www.measuringworth.com/uscpi/.

  • Peltzman, S. (1971). Pricing in public and private enterprises: Electric utilities in the United States. Journal of Law & Economics, 14(1), 109–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peltzman, S. (1976). Toward a more general theory of regulation. Journal of Law & Economics, 19(2), 211–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piché, P.-É. (1937). Régimes et tarifs d’électricité. Actualité Économique, 13(2), 17–30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rassenti, S., Smith, V., & Wilson, V. (2001). Using experiments to inform the privatization/deregulation movement in electricity. Cato Journal, 21(3), 515–544.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, V. (1988). Electric power deregulation: background and prospects. Contemporary Economic Policy, 6(3), 14–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Statistics Canada. (2015). Table 384–5000: Data on long-run provincial and territorial economic performance, annual. Ottawa: Statistics Canada. Available online at http://www5.statcan.gc.ca/cansim/a26?lang=eng&id=3845000.

  • Stigler, G., & Friedland, C. (1962). What can regulators regulate? The case of electricity. Journal of Law & Economics, 5, 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Troesken, W. (1996). Why regulate utilities? The new institutional economics and the Chicago gas industry, 1849–1924. Ann Harbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Troesken, W. (2006). Regime change and corruption: A history of public utility regulation. In E. Glaeser & C. Goldin (Eds.), Corruption and reform: Lessons from America’s economic history. Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research and University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1967). The welfare costs of tariffs, monopolies, and theft. Economic Inquiry, 5(3), 224–232.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wright, G. (2006). Electrical energy—retail prices, residential use, and service coverage: 1902–2000. Table Db 234–241. In S. B. Carter, S. S. Gartner, M. R. Haines, A. L. Olmstead, R. Sutch, & G. Wright (Eds.), Historical Statistics of the United States, Earliest Times to the Present: Millennial Edition. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

Acknowledgements go to Alexandra Foucher, Mike Guetta, Robert Rogers and Art Carden, Jean-Thomas Bernard, Herbert Emery, Edward Stringham, Pierre Desrochers, Michael Giberson, Gérard Bélanger and the participants of the research seminar at Texas Tech University.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Vincent Geloso.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Geloso, V., Belzile, G. Electricity in Quebec before Nationalization, 1919 to 1939. Atl Econ J 46, 101–119 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11293-018-9568-8

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11293-018-9568-8

Keywords

JEL

Navigation