Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Income inequality and risk taking: the impact of social comparison information

  • Published:
Theory and Decision Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In contrast to the assumptions of standard economic theory, recent experimental evidence shows that the income of peers has a systematic impact on observed degrees of risk aversion. This paper reports the findings of two experiments examining the impact of income inequality on risk preferences and whether the knowledge of inequality mediates the decisions. In Experiment 1, participants who were recruited for a real-effort task were paid either a low wage or a high wage. Half of the participants were aware of the income inequality, while the other half were not. After completing their task, they were invited to invest a part of their salary in a risky asset. In Experiment 2, we replicated the same experiment in the laboratory with windfall endowments to test the consistency of results in the laboratory settings. The results of the first experiment show that high-wage subjects take higher risks than low-wage participants do if they are aware of the inequality in wages. This finding supports the idea that income comparisons shape risky decisions. In Experiment 2, on the other hand, we did not observe any significant differences in decisions. This may suggest that the income comparison is sensitive to house-money effect.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Lietuvos Nacionalinė Vartotojų Federacija.

References

  • Antonovics, K., Arcidiacono, P., & Walsh, R. (2009). The effects of gender interactions in the lab and in the field. Review of Economics and Statistics, 91, 152–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow Kenneth, J. (1965). Aspects of the theory of risk-bearing. Helsinki: Yrjö Hahnsson Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G., Murphy, K., & Werning, I. (2005). The equilibrium distribution of income and the market for status. Journal of Political Economy, 113, 282–301.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carlsson, F., He, H., & Martinsson, P. (2013). Easy come, easy go. Experimental Economics, 16(2), 190–207.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carpenter, J., Burks, S., & Verhoogen, E. (2005). Comparing students to workers: The effects of social framing on behavior in distribution games. In J. Carpenter, G. Harrison, & J. List (Eds.), Field experiments in economics. Greenwich and London: JAI/Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cherbonnier, F., & Gollier, C. (2015). Decreasing aversion under ambiguity. Journal of Economic Theory, 157, 606–623.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Croson, R., & Gneezy, U. (2009). Gender differences in preferences. Journal of Economic Literature, 47(2), 448–474.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eckel, C. C., & Grossman, P. J. (2008). Men, women and risk aversion: Experimental evidence. Handbook of experimental economics results, 1, 1061–1073.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. M. (1999). A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, 817–868.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Festinger, L. (1954). A theory of social comparison processes. Human Relations, 7(2), 117–140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Filippin, A., & Crosetto, P. (2016). A reconsideration of gender differences in risk attitudes. Management Science, 62(11), 3138–3160.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gamba, A., Manzoni, E., & Stanca, L. (2014). Social comparison and risk taking behavior. Theory and Decision, 82, 221–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gill, D., & Prowse, V. (2012). A structural analysis of disappointment aversion in a real effort competition. American Economic Review, 102(1), 469–503.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gneezy, U., Niederle, M., & Rustichini, A. (2003). Performance in competitive environments: Gender differences. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(3), 1049–1074.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guiso, L., & Paiella, M. (2008). Risk aversion, wealth, and background risk. Journal of the European Economic Association, 6(6), 1109–1150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hill, S. E., & Buss, D. M. (2010). Risk and relative social rank: Positional concerns and risky shifts in probabilistic decision-making. Evolution and Human Behavior, 31, 219–226.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47, 263–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Konow, J. (2000). Fair shares: Accountability and cognitive dissonance in allocation decisions. American Economic Review, 90, 1072–1091.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kőszegi, B., & Rabin, M. (2006). A model of reference-dependent preferences. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121, 1133–1165.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kőszegi, B., & Rabin, M. (2007). Reference-dependent risk attitudes. The American Economic Review, 97, 1047–1073.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lahno, A. M., & Serra-Garcia, M. (2015). Peer effects in risk taking: Envy or conformity? Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 50(1), 73–95.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levitt, S. D., & List, J. A. (2007). What do laboratory experiments measuring social preferences reveal about the real world? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21(2), 153–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levy, H. (1994). Absolute and relative risk aversion: An experimental study. Journal of Risk and uncertainty, 8(3), 289–307.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Linde, J., & Sonnemans, J. (2012). Social comparison and risky choices. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 44, 45–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • List, J. (2006). The behaviouralist meets the market: Measuring social preferences and reputation effects in actual transactions. Journal of Political Economy, 114, 1–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mishra, S., Hing, L. S. S., & Lalumière, M. L. (2015). Inequality and risk-taking. Evolutionary Psychology, 13(3), 280–307.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parker, S. C. (2004). The economics of self-employment and entrepreneurship. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Payne, B. K., Brown-Iannuzzi, J. L., & Hannay, J. W. (2017). Economic inequality increases risk taking. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 114(18), 4643–4648.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perotti, R. (1993). Political equilibrium, income distribution, and growth. Review of Economic Studies, 60, 755–776.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piketty, T. (2014). Capital in the twenty-first century. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Pratt, J. W. (1964). Risk aversion in the small and in the large. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 32, 122–136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ray, D., & Robson, A. (2012). Status, intertemporal choice and risk taking. Econometrica, 80, 1505–1531.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rohde, I., & Rohde, K. (2011). Risk attitudes in a social context. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 43, 205–225.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmidt, U., Friedl, A., & Lima de Miranda, K. (2015). Social comparison and gender differences in risk taking. Kiel Working paper No. 2011.

  • Schwerter, F. (2013). Social reference points and risk taking. Bonn Econ. Discussion Papers No. 11.

  • Sinn, H.-W. (1994). A theory of the welfare state. NBER Working Paper No. 4856.

  • Sutter, M., & Weck-Hannemann, H. (2003). Taxation and the veil of ignorance—A real effort experiment on the Laffer curve. Public Choice, 115, 217–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thaler, R. H., & Johnson, E. J. (1990). Gambling with the house money and trying to break even: The effects of prior outcomes on risky choice. Management Science, 36(6), 643–660.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1992). Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5, 297–323.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Veblen, T. (1899). The theory of the leisure class. New York: McMillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vendrik, M., & Woltjer, G. B. (2007). Happiness and loss aversion: Is utility concave or convex in relative income? Journal of Public Economics, 91, 1423–1448.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vieider, F. M., Chmura, T., Fisher, T., Kusakawa, T., Martinsson, P., Thompson, F. M., et al. (2015a). Within- versus between-country differences in risk attitudes: Implications for cultural comparisons. Theory and Decision, 78(2), 209–218.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vieider, F. M., Lefebvre, M., Bouchouicha, R., Chmura, T., Hakimov, R., Krawczyk, M., et al. (2015b). Common components of risk and uncertainty attitudes across contexts and domains: Evidence from 30 countries. Journal of the European Economic Association, 13(3), 421–452.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilkinson, R. G., & Pickett, M. (2009). The spirit level: Why more equal societies almost always do better. London: Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Levent Neyse.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

See Fig. 3.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Distribution of WTP levels in experiments

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Schmidt, U., Neyse, L. & Aleknonyte, M. Income inequality and risk taking: the impact of social comparison information. Theory Decis 87, 283–297 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11238-019-09713-8

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11238-019-09713-8

Keywords

Navigation