Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Which IP strategies do young highly innovative firms choose?

  • Published:
Small Business Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper describes and analyzes the strategies of young highly innovative companies to appropriate the returns from their innovations. Upon controlling for other firm and industry characteristics, we show that firms combining a young age and small scale with a high R&D intensive profile are more likely to use intellectual property (IP), specifically combining formal and informal appropriation mechanisms. They are especially more likely to choose secrecy in combination with formal IP. This holds primarily when they introduce more radical innovations new to the market.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The age of the firm is unfortunately not mandatory in the EUROSTAT EU wide organized CIS survey. Only a few participating countries, among which Germany, include this information in the questionnaire.

  2. The survey is conducted annually by the Centre for European Economic Research (ZEW), infas Institut fuer Sozialforschung and ISI Fraunhofer Institute on behalf of the German Federal Ministry of Education and Research. A detailed description of the survey data and the sampling method can be found in the background reports available at ZEW (www.zew.de).

  3. The survey is directed to a stratified sample of companies in manufacturing and services sectors with at least five employees. Although the very small firms are not targeted, the sample nevertheless contains 5% of firms with less than five employees.

  4. We restrict attention to West German firms only, dropping East German observations to avoid a source of heterogeneity that is outside our issues of interest.

  5. Young Innovative Enterprises are defined in the EU State Aid Rules as small Enterprises, less than 6 years old, having being “certified’ by external experts on the basis of a business plan, as capable of developing products or processes which are technologically new or substantially improved and which carry a risk of technological or commercial failure, or have R&D intensity of at least 15% in the last 3 years or currently (for start-ups). However, there are only 51 YICs in our sample when applying this definition. We therefore expand the R&D and age criteria in order to garner more observations.

  6. These could be corporate spinoffs, or independent start-ups which have been acquired in the past. Unfortunately, the CIS survey does not contain information on the corporate history.

  7. The CIS questionnaire also asks respondents to rate the various appropriation mechanisms on their importance. These results show that there are no strongly significant differences in the reported importance of informal mechanisms for appropriating returns between YICs and other innovators, conditional on the mechanisms being used. The difference seems therefore only reflected in whether they use mechanisms or not. In the remainder of the analysis, we will only look at whether or not mechanisms have been used, rather than on how important mechanisms were rated by the respondents.

  8. It should be noted that in this group of 116 firms, only 13 firms are not SMEs, as young firms typically are small sized.

  9. We estimate the four-equation probit models by the method of simulated maximum likelihood, using the Geweke-Hajivassiliou-Keane (GHK) simulator to evaluate the four-dimensional normal integrals in the likelihood function (see e.g., Greene 2000). We use 50 draws of random variates to calculate the simulated likelihood.

  10. We do not report all marginal effects at this is computationally too intensive

References

  • Acs, Z. J., & Audretsch, D. B. (1988). Innovation in large and small firms: an empirical analysis. The American Economic Review, 78(4), 678–690.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anton, J. J., & Yao, D. A. (2004). Little patents and big secrets: managing intellectual property. RAND Journal of Economics, 35, 1–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arora, A., Fosfuri, A., & Gambardella, A. (2001). Markets for technology: the economics of innovation and corporate strategy. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arundel, A. (2001). The relative effectiveness of patents and secrecy for appropriation. Research Policy, 30(4), 611–624.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barney, J. (1991). Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of Management, 17(1), 99–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W.. 2004. Education for innovation: entrepreneurial breakthrough vs. corporate incremental improvements. NBER Working Paper, No. 10578

  • Cassiman, B., & Veugelers, R. (2002). R&D cooperation and spillovers: some empirical evidence from Belgium. American Economic Review, 92(4), 1169–1184.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cassiman, B., & Veugelers, R. (2006). In search of complementarity in innovation strategy: internal R&D, cooperation in R&D and external technology acquisition. Management Science, 52(1), 68–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, W., R. Nelson, & J. Walsh. (2001). Protecting their intellectual assets: appropriability conditions and why firms patent and why they do not in the American Manufacturing Sector. NBER working paper 7552

  • Conti, A., Thursby, J., & Thursby, M. (2013). Patents as signals for startup financing. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 61(3), 592–622.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Czarnitzki, D., & Delanote, J. (2013). Young innovative companies: the new high-growth firms? Industrial and Corporate Change, 22, 1315–1340.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Rassenfosse, G., & Van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie, B. (2013). The role of fees in patent systems: theory and evidence. Journal of Economic Surveys, 27(4), 696–716.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Encaoua, D., & Lefouili, Y. (2005). Choosing intellectual protection: Imitation, patent strength and licensing agreement. Annales d’Economie et de Statistique, 79-80, 241–271.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gans, J. S., Hsu, D. H., & Stern, S. (2002). When does start-up innovation spur the gale of creative destruction? The Rand Journal of Economics, 33(4), 571–586.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garcia-Quevedo, J., Pellegrino, G., & Vivarelli, M. (2014). R&D drivers and age? Are young firms different? Research Policy, 43, 1544–1556.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Graham, S. J. H., Merges, R., Samuelson, P., & Sichelman, T. (2010). High technology entrepreneurs and the patent system: results of the 2008 Berkeley patent survey. Berkeley Technology Law Journal, 24(4), 1255–1328.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greene, W. H. (2000). Econometric analysis (fourth ed.). Upper Saddle River: Prentice-Hall International.

    Google Scholar 

  • Griliches, Z. (Ed.). (1984). R & D, patents, and productivity. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, B. H. (2005). The financing of innovation. In S. Shane (Ed.), Blackwell handbook of technology and innovation management (p. 2005). Oxford: Blackwell Publishers, Ltd..

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, B. H., & Ziedonis, A. (2001). The determinants of patenting in the U.S. semiconductor industry, 1980–1994. RAND Journal of Economics, 32, 101–118.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall, B. H., Helmers, C., Rogers, M., & Sena, V. (2013). The importance (or not) of patents to UK firms. Oxford Economic PapersOxford University Press, 65(3), 603–629.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall, B. H., Helmers, C., Rogers, M., & Sena, V. (2014). The choice between formal and informal intellectual property: a review. Journal of Economic Literature, 52(2), 375–423.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henderson, R. (1993). Underinvestment and incompetence as responses to radical innovation—evidence from the photolithographic alignment equipment industry. RAND Journal of Economics, 24(2), 248–270.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henderson, R., & Clark, K. (1990). Architectural innovation: the reconfiguration of existing product technologies and the failure of established firms. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35(1), 9–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henkel, J., Rønde, T., & Wagner, M. (2015). And the winner is—acquired. Entrepreneurship as a contest yielding radical innovations. Research Policy, 44(2), 295–310.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoenig, D., & Henkel, J. (2015). Quality signals? The role of patents, alliances, and team experience in venture capital financing. Research Policy, 44(5), 1049–1064.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hsu, D. H., & Ziedonis, R. H. (2013). Resources as dual sources of advantage: Implications for valuing entrepreneurial-firm patents. Strategic Management Journal, 34(7), 761–781.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lahr, H., & Mina, A. (2016). Venture capital investments and the technological performance of portfolio firms. Research Policy, 45(1), 303–318.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leiponen, A., & Byma, J. (2009). If you cannot block, you better run: small firms, cooperative innovation, and appropriation strategies. Research Policy, 38, 1478–1488.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lerner, J. (1994). The importance of patent scope: an empirical analysis. RAND Journal of Economics, 25(2), 319–334.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levin, R. C., Klevorick, A. K., Nelson, R. R., & Winter, S. G. (1987). Appropriating the returns from Industrial Research and Development. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 3, 783–820.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mairesse, J., & Mohnen, P. (2010). Using innovation surveys for econometric analysis. Handbook of the Economics of Innovation, 2, 1129–1155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mann, R. J., & Sager, T. W. (2007). Patents, venture capital, and software startups. Research Policy, 36, 193–208.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Millot, V. and P. Llerena, Are trademarks and patents complementary or substitute protection for innovation. Paper presented at the DRUID conference, Copenhagen, Denmark, 2012.

  • Munari, F., & Toschi, L. (2015). Do patents affect VC financing? Empirical evidence from the nanotechnology sector. International Entrepreneurship and Management Journal, 11(3), 623–644.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pakes, A., & Griliches, Z. (1984). Patents and R&D at the firm level: a first look. In Z. Griliches (Ed.), Research and Development, patents and productivity (pp. 55–72). USA: The University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pellegrino, G., Piva, M., & Vivarelli, M. (2012). Young firms and innovation: a microeconometric analysis. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 23, 329–340.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reinganum, J. F. (1983). Uncertain innovation and the persistence of monopoly. The American Economic Review, 73(4), 741–748.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reitzig, M., & Puranan, P. (2009). Value appropriation as an organizational capability: The case of IP protection through patents. Strategic Management Journal, 30, 765–789.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rumelt, R. P. (1987). Theory, strategy and entrepreneurship. In D. J. Teece (Ed.), The competitive challenge, strategies for industrial innovation and renewal (pp. 137–159). Cambridge: Ballinger Publishing Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Santarelli, E., & Vivarelli, M. (2007). Entrepreneurship and the process of firms’ entry, survival and growth. Industrial and Corporate Change, 16(3), 455–488.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schneider, C., & Veugelers, R. (2010). On young highly innovative companies: why they matter and how (not) to policy support them. Industrial and Corporate Change, 19(4).

  • Shane, S. (2001). Technological opportunities and new firm creation. Management Science, 47(2), 205–220.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Somaya, D. and S. Graham, Vermeers and Rembrandts in the same attic: Complementarity between copyrights and trademarks leveraging strategies in Software. Georgia Institute of Technology TIGER Working Paper 2006.

  • Teece, D. J. (1986). Profiting from technological innovation: implications for integration, collaboration, licensing, and public policy. Research Policy, 6, 285–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie, B., & François, D. (2009). The cost factor in patent systems. The Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade, 9(4), 329–355.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wernerfelt, B. (1984). A resource-based view of the firm. Strategic Management Journal, 5(2), 171–180.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors wish to thank the participants at the conferences and seminars at Brussels, Leuven, Mannheim, Copenhagen, Evora (EARIE 2013), and Chicago (IIOS 2013). Veugelers acknowledges the financial support received from FWO Flanders (G. 085816N).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Reinhilde Veugelers.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Veugelers, R., Schneider, C. Which IP strategies do young highly innovative firms choose?. Small Bus Econ 50, 113–129 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-017-9898-y

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-017-9898-y

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation