Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Firm size, age, industrial networking, and growth: a case of the Korean manufacturing industry

  • Published:
Small Business Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper investigates the roles of firm size, age, and industrial networking in determining firm growth. Analyses using the 2-year panel data of 7,889 Korean manufacturing firms between 1994 and 2003 confirm that firm size and age have significant negative effects on firm growth and significant positive impacts on firm survival. R&D and export activities are found to facilitate both firm growth and survival. The primary focus of this study is to examine the effects of industrial networking, such as subcontracting and clustering, on firm growth. The results show that subcontracting does not yield any positive effect for firm growth, but encumbers survival, which may be accounted for by the high subcontracting intensity among small firms. Clustering, on the other hand, is found to promote firm growth and survival. There is, however, little evidence that such a positive effect of clustering is derived from network externalities through cooperation and competition among firms in a cluster per se.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In this paper, establishments, plants, and firms are used interchangeably.

  2. For a review, see Sutton (1997) and Audretsch et al. (2004). There are exceptions against this conventional wisdom. Acs and Audretsch (1990), Audretsch et al. (2004), and Delmar et al. (2003) reported that Gibrat’s law on a firm's size-growth relationship cannot be rejected. Wagner (1992) found no strong evidence that smaller firms tend to grow faster than larger firms. Lotti et al. (2003) suggested that smaller firms are likely to grow faster only in the early stage of their life cycle, while in the subsequent years the Gibrat’s law cannot be rejected. Das (1995) suggested a strong positive effect of firm age on growth in the case of an infant computer hardware industry in India. Heshmati (2001) found a positive firm age-growth relationship in terms of assets and sales, while negative in the employment model of firm growth.

  3. In this paper, clustering, industrial complex, and industrial districts are used interchangeably.

  4. Korea means South Korea, unless otherwise noted.

  5. These big business conglomerates are often called chaebols. Among developed countries, Japan shares similar industrial structure with Korea, in which large firms play a leading role in the economy (Johnson 1982).

  6. For details on Gibrat’s law and follow-up studies, see Sutton (1997) and Caves (1998).

  7. There are more relevant studies using data from European, Asian, and African countries: Dunne and Hughes (1994); Hart and Oulton (1996); Kumar (1985), and Reid (1993) using UK data; Contini and Revelli (1989) for Italian firms; Almus and Nerlinger (2000); Harhoff et al. (1998), and Wagner (1992) using West German data; Mata (1994) for Portuguese manufacturing firms; Weiss (1998) for Austrian firms; Liu et al. (1999) using Taiwan data; Yasuda (2005) for Japan, and finally, McPherson (1996) using data on five countries in Southern Africa.

  8. Jovanovic (1982) proposes the special assumptions under which Gibrat’s law still holds. If the distribution of firm efficiency is lognormal, firm growth is independent of size for firms of the same age. If firm costs are Cobb-Douglas with decreasing returns to scale, firm size is not relevant for age. If firm costs are Cobb-Douglas with decreasing returns to scale, firm size is not relevant for mature firms. However, these assumptions fail to be proved in Evans (1987a).

  9. Geroski et al. (2003), Del Monte and Papagni (2003), and Goddard et al. (2005) have shown results in support of Gibrat’s law. In contrast, Goddard et al. (2002), Chen and Lu (2003), Oliveira and Fortunato (2006) and Aslan (2008) demonstrated that Gibrat’s law does not hold.

  10. For example, Mansfield (1962) finds that the successfully innovating firms grow about twice as rapidly as other comparable firms. The rewards for successful innovation seem to have been substantial for the short-term growth of smaller firms.

  11. Other difficulties in relation to subcontracting transactions include the receipt of irregular and unexpected orders (47.2%) and sudden curtailment of delivery terms (39.2%) (Korea Federation of Small and Medium Business 2007).

  12. In 2004, more than half of subcontracted firms partly or totally re-subcontracted their work to other firms (Korea Federation of Small and Medium Business 2005). The gap between big firms and SMEs in terms of the profit rate and productivity has become wider (ibid.).

  13. The Korean government conceals information of certain firms for the purpose of confidentiality. For example, if a firm is the only one to run the business of a particular industry in an administration district, data on this company are missing. In order to secure as much data as possible, the two-digit industry code is used instead of the five-digit one following the Korea Standard Industrial Classification.

  14. Usually, “exit” of a firm means that the firm fails and disappears during the observation period. However, in this paper, firms in which the number of employees has shrunk below five are also regarded as the exiting firms due to the survey design.

  15. There are alternative ways to measure the extent of firm growth, such as sales or employment of a firm. According to Delmar (1997), 30.9% of the previous studies on firm growth relied on the sales variable, while 29.1% of studies used the number of employees of a firm as the measure of firm growth. However, the employment size is regarded as most reliable in terms of data quality compared to alterative measures (Liu et al. 1999). Using the size of employment as the proxy of firm size, we were able to compare the case of Korean manufacturing firms with other studies on developed countries without facing with the measurement incompatibility across studies (Acs and Audretsch 1990; Evans 1987a, b; Farinos and Moreno 2000; Harhoff et al. 1998; Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development 2002).

  16. The major industry is defined as the industry of the highest concentration ratio within a cluster. The concentration ratio of an industry within a cluster is calculated by dividing the number of employees in a given industry into that of all firms in a given cluster. The variable of “major industry” is used as the indicator for the density of networking among firms in the same industry within a cluster. Industry is classified according to the two-digit Korean Standard Industrial Classification.

  17. Results of Table 1 on differences in characteristics between surviving firms and all firms are all statistically significant at the 5% level by the mean equivalence test.

  18. Details on how to obtain the LQ variable may be derived from Bennet et al. (1999) and Fingleton et al. (2004).

  19. This issue is acknowledged and empirically investigated in many studies related to Gibrat’s law using US and European countries, such as Dunne and Hughes (1994), Hall (1987), Harhoff et al. (1998), Mata (1994), and Weiss (1998).

  20. As it is not easy to directly investigate the relationships among firm size, age, and growth due to their quadratic and interaction coefficients, the percentage of firms of which partial derivatives of the growth function with respect to size and age are positive (or negative) is computed using the estimates of model (4): for 96.3% of all firms, size effects were negative, and for 93.5% of all firms, age effects were negative. This result shows that, in most firms, firm size and age have a negative effect on firm growth, which confirms the result of most previous studies, including Evans (1987a, b).

  21. Insignificance of subcontracting effect on growth is also inconsistent with Song et al. (2004), who suggest that the subcontracting firm is less likely to grow due to excessive price-cut demand from the parent company.

  22. Technically, different data sources and variable definitions may also bring on ambiguity in empirical results. Yasuda’s study (2005) is based on Japanese manufacturing firms with 50 employees or more and subcontracting firms for only one parent company. This paper, on the other hand, deals with Korean firms with five employees or more, and subcontracting is limited to the form that the parent company provides material for subcontractors.

  23. According to a staff member of the Korea Industrial Complex Managing Corporation, positive externalities through industrial networking itself may be weak in the case of the Korean industrial complex. Nevertheless, comparative advantages of clustered firms certainly are derived from well-established infrastructure. He also mentioned that policy supports, mainly tax exemption and subsidy, played a role in firm growth and survival in a cluster (interviewed on 16 February 2006).

References

  • Acs, Z. J., & Audretsch, D. B. (1990). Innovation and small firms. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Almus, M., & Nerlinger, E. A. (2000). Testing Gibrat’s Law for young firms—empirical results for West Germany. Small Business Economics, 15(1), 1–12.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Altenburg, T., & Meyer-stamer, J. (1999). How to promote clusters: Policy experiences from Latin America. World Development, 27(9), 1693–1713.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aslan, A. (2008). Testing Gibrat’s law: Empirical evidence from panel unit root tests of Turkish firms. International Research Journal of Finance and Economies, 16, 137–142.

    Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D. B., Klomp, L., Santarelli, E., & Thurik, A. R. (2004). Gibrat’s law: Are the services different? Review of Industrial Organization, 24(3), 301–324.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bennet, R. J., Graham, D. J., & Bratton, W. (1999). The location and concentration of business in Britain: Business clusters, business services, market coverage and local economic development. Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers, New Series, 24, 393–420.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berry, A. (1997). SME competitiveness: The power of networking and subcontracting. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bok, D. K., Koh, J. M., Shim, S. M., & Koh, Y. S. (2002). Strategies for developing industrial clusters and related Korean and overseas case. Seoul: Samsung Economics Research Institute (in Korean).

  • Caves, R. (1998). Industrial organization and new findings on the turnover and mobility of firms. Journal of Economic Literature, 36(4), 1947–1982.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen, M. C. (2002). Industrial district and social capital in Taiwan’s economic development. Ph.D. Dissertation, Yale University.

  • Chen, J., & Lu, W. (2003). Panel unit root tests of firm size and its growth. Applied Economics Letters, 10(6), 343–345.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cho, Y. S. (2005). Forecasting on the shape of innovative cluster in Seoul digital complex and policy theme. Korean Regional Development Association Paper, 17(1), 73–90 (in Korean).

    Google Scholar 

  • Contini, B., & Revelli, R. (1989). The relationship between firm growth and labor demand. Small Business Economics, 1(4), 309–314.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Das, S. (1995). Size, age and firm growth in an infant industry: The computer hardware industry in India. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 13(1), 111–125.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeCarolis, D. M., & Deeds, D. L. (1999). The impact of stocks and flows of organizational knowledge on firm performance: An empirical investigation of the biotechnology industry. Strategic Management Journal, 20(10), 953–968.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Del Monte, A., & Papagni, E. (2003). R&D and the growth of firms: An empirical analysis of a panel of Italian firms. Research Policy, 32(6), 1003–1014.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Delmar, F. (1997). Measuring growth: Methodological considerations and empirical results. In D. Donckels & A. Miettinen (Eds.), Entrepreneurship and SME Research: On its way to the next millennium. Aldershot, UK: Ashgate.

    Google Scholar 

  • Delmar, F., Davidsson, P., & Gartner, W. (2003). Arriving at the high-growth firm. Journal of Business Venturing, 18(2), 189–216.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doms, M., Dunne, T., & Roberts, M. J. (1995). The role of technology use in the survival and growth of manufacturing plants. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 13, 523–542.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dore, R. (1983). Goodwill and the sprit of market capitalism. British Journal of Society, 34, 459–482.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dunne, P., & Hughes, A. (1994). Age, size, growth and survival: UK companies in the 1980s. Journal of Industrial Economics, 42(2), 115–140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dunne, T., Roberts, M. J., & Samuelson, L. (1989). The growth and failure of manufacturing plants. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 104, 671–698.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ericson, R., & Pakes, A. (1995). Markov-perfect industry dynamics: A framework for empirical work. The Review of Economics Studies, 62(1), 53–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Evans, D. S. (1987a). Tests of alternative theories of firm growth. Journal of Political Economy, 95(4), 657–674.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Evans, D. S. (1987b). The relationship between firm growth, size and age: Estimates for 100 manufacturing industries. Journal of Industrial Economics, 35(4), 567–581.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farinos, J. C., & Moreno, L. (2000). Firms’ growth, size and age: A nonparametric approach. Review of Industrial Organization, 17, 249–265.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fingleton, B., Igliori, C., & Moore, B. (2004). Employment growth of small high-technology firms and the role of horizontal clustering: Evidence from computing services and R&D in Great Britain, 1991–2000. Urban Studies, 41(4), 773–799.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • FitzRoy, F. R., & Kraft, K. (1991). Firm size, growth and innovation: Some evidence from West Germany. In Z. J. Acs & D. B. Audretsch (Eds.), Innovation and technological change: An international comparison. New York: Harvester Wheatsheaf.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, D. (1988). The misunderstood miracle: Industrial development and political change in Japan. New York: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Geroski, P. A. (1995). What do we know about entry? International Journal of Industrial Organization, 13(4), 421–440.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geroski, P. A., Lazarova, S., Urga, G., & Walters, F. (2003). Are differences in firm size transitory or permanent? Journal of Applied Econometrics, 18(1), 47–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gibrat, R. (1931). Les Inegalites Economiques. Paris: Librairie du Recueil Sirey.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goddard, J., McKillop, D., & Wilson, J. (2005). Panel unit root tests of the size and growth of large US credit unions. Managerial Finance, 31(11), 36–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goddard, J., Wilson, J., & Blandon, P. (2002). Panel tests of Gibrat’s law for Japanese manufacturing. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 20(3), 415–433.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grabher, G. (1993). The embedded firm: On the socioeconomics of industrial networks. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, B. H. (1987). The relationship between firm size and firm growth in the US manufacturing sector. Journal of Industrial Economics, 35(4), 583–606.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harhoff, D., Stahl, K., & Woywode, M. (1998). Legal form, growth and exit of West German firms–empirical results for manufacturing, construction, trade and service industries. Journal of Industrial Economics, 46(4), 453–488.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hart, P. E., & Oulton, N. (1996). Growth and size of firms. Economic Journal, 106(3), 1242–1252.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hassink, R. (2001). Towards regionally embedded innovation support systems in South Korea? Case studies from kyongbuk-taegu and kyonggi. Urban Studies, 38(8), 1373–1395.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayashi, M. (2005). SMEs, subcontracting and economic development in Indonesia: With reference to Japan’s experience. Tokyo: Japan International Cooperation Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heckman, J. (1979). Sample selection bias as a specification error. Econometrica, 47(1), 153–161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heshmati, A. (2001). On the growth of micro and small firms: Evidence from Sweden. Small Business Economics, 17, 213–228.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hill, J., & Naroff, J. L. (1984). The effect of location on the performance of high-technology firms. Financial Management, 13, 27–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hymer, S., & Pashigian, P. (1962). Firm size and rate of growth. Journal of Political Economy, 52, 556–569.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iammarino, S., & McCann, P. (2006). The structure and evolution of industrial clusters: Transactions, technology and knowledge spillovers. Research Policy, 35(7), 1018–1036.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Im, K., Pesaran, H., & Shin, Y. (2003). Testing for unit roots in heterogeneous panels. Journal of Econometrics, 115, 53–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, C. (1982). MITI and the Japanese miracle: The growth of industrial policy (pp. 1925–1975). Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jovanovic, B. (1982). Selection and evolution of industry. Econometrica, 50, 649–670.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koh, S. C. (2004). The formation of innovative clusters and schemes for developing them in Korea. Korean Regional Development Association, presented at the summer science meeting (in Korean).

  • Korea Federation of Small and Medium Business. (2005). Survey of small and medium enterprises. Seoul: KFSB (in Korean).

    Google Scholar 

  • Korea Federation of Small and Medium Business. (2007). Survey of small and medium enterprises. Seoul: KFSB (in Korean).

    Google Scholar 

  • Korea Ministry of Commerce, Industry, Energy, and Korea Industrial Complex Corporation. (2008). Statistics on industrial complex in Korea. Seoul: KICC (in Korean).

    Google Scholar 

  • Korea National Statistical Office. (2004). The report on Industrial Census 2003. Seoul: KNSO (in Korean).

    Google Scholar 

  • Kumar, M. S. (1985). Growth, acquisition activity and firm size: Evidence from the United Kingdom. Journal of Industrial Economics, 33(3), 327–338.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu, J. T., Tsou, M. W., & Hammitt, J. K. (1999). Do small plants grow faster? Evidence from the Taiwan electronics industry. Economics Letters, 65(1), 121–129.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lotti, F., Santarelli, E., & Vivarelli, M. (2003). Does Gibrat’s Law hold among young, small firms? Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 13(3), 213–235.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield, E. (1962). Entry, Gibart’s law, innovation, and the growth of firms. American Economic Review, 52(5), 1023–1051.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, A. (1920). Principles of economics. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mata, J. (1994). Firm growth during infancy. Small Business Economics, 6, 27–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McDougall, P. P., & Oviatt, B. M. (1997). International entrepreneurship literature in 1990s and directions for future research. In D. L. Sexton & R. W. Smilor (Eds.), Entrepreneurship 2000 (pp. 291–320). Chicago, IL: Upstart.

    Google Scholar 

  • McPherson, M. A. (1996). Growth of micro and small enterprises in Southern Africa. Journal of Development Economics, 48(2), 253–277.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Narula, R., & Santangelo, G. (forthcoming). Location, collocation and R&D alliances in the European ICT industry. Research Policy.

  • Nishiguchi, T. (1994). Strategic industrial sourcing: The Japanese advantage. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nugent, J. B. (1996). What explains the trend reversal in the size distribution of Korean manufacturing establishments? Journal of Development Economics, 48, 225–251.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nugent, J. B., & Yhee, S. J. (2002). Small and medium enterprises in Korea: Achievements, constraints and policy issues. Small Business Economics, 18(1), 85–119.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oliveira, B., & Fortunato, A. (2006). Testing Gibrat’s law: Empirical evidence from a panel of Portuguese manufacturing firms. International Journal of the Economics of Business, 13(1), 65–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development. (1999). Boosting innovation: The cluster approach. Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development. (2001). Innovative clusters: Drivers of national innovation systems. Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development. (2002). High-growth SMEs and employment. Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • Park, Y. (2006). Essays on industrial networking and small and medium firms. Ph.D. Dissertation, KDI School of Public Policy and Management.

  • Pavitt, K. (1987). On the nature of technology. Mimeo, Science Policy Research Unit, University of Sussex.

  • Piore, M. J., & Sabel, C. F. (1984). The second industrial divide: Possibilities for prosperity. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Porter, M. (1990). The competitive advantage of nations. New York: The Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Porter, M. (1998). On competition. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Powell, W. (1990). Neither market nor hierarchy: Network forms of organization. Research in Organizational Behavior, 12, 295–336.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rauch, J. E. (1999). Networks versus markets in international trade. Journal of International Economics, 48, 7–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reid, G. C. (1993). Growth and its determinants. In Small business enterprises: An economic analysis (pp. 187–207). New York, NY: Routledge.

  • Samuels, J. M. (1965). Size and growth of firms. Review of Economic Studies, 32(1), 105–112.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saxenian, A. L. (1994). Regional advantage: Culture and competition in silicon valley and Route 128. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Seo, J. D., & Park, S. C. (2003). A study for the development of the Korean industrial complex. Seoul: Korea Small Business Institute (in Korean).

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. A., & Bonini, C. P. (1958). The size distribution of business firms. American Economic Review, 48(4), 607–617.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A., & Whittington, G. (1975). The size and growth of firms. Review of Economic Studies, 42(1), 15–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Song, C. J., et al. (2004). A study for developing cooperative business model between large and small companies. Seoul: Korean Small Business Institute (in Korean).

    Google Scholar 

  • Sutton, J. (1997). Gibrat’s legacy. Journal of Economic Literature, 35(1), 40–59.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, J. (1992). Firm size, firm growth, and persistence of chance: Testing Gibrat’s Law with establishment data from lower Saxony. Small Business Economics, 4(2), 125–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weiss, C. R. (1998). Size, growth, and survival in the upper Austrian farm sector. Small Business Economics, 10(4), 305–312.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • White, H. (1980). A Heteroscedasticity—consistent covariance matrix estimator and a direct test for heteroscedasticity. Econometrica, 48(4), 817–838.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wynarczyk, P., & Watson, R. (2005). Firm growth and supply chain partnerships: An empirical analysis of U. K. SME subcontractors. Small Business Economics, 24(1), 39–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yasuda, T. (2005). Firm growth, size, age and behavior in Japanese manufacturing. Small Business Economics, 24(1), 1–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jaeun Shin.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Park, Y., Shin, J. & Kim, T. Firm size, age, industrial networking, and growth: a case of the Korean manufacturing industry. Small Bus Econ 35, 153–168 (2010). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-009-9177-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-009-9177-7

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation