Advertisement

The Review of Austrian Economics

, Volume 22, Issue 3, pp 209–224 | Cite as

A reformulation of the foundations of welfare economics

  • Randall G. Holcombe
Article

Abstract

Neoclassical welfare economics takes an outcome-oriented approach that uses Pareto optimality as its benchmark for welfare maximization. When one looks at the remarkable improvements in economic welfare that have characterized market economies, most of those improvements in welfare have been due to economic progress that has introduced new and improved goods and services into the economy, and innovations in production methods that have brought costs down, leading to higher real incomes. Pareto optimality is only peripherally related to actual economic welfare, and no economist would argue that people are materially better off today than a century ago because the economy is closer to Pareto optimality. After analyzing the actual factors that lead to improvements in welfare, this paper suggests a reformulation of the foundations of welfare economics to replace the almost irrelevant outcome-oriented concept of Pareto optimality as the benchmark for evaluating welfare with a process-oriented benchmark based on factors that generate economic progress. The paper then explores some implications of this reformulation.

Keywords

Welfare economics Pareto optimality Economic growth Economic progress 

JEL

B53 D60 

References

  1. Alchian, A. A. (1950). Uncertainty, evolution, and economic theory. Journal of Political Economy, 58(no. 3), 211–222.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Armentano, D. T. (1972). The myths of antitrust: economic theory and legal cases. New Rochelle: Arlington House.Google Scholar
  3. Arrow, K. J., & Debreu, G. (1954). Existence of an equilibrium for a competitive economy. Econometrica, 22(no. 3), 265–290.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Bator, F. M. (1957). The simple analytics of welfare maximization. American Economic Review, 47(no. 1), 22–59.Google Scholar
  5. Bator, F. M. (1958). The anatomy of market failure. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 72(no. 3), 351–379.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Baumol, W. J. (1990). Entrepreneurship: productive, unproductive, and destructive. Journal of Political Economy, 98(no. 5, Part1), 893–921.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Beinhocker, E. D. (2006). The origin of wealth: evolution, complexity, and the radical remaking of economics. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.Google Scholar
  8. Buchanan, J. M. (1969). Cost and choice: an inquiry in economic theory. Chicago: Markham.Google Scholar
  9. Caldwell, B. J. (1982). Beyond positivism: economic methodology in the twentieth century. London: George Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
  10. Caplan, B. (1999). The Austrian search for realistic foundations. Southern Economic Journal, 65(no. 4), 823–838.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Coase, R. H. (1960). The problem of social cost. Journal of Law & Economics, 3, 1–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Cordato, R. E. (1992). Welfare economics and externalities in an open-ended universe: a modern Austrian perspective. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers.Google Scholar
  13. Cox, W. M., & Alm, R. (1999). Myths of rich and poor: why we’re better off than we think. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
  14. de V Graaf, J. (1957). Theoretical welfare economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  15. Frey, B. S., & Stutzer, A. (2001). Happiness and economics: how the economy and institutions affect human well-being. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  16. Friedman, M. (1953). Essays in positive economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  17. Gwartney, J., & Lawson, R. (2007). Economic freedom of the world: 2007 report. Vancouver: Fraser Institute.Google Scholar
  18. Hayek, F. (1945). The use of knowledge in society. American Economic Review, 35(no. 4), 519–530.Google Scholar
  19. Herbener, J. M. (1997). The Pareto rule and welfare economics. Review of Austrian Economics, 10(no. 1), 79–106.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Hicks, J. R. (1939). Value and capital: an inquiry into some fundamental principles of economic theory. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
  21. Holcombe, R. G. (1989). Economic models and methodology. New York: Greenwood.Google Scholar
  22. Holcombe, R. G. (2008). Why does government produce national defense? Public Choice, 137(nos. 1/2), 11–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Kahneman, D. (2003). Maps of bounded rationality: psychology for behavioral economics. American Economic Review, 93(no. 5), 1449–1475.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. L., & Thaler, R. H. (1991). Anomalies: the endowment effect, loss aversion, and status quo bias. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5(no. 1), 193–206.Google Scholar
  25. Kirzner, I. M. (1973). Competition and entrepreneurship. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  26. Kohn, M. (2004). Value and exchange. Cato Journal, 24(no. 3), 303–339.Google Scholar
  27. Lakatos, I. (1978). The methodology of scientific research programmes, vol. 1. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  28. Landes, D. S. (1998). The wealth and poverty of nations: why some are so rich and some so poor. New York: W.W. Norton.Google Scholar
  29. Lipsey, R. G., & Lancaster, K. (1956). The general theory of second best. Review of Economic Studies, 24(no. 1), 11–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Lucas, R. E., Jr. (1988). On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics, 22, 3–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Marshall, A. (1920). Principles of economics (8th ed.). London: Macmillan. [1st ed. 1890].Google Scholar
  32. McCloskey, D. M. (1985). The rhetoric of economics. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.Google Scholar
  33. Moykr, J. (1990). The lever of riches. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  34. Nelson, R. R., & Winter, S. G. (1982). An evolutionary theory of economic change. Cambridge: Belknap.Google Scholar
  35. Pigou, A. C. (1962). The economics of welfare (4th ed.). London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  36. Prychitko, D. L. (1993). Formalism in Austrian School Welfare Economics: another pretense of knowledge? Critical Review, 7(no. 4), 567–592.Google Scholar
  37. Romer, P. M. (1986). Increasing returns and long-run growth. Journal of Political Economy, 94, 1002–1037.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Romer, P. M. (1990). Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy, 98(No. 5, Part 2), S71–S102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Rothbard, M. N. (1956). Toward a reconstruction of utility and welfare economics. In M. Sennholz (Ed.), On freedom and free enterprise: essays in honor of Ludwig von Mises. Princeton: D. Van Nostrand.Google Scholar
  40. Rothbard, M. N. (2004). Man, economy, and state with power and market. Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.Google Scholar
  41. Samuelson, P. A. (1947). Foundations of economic analysis. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  42. Samuelson, P. A. (1954). The pure theory of public expenditure. Review of Economics and Statistics, 36, 387–389.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  43. Samuelson, P. A. (1955). A diagrammatic exposition of a theory of public expenditure. Review of Economics and Statistics, 37, 350–356.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Samuelson, P. A. (1956). Social indifference curves. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 73(no. 1), 1–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  45. Samuelson, P. A. (1973). Economics (9th ed.). New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
  46. Schumpeter, J. A. (1934). The theory of economic development. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  47. Schumpeter, J. A. (1950). Capitalism, socialism, and democracy (3rd ed.). London: George Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
  48. Sen, A. (1992). Inequality reexamined. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  49. Smith, A. (1937). The wealth of nations. New York: Modern Library. [orig. 1776].Google Scholar
  50. Smith, V. L. (1974). Economic theory and its discontents. American Economic Review, 64(no. 2), 320–322.Google Scholar
  51. Solow, R. M. (1956). A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70, 65–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  52. von Mises, L. (1951). Socialism. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC 2009

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Department of EconomicsFlorida State UniversityTallahasseeUSA

Personalised recommendations