Skip to main content
Log in

A reformulation of the foundations of welfare economics

  • Published:
The Review of Austrian Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Neoclassical welfare economics takes an outcome-oriented approach that uses Pareto optimality as its benchmark for welfare maximization. When one looks at the remarkable improvements in economic welfare that have characterized market economies, most of those improvements in welfare have been due to economic progress that has introduced new and improved goods and services into the economy, and innovations in production methods that have brought costs down, leading to higher real incomes. Pareto optimality is only peripherally related to actual economic welfare, and no economist would argue that people are materially better off today than a century ago because the economy is closer to Pareto optimality. After analyzing the actual factors that lead to improvements in welfare, this paper suggests a reformulation of the foundations of welfare economics to replace the almost irrelevant outcome-oriented concept of Pareto optimality as the benchmark for evaluating welfare with a process-oriented benchmark based on factors that generate economic progress. The paper then explores some implications of this reformulation.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. It may be possible to further increase social welfare if redistribution would lower the utility of those from whom resources were transferred less than it would add to the utility of the recipients of those resources, following Samuelson (1956).

  2. Second-hand smoke can be considered an external cost, of course, but can be limited by clearly defined property rights to determine where someone can smoke, and at any rate is more limited than the health care costs described in the next sentence. The externality of second-hand smoke can spread throughout an entire room. The externality generated by publicly funded health care can spread throughout an entire nation. And, if transaction costs within a room are low, then following Coase (1960) bargaining among individuals can internalize the externality of second-hand smoke.

  3. This is the idea behind revealed preference, and the idea behind what Rothbard (1956) calls demonstrated preference. Rothbard (1956) should be acknowledged because the title of this paper is similar to his title. While there is some similarity in the ideas also, criticisms of Rothbard by Cordato (1992), Prychitko (1993), and Caplan (1999) are well-taken.

  4. Kirzner (1973) would clearly separate the function of the entrepreneur from that of the investor, but Rothbard (2004: 64) indicates that entrepreneurship consists not only of the entrepreneur spotting a profit opportunity, but also acting on it so that he has “invested accordingly.”

  5. For a critique of this theory, see Holcombe (2008).

  6. In the taxonomy given by the Journal of Economic Literature classification system, welfare economics is classification D6, under the heading of Microeconomics. Growth theory is classification O4, under the heading of Economic Development, Technological Change, and Growth.

  7. Within a general equilibrium framework, if the economy is in equilibrium and then a Schumpeterian entrepreneur disturbs that equilibrium, producing creative destruction, the economy moves from a Pareto optimum away to a situation that is not Pareto optimal, which generates economic progress and is welfare-enhancing. The caveat here is that the economy may not be resting at a Pareto optimum, so one cannot know whether the change moves away from Pareto optimality. Because Pareto optimality is non-observable, one can never, in fact, say that an actual economy is moving closer, or further from, a Pareto optimum.

References

  • Alchian, A. A. (1950). Uncertainty, evolution, and economic theory. Journal of Political Economy, 58(no. 3), 211–222.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Armentano, D. T. (1972). The myths of antitrust: economic theory and legal cases. New Rochelle: Arlington House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J., & Debreu, G. (1954). Existence of an equilibrium for a competitive economy. Econometrica, 22(no. 3), 265–290.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bator, F. M. (1957). The simple analytics of welfare maximization. American Economic Review, 47(no. 1), 22–59.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bator, F. M. (1958). The anatomy of market failure. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 72(no. 3), 351–379.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W. J. (1990). Entrepreneurship: productive, unproductive, and destructive. Journal of Political Economy, 98(no. 5, Part1), 893–921.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beinhocker, E. D. (2006). The origin of wealth: evolution, complexity, and the radical remaking of economics. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1969). Cost and choice: an inquiry in economic theory. Chicago: Markham.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caldwell, B. J. (1982). Beyond positivism: economic methodology in the twentieth century. London: George Allen & Unwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caplan, B. (1999). The Austrian search for realistic foundations. Southern Economic Journal, 65(no. 4), 823–838.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (1960). The problem of social cost. Journal of Law & Economics, 3, 1–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cordato, R. E. (1992). Welfare economics and externalities in an open-ended universe: a modern Austrian perspective. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cox, W. M., & Alm, R. (1999). Myths of rich and poor: why we’re better off than we think. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • de V Graaf, J. (1957). Theoretical welfare economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. S., & Stutzer, A. (2001). Happiness and economics: how the economy and institutions affect human well-being. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. (1953). Essays in positive economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gwartney, J., & Lawson, R. (2007). Economic freedom of the world: 2007 report. Vancouver: Fraser Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. (1945). The use of knowledge in society. American Economic Review, 35(no. 4), 519–530.

    Google Scholar 

  • Herbener, J. M. (1997). The Pareto rule and welfare economics. Review of Austrian Economics, 10(no. 1), 79–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J. R. (1939). Value and capital: an inquiry into some fundamental principles of economic theory. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R. G. (1989). Economic models and methodology. New York: Greenwood.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R. G. (2008). Why does government produce national defense? Public Choice, 137(nos. 1/2), 11–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D. (2003). Maps of bounded rationality: psychology for behavioral economics. American Economic Review, 93(no. 5), 1449–1475.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. L., & Thaler, R. H. (1991). Anomalies: the endowment effect, loss aversion, and status quo bias. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5(no. 1), 193–206.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirzner, I. M. (1973). Competition and entrepreneurship. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

  • Kohn, M. (2004). Value and exchange. Cato Journal, 24(no. 3), 303–339.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lakatos, I. (1978). The methodology of scientific research programmes, vol. 1. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Landes, D. S. (1998). The wealth and poverty of nations: why some are so rich and some so poor. New York: W.W. Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lipsey, R. G., & Lancaster, K. (1956). The general theory of second best. Review of Economic Studies, 24(no. 1), 11–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. E., Jr. (1988). On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics, 22, 3–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, A. (1920). Principles of economics (8th ed.). London: Macmillan. [1st ed. 1890].

    Google Scholar 

  • McCloskey, D. M. (1985). The rhetoric of economics. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moykr, J. (1990). The lever of riches. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. R., & Winter, S. G. (1982). An evolutionary theory of economic change. Cambridge: Belknap.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pigou, A. C. (1962). The economics of welfare (4th ed.). London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prychitko, D. L. (1993). Formalism in Austrian School Welfare Economics: another pretense of knowledge? Critical Review, 7(no. 4), 567–592.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P. M. (1986). Increasing returns and long-run growth. Journal of Political Economy, 94, 1002–1037.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P. M. (1990). Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy, 98(No. 5, Part 2), S71–S102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rothbard, M. N. (1956). Toward a reconstruction of utility and welfare economics. In M. Sennholz (Ed.), On freedom and free enterprise: essays in honor of Ludwig von Mises. Princeton: D. Van Nostrand.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothbard, M. N. (2004). Man, economy, and state with power and market. Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1947). Foundations of economic analysis. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1954). The pure theory of public expenditure. Review of Economics and Statistics, 36, 387–389.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1955). A diagrammatic exposition of a theory of public expenditure. Review of Economics and Statistics, 37, 350–356.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1956). Social indifference curves. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 73(no. 1), 1–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1973). Economics (9th ed.). New York: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1934). The theory of economic development. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1950). Capitalism, socialism, and democracy (3rd ed.). London: George Allen & Unwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. (1992). Inequality reexamined. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A. (1937). The wealth of nations. New York: Modern Library. [orig. 1776].

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, V. L. (1974). Economic theory and its discontents. American Economic Review, 64(no. 2), 320–322.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow, R. M. (1956). A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70, 65–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • von Mises, L. (1951). Socialism. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Randall G. Holcombe.

Additional information

The author gratefully acknowledges helpful comments from an anonymous reviewer of this journal.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Holcombe, R.G. A reformulation of the foundations of welfare economics. Rev Austrian Econ 22, 209–224 (2009). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-009-0089-1

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-009-0089-1

Keywords

JEL

Navigation