Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Political realism and models of the state: Antonio de Viti de Marco and the origins of public choice

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Parliament became … the market where the favors of the state, both great and small, were negotiated. (De Viti de Marco 1930, p. vii).

Abstract

It is well known that one of the features of public choice, political realism, is embedded in a time-honored Italian tradition going back to Machiavelli and perpetuated by G. Mosca and V. Pareto in their political and sociological writings. The scientific spirit, which in their era led to the foundation of various social disciplines, fostered the application of economic analysis to the political sphere. In that context, Antonio de Viti de Marco (1858–1943) formulated an economic model of the state, consisting of two types of constitutional extremes: the absolute state and the democratic state. We ask herein how that model may be reconciled to G. Mosca and Pareto’s theory of the ruling class, with which De Viti de Marco agreed. Finally, we analyze his political writings in order to reconstruct his interpretation of collusion, rent seeking and “clientelism”, i.e., the redistribution of extracted rent, which takes place in the form of discretionary allocations of public jobs, public contracts and other corporative favors. Collusion is the use of democratic institutions by the ruling classes in order to gain monopoly power. While collusion is the basis of rent creation, rent extraction is not the final goal of politicians; rather, it is a means of strengthening electoral support.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Such as the growth of the public sector.

  2. See Moss (1991), who explains how one may at the same time go back to both Hobbes and Hume.

  3. See Ricci (1946, pp. 83–84) and Da Empoli (2004).

  4. See, for instance, Da Empoli (2015), who points out this difference between the Italian Scienza delle Finanze, the public choice school and the public economics tradition, which dates back to Wicksell, Lindhal, Musgrave and Peacock, among others.

  5. On the redefinition of the social sciences by that generation see Cardini (1986, p. 248; 1994, p. 191), while for sociology, see, for example, Bobbio (1972, pp. 38 ff.).

  6. Cardini (1986, p. 248) and Fusco (1994) mention these characteristics.

  7. Bobbio (1972, p. 42) writes that sociology for Pareto is “an introduction to the study of economics, not an independent discipline”. In this paper the translations are ours, where they are not already available.

  8. Medema (2005) notes that in Italy the separation of public finance from economics concerned both its scholarly literature and its educational curriculum.

  9. Finoia (1995, p. 10) recalls that the Italian polemic between free traders and interventionists was based on the conception of the state and its functions.

  10. Faucci (2000) illustrates the vigorous Italian reaction to the historicist movement of the 1890s. Cardini (1994) writes on the polemic of the Italian economists towards the German jurists and their doctrine of the state.

  11. Buchanan (1960) recognizes this characteristic in the Italian scholars.

  12. Einaudi (1936) writes that the Italian financial theory is based on the hypothesis of homo oeconomicus and that it traces the state back to economic individuals. This idea is confirmed by Da Empoli (1993) and Fausto (2003).

  13. The German and Italian scholars of public finance also are compared in Fossati (2003).

  14. Faucci (2000) writes that the eighteenth century Italian economists were subjectivists (value as a mental judgment), hedonists (the individual seeks to maximize pleasure) and utilitarians (the aim of society is to obtain “the greatest happiness for the greatest number”).

  15. The origin in Ferrara is pointed out in Buchanan (1960). Da Empoli (2004) states that Ferrara can be seen as an early representative of the subjectivist approach to economics.

  16. For a vivid description of the first steps in the foundation of public finance as pure theory, see Einaudi’s (1936) account.

  17. On this phase of the foundation of public finance in Italy, considerable literature exists. See, among many others, Da Empoli (1993, 2015) and Fausto (2003).

  18. On the Italian link between Scienza delle Finanze and public choice, see Fausto (2003), Wagner (2003), Mastromatteo (2003) and Medema (2005).

  19. Bobbio (1972, p. 68) and Faucci (2000) examine the influence of Marx on Pareto.

  20. Buchanan (2003) specifies in addition that governments were modelled by Marxists as furthering class interests, but governments that might be installed after the revolution would become both omniscient and benevolent.

  21. Together with that of Ferrara (Buchanan 1960); also see Sereno (1952). As an example of the international reputation of G. Mosca, see the review by Hartz (1959).

  22. They are both individualistic because in both models public choices emerge from relations between individuals with different preferences (Da Empoli 1995).

  23. Fausto (1995, p. 94) finds in Buchanan (1960) a contrasting interpretation of De Viti.

  24. In the words of Dallera (2003), “Public finance became a field of interest for political science and a theme for political sociology, sometimes as a political model, sometimes as a sociological model”.

  25. Italy was born in 1861 as a constitutional monarchy, in which the right to vote was restricted to 2% of the population.

  26. Wagner (2003), too, points out that “The neo-classical public finance that emerged in the late 19th century was articulated within a democratic political context”.

  27. In the words of Da Empoli (1993, p. 78) “All of the authors mentioned were staunch supporters of the market according to the liberal classical tradition and were very critical of governmental policies, whose rent-seeking aspects were … criticized by them on many occasions”.

  28. Da Empoli (1989) advanced the hypothesis that the individualistic approach in the study of public economics in Italy was born precisely from the wish to channel state intervention along more equitable and rational lines.

  29. We exclude some other topics, as for example the median voter (see, for instance, Da Empoli 2015).

  30. The first edition was published in 1928, the last in 1939.

  31. Together with Pantaleoni, Mazzola and then Pareto, he played a fundamental role in the rebirth of the Giornale degli economisti, for which he wrote Cronache (Chronicles) from 1897 to 1899; from 1911 to 1913 he published weekly in Il Popolo, a journal of his electoral constituency; in 1911, he began collaboration with G. Salvemini’s L’Unità, in which he wrote regularly from 1914 to 1920, while from 1916 to 1918 he was its co-director.

  32. For a detailed analysis of the financial calculation as a result of individual decisions in De Viti, see Dehove (1946, pp. 265–266) and Medema (2005, p. 12).

  33. In the words of De Viti ([1928] 1936, p. 42), “which wants and which individual and group interests help to form the State’s calculation of advantage and disadvantage, and which wants may happen to be excluded from this calculation?”.

  34. On this, see also Da Empoli (2004, p. 331).

  35. On this, Kayaalp (1998, p. 101) cites the expression of Bellanca “histoire raisonnée”. Fossati (2015) raises the problem of whether the method is logical or historical.

  36. We are referring here to the notion of ideal type associated with Max Weber.

  37. It is also interesting to see Buchanan (1985, p. 41) arguing that “It is, of course, no accident that constitutional democracy … emerged in the post-Enlightenment period, and that it finds intellectual support in the eighteenth century discovery of the spontaneous coordination properties of the market economy”.

  38. The conception of competition for the market, and not within the market, was found in De Viti’s paper on the telephone industry (De Viti de Marco 1890). That conception later was rediscovered by Chadwick and Demsetz (see M. Mosca 2007).

  39. That point also is reiterated by Buchanan (1975, p. 384): “De Viti de Marco explicitly constructed a model in which the consumers and the suppliers-producers of public goods make up the same community of persons”.

  40. See Fusco (1994, p. XIX), who quotes Einaudi in the introductory note.

  41. According to Fossati (2015), any (and every) political group can rise to power; as long as competition takes place through voting mechanisms, the current ruling group can be replaced by any other, and the group that is more efficient in the production of public goods will prevail.

  42. De Viti’s ([1928] 1936, p. 43) complete quote is: “we have merely to imagine that the alternation of the groups in control of the government takes place with sufficient rapidity, and we finally come to consider as practically identical the groups that are in turn governing and governed. This brings out exactly the concept of co-operative society, the essential characteristic of which lies in the personal identity of producers and consumers.”.

  43. Einaudi (1936) identifies the social compact as the basis of that idea. Fausto (2003, p. 13) writes: “the co-operative State … uses coercion to force citizens to comply with the social contract”.

  44. In his criticism of Arrow and Black’s ideas on majority cycles.

  45. In the following quotation, it would seem that an analogy also can be found between the two in the result: “majority decision making itself becomes a means through which the whole group ultimately attains consensus, that is, makes a genuine social choice. It serves to ensure that competing alternatives may be experimentally and provisionally adopted, tested, and replaced by new compromise alternatives approved by a majority group ever changing composition. This is democratic choice process” (Buchanan [1954] 1987, p. 176). But Buchanan’s (1959) essay seems to confirm the more prudent interpretation, which we have provided in the text.

  46. The absolute state for De Viti de Marco (1902–1903, p. 15) “answers to an historical truth [in which] the class that possesses the privileges of the state, looks after its own interests and not those of the ruled, as happened before the French Revolution for the first and second estates, to the prejudice of the third, ruled.”.

  47. Fossati (2015, p. 13) argues that De Viti was convinced that, in the historical moment in which he was living, the State was democratic or popular, insofar as “taxpayers vote the taxes”.

  48. De Viti’s letter to B. Griziotti, quoted in Cardini (1985, p. 13).

  49. Eusepi and Wagner (2013), are an exception, i.e., they recognize that characteristic, even if briefly. They studied the specific subject of De Viti de Marco’s formulation of tax prices, and the importance of constitutional arrangements in his theory of public finance. Petretto (2014) links the work of De Viti with political economy. Fossati (2015, p. 6) cites Rossi’s review: “De Viti sometimes moves away from the polar case of cooperative state, and thus his wording becomes complex and confusing”.

  50. Fossati (2015), in an article that is a complete, critical re-reading of the Principles, compares the theoretical framework with the concrete issues, but by the latter Fossati does not mean the political and fiscal situation actually existing in De Viti’s time, but rather the various topics public finance dealt with in the Principles themselves (such as the effects of taxation, discussions of public debt, the theories of progressivity-proportionality of taxes).

  51. Bobbio (1972, p. 19 and p. 25) does the same with G. Mosca.

  52. And, in fact, Buchanan (1983, p. 13), concerning the hypothesis of homo oeconomicus as a foundation of public choice, refers to De Viti. The latter, as in the public choice approach, “assumes that representatives, like voters, are rational, economic men bent on maximizing their utilities” (Mueller 1976, § III).

  53. “Until the direct-democratic ideal is attained … within the framework of the ubiquitous representative-democratic constitutional system, not the taxpayers but their elected agents will continue to decide … what public goods to produce and how to distribute the tax burden among the constituents” (Kayaalp 1998, pp. 101–102).

  54. In Papa’s (1965, p. 192) words, “De Viti was immune to suggestions of the myth of good government”.

  55. The expression “rent seeking” was first introduced by Krueger (1974).

  56. “Incomplete democracy” is in the title of De Viti’s political biography by Cardini (1985).

  57. Di Liddo and Giuranno (2016) show that incumbents increase rent extraction with cooperative, rather than non-cooperative, political behavior.

  58. We are aware that, when speaking of rent seeking, it would be interesting to confront De Viti with Tullock (1967, 2003), but this would lead us out of the main line of our inquiry. An examination in historical perspective of the work of Tullock along those lines will be the subject of further research.

  59. De Viti ([1898] 1930, p. 253) continues: “he can vote the duty on wheat, or the protectionist tariff, or the breaking of a treaty of commerce, or the African expedition, or war, or taxes; all this he can do; for moving a prefect or a magistrate, or for a pardon or an amnesty for fines, or for an arrangement with the tax officer”.

  60. On another occasion, he writes: “Otherwise, it would remain inexplicable what interest brought crowds of members of parliament from the South [of Italy] to Rome, with the task, apparently, of just passing laws of greater spoliation of their provinces” (De Viti de Marco [1894] 1930, p. 209).

  61. “Prefetto” and “Questore” are appointed by the central government.

  62. Here, we should note that De Viti anticipated the basis of the tradeoff between decision-making costs and external costs, which determines the optimal collective decision-making rule, later developed by Buchanan and Tullock (1962).

  63. The quotation continues: “The political battles, born of pretty careful scientific enquiry and reflection … often provided an experimental basis for theoretical research which on the other hand allowed him an overall view of the nature of the state and what it should be like” (Cardini 1994, p. 187).

  64. Already in G. Mosca, the contradiction between liberalism and a theory of the elites is apparent. See The Myth of the Ruling Class (Meisel 1958).

  65. Steve (1995, p. 44) answers our question like this: “it may be suggested that De Viti had hoped, up until the advent of Fascism, that the conditions for a democratic public finance could be reconstructed”.

  66. In Italy, women’s suffrage was introduced only in the 1946 elections.

  67. According to Cardini (1994, p. 189), De Viti believed that “the contemporary states were moving towards collective participation in the administration of the state”.

  68. He states that the US president does act “in defense of American interests; but these interests, for their scale, and for their recent and democratic origin, coincide with the immediate interests of the greater number and correspond to those of the lower strata of the countries of the civilized world” (De Viti de Marco [1917b] 1918, p. 144); also see Martelloni and Mosca (2018).

  69. “For some thirty to thirty-five years I have been fighting for the reform of the regime that you call bourgeois, denouncing its increasing privileges and degeneration, in the hope that the ruling class is capable of reforming itself. My life has gone by in this way, perhaps unprofitably” (De Viti de Marco 1920, p. 3787).

  70. Buchanan (1975, p. 385): “The Italians devoted much more attention to the implications of non-democratic political structures for the emergence and viability of fiscal institutions, on both the tax and the expenditure sides, than did their continental counterparts”. And, likewise, “Precursors of supply-side analysis can, of course, be found in the Italian theory of public finance in the non-democratic or monopolistic state. Models of this political structure were developed in some detail, models in which some ruling group or class collects taxes from the masses who are ruled and utilizes the proceeds to its own maximum advantage” (Buchanan 1975, p. 388). Buchanan (1978, p. 11) cites Machiavelli, Pareto, G. Mosca, De Viti, Puviani and Fasiani.

  71. In other words, to “model the way politics works, the way the state works” (Buchanan [2011] 2016, p. 130). What the American economist remembers asking in his 1949 work was to “pay some attention to the models of politics” (Buchanan 2003); in that path-breaking article, Buchanan cites De Viti several times. We agree with Da Empoli (1989, p. 16) that in Buchanan’s (1949) essay, De Viti de Marco’s influence is clear. De Viti’s influence on public choice also is recognized by Salsman (2017).

  72. Our interpretation contradicts that of Giardina (1992, p. 146), according to which De Viti’s theory does not allow us to go “deeper into public decision processes in systems of representative democracy”; in fact, Giardina puts Pareto “at the basis of the contemporary theories on pressure groups” (p. 164).

  73. And, as mentioned above, to many other Italians, and, in general, to Italian political culture.

  74. Incidentally, the subject we have examined also resolves other historiographical controversies. The first concerns De Viti’s place in the area of voluntary-exchange theory (Fausto 1995, p. 16). Our analysis leads us to conclude that De Viti’s political opinions actually recall the opposite, political-sociological approach. Boccaccio and De Bonis (2003) point out that the attention to institutions is a characteristic of the Italian tradition, to be found not only in authors adopting the political-sociological approach, but also the voluntary-exchange approach. The second controversy relates to the possibility of tracing the concept of “government failure” in De Viti’s thought. His interpreters don’t usually attribute that possibility to him; it is recognized by Medema (2005, p. 13), however, who anchors his analysis only on De Viti’s Principles, considering government failure therein as just a “potential” contribution (p. 14). The analysis of both the political and scientific writings of De Viti de Marco that we have carried out here also reveals his positions concerning those two watersheds in the history of political economic thought.

References

  • Black, D. (1958). The theory of committees and elections. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bobbio, R. (1971). Una filosofia militante. Studi su Carlo Cattaneo. Torino: Einaudi.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bobbio, R. (1972). On Mosca and Pareto. Genéve-Paris: Librairie Droz.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Boccaccio, M., & De Bonis, V. (2003). Political sociological theories in the Italian tradition of public finance. In D. Fausto & V. De Bonis (Eds.), The theory of public finance in Italy from the origins to the 1940s (pp. 75–98). Pisa-Roma: Istituti Editoriali e Poligrafici Internazionali.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1949). The pure theory of government finance: A suggested approach. Journal of Political Economy, 57(6), 496–505.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1954). Social choice, democracy and free markets. Journal of Political Economy, 114–123. Reprinted in Economics between predictive science and moral philosophy (Ch. 11). College Station: Texas A&M University Press, 1987.

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1959). Positive economics, welfare economics, and political economy. Journal of Law and Economics, 2, 124–138.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1960). “La scienza delle finanze”: The Italian tradition in fiscal theory. In Fiscal theory and political economy. Selected essays (pp. 24–74). Chapel Hill: The University of North Carolina Press.

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1975). Public finance and public choice. National Tax Journal, 28(4), 383–395.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1978). From private preferences to public philosophy. In The economics of politics (pp. 3–20). Lancing: The Institute of Economic Affairs.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1983). The public choice perspective. Economia delle Scelte Pubbliche, 1, 7–15.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1985). Constitutional democracy, individual liberty and political equality. Jahrbuch für neue politische Ökonomie, 4, 35–47.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1990). Ricordo di un anno in Italia. In Libertà nel contratto costituzionale, edited by P. Marelli (pp. XIII–XXII). Milano: Il Saggiatore. English trans. Economics from the outside, in “better than plowing” and beyond (pp. 82–92). College Station, Texas A&M University Press, 2007.

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1999). Politics without romance. A sketch of positive public choice theory and its normative implications. In J. M. Buchanan (Ed.), The collected works of James M. Buchanan. The logical foundations of constitutional liberty (Vol. I, pp. 45–59). Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (2003). Public choice: The origins and development of a research program. Fairfax: George Mason University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (2011). Scienza delle finanze and public choice. In M. Mosca (Ed.), Antonio de Viti de Marco. A story worth remembering (pp. 127–132). New York: Palgrave, 2016.

  • Buchanan, J., & Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Cardini, A. (1985). Antonio de Viti de Marco: la democrazia incompiuta. Rome: Laterza.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cardini, A. (1986). Gaetano Salvemini e Antonio de Viti de Marco. In G. Cingari (Ed.), Gaetano Salvemini tra politica e storia (pp. 248–276). Bari: Laterza.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cardini, A. (1994). Antonio de Viti de Marco. Economista e politico. Rivista di diritto finanziario e scienza delle finanze, 53(2), 187–205.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cardoza, A. L. (1986). Antonio de Viti de Marco: La democrazia incompiuta by Antonio Cardini, book review. The Journal of Modern History, 58(4), 967–969.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Congleton, R. D., & Hillman, A. L. (2015). Companion to the political economy of rent seeking. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Da Empoli, D. (1989). Introduzione. In J. M. Buchanan (Ed.), Stato, mercato e libertà (pp. 7–36). Bologna: Il Mulino.

    Google Scholar 

  • Da Empoli, D. (1993). Public choice in Italy. Public choice, 77(1), 75–83.

    Google Scholar 

  • Da Empoli, D. (1995). A proposito del “Carattere teorico dell’economia finanziaria”. In A. Pedone (Ed.), Antonio de Viti de Marco (pp. 51–54). Roma-Bari: Laterza.

    Google Scholar 

  • Da Empoli, D. (2004). The Italian public finance contribution to public choice. In C. K. Rowley & F. Schneider (Eds.), The encyclopedia of public choice (Vol. II, pp. 329–333). New York: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Da Empoli, D. (2015). Il “paradigma” italiano di finanza pubblica. Atti dei convegni Lincei, n., 290, 95–122.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dallera, G. (2003). The Italian tradition in fiscal theory: Taxation and efficiency. In D. Fausto & V. De Bonis (Eds.), The theory of public finance in Italy from the origins to the 1940s (pp. 123–158). Pisa-Roma: Istituti Editoriali e Poligrafici Internazionali.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Viti de Marco, A. (1888). Il carattere teorico dell’economia finanziaria. Roma: Pasqualucci.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Viti de Marco, A. (1890). L’industria dei telefoni e l’esercizio di Stato. Giornale degli economisti. Sept. 279–306. Engl. transl. The telephone industry and state exercise of said. In M. Baldassarri & P. Ciocca (Eds.), Roots of the Italian school of economics and finance: From Ferrara (1857) to Einaudi (1944) (III, pp. 505–529). New York: Palgrave, 2001.

  • De Viti de Marco, A. (1894). I moti siciliani. In A. De Viti de Marco (ED.), Un trentennio di lotte politiche (18941922) (pp. 201–219). Roma: Collezione Meridionale Editrice, 1930.

  • De Viti de Marco, A. (1896–1897). Scienza delle finanze e diritto finanziario. Lezioni del prof. A. De Viti De Marco compilate dagli studenti A. d’Adamo e A. Sonnino. Roma: Laudi.

  • De Viti de Marco, A. (1898). Dopo i tumulti di Milano. In A. De Viti de Marco (Ed.), Un trentennio di lotte politiche (18941922) (pp. 239–267). Roma: Collezione Meridionale Editrice, 1930.

  • De Viti de Marco, A. (1902–1903). Lezioni di scienza delle finanze raccolte e compilate da E. De Gaetani e V. Melillo. Roma: Tipo-lit. del Genio Civile.

  • De Viti de Marco, A. (1914a). Scienza delle finanze, lezioni compilate dal dottor C. Sampaolesi: Dama. Roma.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Viti de Marco, A. (1914b). Cause ed effetti delle vittorie bloccarde. La Stampa, 16 July.

  • De Viti de Marco, A. (1914c). Il problema doganale e l’attuale momento politico. In A. De Viti de Marco (Ed.), Un trentennio di lotte politiche (18941922) (pp. 165–198). Roma: Collezione Meridionale Editrice, 1930.

  • De Viti de Marco, A. (1917a). Un discorso di propaganda pacifista, 26 January. In A. De Viti de Marco (Ed.), La guerra europea: scritti e discorsi (pp. 123–127). Roma: Edizione dell’Unità, 1918.

  • De Viti de Marco, A. (1917b). Politica americana, 16 February. In A. De Viti de Marco (Ed.), La guerra europea: scritti e discorsi (pp. 137–145). Roma: Edizione dell’Unità, 1918.

  • De Viti de Marco, A. (1920). Atti parlamentari. Camera dei deputati. Roma, 22 July.

  • De Viti de Marco, A. (1922). Economie o imposte? In A. De Viti de Marco (Ed.), Un trentennio di lotte politiche (18941922) (pp. 411–446). Roma: Collezione Meridionale Editrice, 1930.

  • De Viti de Marco, A. (1928). First principles of public finance (p. 1936). London: Cape.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Viti de Marco, A. (1930). Un trentennio di lotte politiche (1894–1922). Roma: Collezione meridionale editrice.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dehove, G. (1946). L’œuvre scientifique de quelques économistes étrangers – L’œuvre financière d’Antonio de Viti de Marco. Revue d’économie politique, 56(3), 249–291.

    Google Scholar 

  • Di Liddo, G., & Giuranno, M. G. (2016). Asymmetric yardstick competition and municipal cooperation. Economics Letters, 141(C), 64–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Einaudi, L. (1934). Dove si discorre di Pareto, di Mosca ed anche di De Viti. La riforma sociale, 45, 707–711. Reprinted in Nuovi Saggi (pp. 367–371). Torino: Einaudi, 1937.

  • Einaudi, L. (1936). Introduction. In A. De Viti de Marco (Ed.), First principles of public finance (pp. 19–30). London: Cape.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eusepi, G., & Wagner, R. E. (2012). Indebted state versus intermediary state: Who owes what to whom. Constitutional Political Economy, 23(3), 199–212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eusepi, G., & Wagner, R. E. (2013). Tax prices in a democratic polity: The continuing relevance of Antonio de Viti de Marco. History of Political Economy, 45(1), 99–121.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Faucci, R. (1991). De Viti de Marco, Antonio. Dizionario biografico degli italiani (pp. 588–592). Roma: Istituto della Enciclopedia Italiana.

  • Faucci, R. (2000). L’economia politica italiana dal cinquecento ai nostri giorni. Torino: Utet.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fausto, D. (1995). I “Principii di economia finanziaria” nella letteratura straniera. In A. Pedone (Ed.), Antonio de Viti de Marco (pp. 80–102). Rome: Laterza.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fausto, D. (2003). An outline of the main Italian contributions to the theory of public finance. In D. Fausto & V. De Bonis (Eds.), The theory of public finance in Italy from the origins to the 1940s (pp. 11–41). Pisa-Roma: Istituti Editoriali e Poligrafici Internazionali.

    Google Scholar 

  • Felice, F. (2006). Le libéralisme radical des premières années du XXe siècle en Italie. Maffeo Pantaleoni - Antonio De Viti de Marco. In P. Nemo & J. Petiot (Eds.), Histoire du libéralisme en Europe (pp. 619–650). Paris: PUF.

    Google Scholar 

  • Finoia, M. (1995). Il pensiero economico italiano agli esordi di Antonio de Viti de Marco. In A. Pedone (Ed.), Antonio de Viti de Marco (pp. 3–16). Rome: Laterza.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fossati, A. (2003). Public goods in the Italian tradition. In D. Fausto & V. De Bonis (Eds.), The theory of public finance in Italy from the origins to the 1940s (pp. 99–122). Pisa: Istituti Editoriali e Poligrafici Internazionali.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fossati, A. (2015). The fiscal economics of Antonio de Viti de Marco revisited, mimeo.

  • Frosini, T. E. (2010). L’antiparlamentarismo e i suoi interpreti. In A. Cerri, P. Häberle, I. M. Jarvad, P. Ridola, & D. Schefold (Eds.), Il diritto tra interpretazione e storia (pp. 365–386). Roma: Aracne.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fusco, A. M. (1994). Nota introduttiva. In A. de Viti de Marco (Ed.), Un trentennio di lotte politiche (18941922), edited by A. M. Fusco (pp. XV-XLVI). Napoli: Giannini.

  • Giardina, E. (1992). Commentary. In A. Peacock (1992). Public choice analysis in historical perspective (pp. 145–167). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hartz, L. (1959). Review: The myth of the ruling class: Gaetano Mosca and the “Elite”, by James H. Meisel (Ann Arbor, The University of Michigan Press, 1958, pp. vi, 432), American Political Science Review, 53(3), 804–806.

  • Holcombe, R. G. (2015). Rent seeking and constitutional political economy. In R. D. Congleton & A. L. Hillman (Eds.), Companion to the political economy of rent seeking (pp. 473–487). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kayaalp, O. (1998). Antonio de Viti de Marco. In F. Meacci (Ed.), Italian economists of the twentieth century (pp. 95–113). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krueger, A. O. (1974). The political economy of the rent-seeking society. The American Economic Review, 64(3), 291–303.

    Google Scholar 

  • Martelloni, F., & Mosca, M. (2018). De Viti de Marco, the “European war” and president Wilson. Journal of the History of Economic Thought. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1053837217000037.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mastromatteo, G. (2003). The growth of public expenditure in the Italian theory of public finance. In D. Fausto & V. De Bonis (Eds.), The theory of public finance in Italy from the origins to the 1940s (pp. 221–242). Pisa-Roma: Istituti Editoriali e Poligrafici Internazionali.

    Google Scholar 

  • Medema, S. G. (2005). “Marginalizing” government: From la scienza delle finanze to Wicksell. History of Political Economy, 37(1), 1–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meisel, J. H. (1958). The myth of the ruling class: Gaetano Mosca and the “elite”. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mosca, M. (2007). The notion of market power for the Italian marginalists De Viti de Marco and Pantaleoni. In P. F. Asso & L. Fiorito (Eds.), Economics and institutions (pp. 47–61). Milano: Angeli.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mosca, M. (2015). “Io che sono un darwinista”. La visione di Maffeo Pantaleoni. Il pensiero economico italiano, 23(1), 23–45.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moss, L. S. (1991). Thomas Hobbes’s influence on David Hume: The emergence of a public choice tradition. History of Political Economy, 23(4), 587–612.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D. C. (1976). Public choice. A survey. Journal of Economic Literature, 14(2), 395–433.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pantaleoni, M. (1883). Contributo alla teoria del riparto delle spese pubbliche. Engl. transl. (partial) in R. A. Musgrave & A. T. Peacock, Classics in the theory of public finance (pp. 16–27). London: MacMillan, 1958.

  • Papa, A. (1965). Ritratti critici di contemporanei. Antonio de Viti de Marco. Belfagor, 2, 188–209.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peacock, A. (1992). Public choice analysis in historical perspective. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Pedone, A. (1998). Interview on Antonio de Viti de Marco, mimeo.

  • Petretto, A. (2014). The modern theory of regulation as an inheritance of De Viti de Marco’s cooperative state. History of Economic Thought and Policy, 10(2), 29–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ricci, U. (1946). In memoria di Antonio de Viti de Marco. Studi Economici, 1(1), 81–86.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rossi, E. (1948). A. de Viti de Marco. Uomo civile. Bari: Laterza.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rowley, C. K. (2004). Public choice from the perspective of the history of thought. In C. K. Rowley & F. Schneider (Eds.), The encyclopedia of public choice, I (pp. 201–214). New York: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Salsman, R. M. (2017). The political economy of public debt. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1954). The theory of public expenditure. Review of Economics and Statistics, 36(4), 386–389.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sereno, R. (1952). Note on Gaetano Mosca. The American Political Science Review, 46(2), 603–605.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steve, S. (1995). La finanza di Antonio de Viti de Marco. In A. Pedone (Ed.), Antonio de Viti de Marco (pp. 35–50). Rome: Laterza.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1967). The welfare costs of tariffs, monopolies, and theft. Western Economic Journal, 5(3), 224–232.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (2003). The origin of rent-seeking concept. International Journal of Business and Economics, 2(1), 1–8.

    Google Scholar 

  • Villani, A. (Ed.) (1991). Regole ed economia costituzionale. Una introduzione. In G. Brennan & J. M. Buchanan (Ed.), La ragione delle regole (pp. 9–72). Milano: Angeli.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, R. E. (2003). Public choice and the diffusion of classic Italian public finance. In D. Fausto & V. De Bonis (Eds.), The theory of public finance in Italy from the origins to the 1940s (pp. 271–282). Pisa-Roma: Istituti Editoriali e Poligrafici Internazionali.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

Paper presented at the AEA/ASSA Conference, San Francisco, 3–5 January 2016, the AISPE Conference, Lecce, 28–30 April 2016; the SIEP Annual meeting, 22–23 September 2016, Lecce, and the SIE Conference, 19–21 October 2017, Cosenza. The authors would like to thank Richard Wagner, Roger Congleton, Maria Cristina Marcuzzo, Roberto Cellini, Domenico da Empoli, Amedeo Fossati, Massimo Paradiso and the other participants in the sessions. Michele Giuranno is grateful to Gabriella Punzi for her valuable research assistantship. We also thank two anonymous referees for their very useful suggestions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Michele G. Giuranno.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Giuranno, M.G., Mosca, M. Political realism and models of the state: Antonio de Viti de Marco and the origins of public choice. Public Choice 175, 325–345 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-018-0539-z

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-018-0539-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation