Skip to main content
Log in

The Grecian horse: does immigration lead to the deterioration of American institutions?

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Concerns about the institutional impact of immigration, particularly in the United States, are not new. We can trace them back to Benjamin Franklin, Thomas Jefferson, and Alexander Hamilton. More recently, in response to a literature that questions the desirability of current immigration restrictions, Borjas (J Econ Lit 53:961–974, 2015) speculates that immigrants coming from countries with poor institutions could reduce substantially the institutional quality in the United States to a point where it could negate all economic gains associated with immigration in terms of GDP and income. Using the Economic Freedom of North America index since 1980, we find no evidence to corroborate Borjas’s concerns. However, we find mixed evidence that immigration increases minimum wages and union density.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Additional examples of studies evaluating the efficiency losses associated with immigration restrictions include Moses and Letnes (2004), Walmsley and Winters (2005), Clemens (2011), Kennan (2013), di Giovanni et al. (2015), and Docquier et al. (2015). Docquier et al. (2015) seem to offer the most conservative estimates of gains resulting from liberalizing migration. First, they find that, contrary to most other studies, there are “high ‘incompressible’ migration costs” and therefore “the number of people in the world who have a desire to migrate is around 400 million” (Docquier et al. 2015, p. 326). Second, when accounting for these “incompressible” migration costs, Docquier et al. (2015, p. 335) show that the efficiency gains fall in the range of 7–18% of world GDP in the medium term, “with a focal effect around 12 percent of the world GDP.” Specifically, they show that two possible effects can significantly impact the efficiency gains from liberalizing migration. They show that “schooling externalities” are the most significant factor that can reduce these efficiency gains. They find that these gains fall to 7% in the presence of “schooling externalities” (p. 331). Yet, migration “network externalities” have the most positive impact on efficiency gains. In the presence of migration “network externalities,” the efficiency gains resulting from “a complete liberalization of migration with network effects” climb to 17.9% of GDP (p. 332).

  2. Borjas’s concerns about the effects of immigration on US institutions are not new. They can be traced as far back as prerevolutionary times. For example, Franklin ([1753] 1904, pp. 408–416), in a letter addressed to Peter Collinson dated May 9, 1753, expresses his strong reservations about the ability of German immigrants to assimilate and his concerns about the likely impact a massive immigration of Germans would have on the country’s ability to preserve its unique institutions. Henry George (1899, p. 409), in a series of articles from 1869 to 1899, expressed his concerns about “the immigration of Chinese in considerable numbers, which began shortly after the discovery of gold in California.” George (1899, p. 411) believed that “Chinese immigration differs from European immigration in being practically non-assimilable.” As a result, he thought that this massive settlement in the United States of nonassimilable immigrants, the Chinese, “would be to the degradation of the superior civilization without any commensurate improvement of the lower” (p. 413). Finally, after Thomas Jefferson proposed, in his first address to Congress on December 7, 1801, to revise the Alien and Sedition Acts of 1798 that required immigrants to establish a residence of 14 years before they could be naturalized and allowed to vote, Alexander Hamilton wrote a series of essays criticizing Jefferson’s proposal using Jefferson’s own Notes on the State of Virginia, in which he “cautioned against ‘great importations of foreigners’—carrying with them, he feared, their monarchist views” (quoted in Population Council 2010, pp. 177–178). Hamilton feared that granting citizenship to foreigners unconditionally would lead to the deterioration of American political institutions. Hamilton concludes in his last essay dated January 12, 1802, that “to admit foreigners indiscriminately to the rights of the citizens, the moment they put foot in our country, as recommended in the message, would be nothing less than to admit the Grecian horse into the citadel of our liberty and sovereignty” (quoted in Population Council 2010, p. 182).

  3. See also Gwartney et al. (2004) and Easton and Walker (1997), who also find strong positive relationships between the level of economic freedom, economic growth, and income. Hall and Lawson (2014, p. 1) survey the economic literature using the economic freedom of the world as an independent variable and find that “over two-thirds of these studies found economic freedom to correspond to a ‘good’ outcome such as faster growth, better living standards, more happiness, etc. Less than 4% of the sample found economic freedom to be associated with a ‘bad’ outcome such as increased income inequality. The balance of evidence is overwhelming that economic freedom corresponds with a wide variety of positive outcomes with almost no negative tradeoffs.”.

  4. Stansel and Patrick Tuszynski (2017) survey the literature using the EFNA as an independent variable and find results similar to Hall and Lawson (2014). They show that out of 155 papers that empirically assess the impact of economic freedom in North American states and provinces, “two-thirds of these found economic freedom to be associated with ‘good’ outcomes (such as faster economic growth), and only one found economic freedom to be associated with a ‘bad’ outcome” (p. 1).

  5. See also Gochenour and Nowrasteh (2014), who show that increased immigration stocks and flows don’t appear to lead to a larger welfare state.

  6. A possible explanation for this absence of such implication is that these authors’ research has more to do with the emergence of specific economic-growth-conducive institutions and their stickiness resulting from migrants bringing institutions conducive to economic growth into countries almost devoid of any of such institutions, leading to higher income today; it has less to do with migrants bringing institutions harmful to economic growth to supplant existing institutions that support economic growth. Even though this literature is related to Borjas’s concerns about the institutional impact of immigration, the authors didn’t find in Borjas’s work any reference to Putterman and Weil’s or Ang’s works as evidence supporting his concerns about the institutional impact of immigration.

  7. See Müeller et al. (2012) for a critique of Algan and Cahuc’s (2010) results showing a much weaker relationship between inherited trust in 1935 and trust in the home country. They also argue that the overall measure of inherited trust in 1935 is to be interpreted with caution because of the limitations of the General Social Survey, particularly with regard to the sample size for most ethnic heritage groups.

  8. Algan and Cahuc (2013) do discuss some policy implications of the research on the impact of trust and its various measures on development and growth. They show that while “a large part of the literature considers trust to be a cultural component hardly malleable. . . recent studies looking at immigrants show that their level of trust converges gradually to the average level of trust in their country of destination” (Algan and Cahuc 2013, p. 39). When discussing ethnic fractionalization and trust, Algan and Cahuc (2013, p. 47) point to Uslaner’s (2012) work, which “challenges Putnam’s thesis and argues that residential segregation, rather than ethnic diversity per se, drives down trust.” Algan and Cahuc (2013, p. 47) argue that “one conclusion is that immigration and urbanization policy should avoid ethnic ghettos to maintain trust.” Algan and Cahuc’s (2013, p. 50) survey also shows that “trust and institutions strongly interact, with causality running in both directions. These findings set new avenues of research to identify the policies that could promote social capital and cooperation, from rule of law and democracy to education policies.” In their discussion of the policy implications, Algan and Cahuc (2013) do not explore the idea that restrictions should be put on immigrants coming from countries where trust is low.

  9. We should note that EFNA goes back to 1981, while our period of analysis starts in 1980. However, because we are dealing with institutional change and institutional change takes time, we believe that the scores that each state received in 1981 are unlikely to be much different from the scores each state would have received in 1980. It’s unlikely as well that the variation in scores between 1980 and 1981 would be the result of the immigration stock in 1980 or the change of that stock in the preceding 12 months.

  10. A potential problem with our equation is that the unobserved determinants of economic freedom, represented in \(\varepsilon_{it}\), likely are correlated with the share of immigrants, leading to an upward-biased estimate of \(\gamma\). To some extent, our first estimation method circumvents this problem. In Sect. 3, we discuss further how we attempt to address this problem.

  11. We should note that in the authors’ conception of the liberal-conservative continuum, they refer to operational ideology [or what Stimson (1999) calls policy mood] rather than symbolic ideology (or self-identification) (Berry et al. 1998, pp. 327–328; Berry et al. 2012, p. 178n2). Such a measure has an advantage over the more standard variable “percent of legislature controlled by democrats” because it mitigates the effects that “important ideological distinctions among parties with the same label, e.g., the difference between Southern and Nonsouthern democrats” have in terms of policy choice (Berry et al. 1998, p. 329).

  12. To eliminate the Nickell bias resulting from a correlation between regressor \(ef_{it - 1}\) and the error term \(\varepsilon_{it}\), we also run baseline fixed effects regressions without the lagged dependent variable since fixed effects control for any time-invariant unobserved heterogeneity between the states, which among other things includes the initial level of economic freedom. The authors thank the referee for suggesting this additional robustness test.

  13. The “shift-share” instrument is often used in the immigration literature. See, for example, Basso and Peri (2015) and Mayda et al. (2015). The main reason for not using an external instrument such as the shift-share instrument is that one important assumption behind such an instrument is that the size of the past settlement of immigrants from an origin country is the sole determinant of migration to a specific state by immigrants from the same origin country. However, as noted by Mayda et al. (2015, p. 6), it’s likely that “the past location of immigrants across destinations might be correlated with past local economic and political conditions. To the extent that these conditions are persistent and hence correlated over time, this would invalidate the exclusion restriction of shift-share instruments à la Card (2001).” In previous iterations of this paper, we did use the shift-share instrument, and Hansen’s J tests confirm that it performed poorly.

  14. Stansel et al. (2017, p. 13) define union density as "the percentage of unionized workers in a state".

  15. In addition, to address possible issues with omitted variables, we perform additional robustness checks by estimating our basic model in first differences to remove all possible state-specific effects. The results of our robustness checks are available in the Appendix.

  16. An objection to using the share of age-eligible-to-vote naturalized citizens in the age-eligible-to-vote population as a variable of interest to tease out the direct impact of immigrants on economic freedom is that not all naturalized US citizen immigrants who are eligible to vote are registered to vote and actually vote. Therefore, using the share of naturalized US citizens is a poor proxy, but we cannot ignore that US citizen immigrants might influence the political process through lobbying as well. In addition, not all native-born individuals who are eligible to vote are registered to vote and actually vote. To the authors’ knowledge, no state-level data are available on the share of naturalized immigrants eligible to vote who actually vote; data exist only on the share of US citizens eligible to vote who actually vote. However, data are available at the US national level looking at the share of naturalized US citizens and native-born citizens eligible to vote who are registered and who voted in past presidential or congressional elections. See Crissey and File (2012), who examine the voting behavior of naturalized citizens from 1996 to 2010 using the US Census Bureau’s Current Population Survey’s November Voting Supplements. For example, data show that in 2010, about 54.2% of naturalized US citizens eligible to register to vote were registered voters and approximately 37% of all naturalized US citizens eligible to vote actually voted. Data also show that naturalized US citizens register and vote at a lower rate than native citizens do. In 2010, 66.1% of eligible native citizens were registered voters, and 46.3% of eligible native citizens voted (Crissey and File 2012, p. 14, Table 1).

  17. Only in our fixed effects regression (3) including the lagged dependent variable is the effect negative and statistically significant at the 10% level. The results in our fixed effects regression (1) without the lagged dependent variable show that, while the relationship between the share of naturalized citizen immigrant population and the overall economic freedom score is negative, it is not statistically significant. Therefore, some of the results in our fixed effects regression (3) may be driven by the Nickell bias.

  18. As we did when we examined the relationship between immigration and economic freedom, in an effort to address possible issues with omitted variables when examining the relationship between naturalized US citizens and economic freedom, we performed additional robustness checks by estimating our model in first differences to remove all possible state-specific effects. The results of our robustness checks are available in the Appendix.

  19. As we explain above, weak statistical significance appears only in the fixed effects regressions, but no statistical significance is found in the system GMM regressions.

  20. Much of the empirical literature on wage effects finds that new waves of immigrants are close substitutes for earlier waves of immigrants and have a significant negative impact on the wages of those previous immigrants (National Research Council 1997, p. 223). See also Card (2001) and Ottaviano and Peri (2008).

  21. Mayda et al. (2015) address this issue when looking at the impact of US immigration on the share of votes that Republicans and Democrats receive during the elections. They show that immigrants are more likely to vote for Democrats, but at the same time native-born individuals are more likely to vote for Republicans, if they believe that immigrants are voting for Democrats.

  22. Stansel et al. (2017, p. 69) define the general consumption expenditure as “total expenditures minus transfers to persons, transfers to businesses, transfers to other governments, and interest on public debt.” Stansel et al. (2017, p. 70) define insurance and retirement payments as a percentage of income as “payments by employment insurance, workers compensation, and various pension plans.”.

  23. Stansel et al. (2017, p. 73) adopt the following definition: “Property and Other Tax revenue consists of total tax revenue minus income and sales tax revenues.”.

References

  • Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., Robinson, J. A., & Yared, P. (2008). Income and democracy. American Economic Review, 98(3), 808–842.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., Harnoss, J., & Rapoport, H. (2016). Birthplace diversity and economic prosperity. Journal of Economic Growth, 21(2), 101–138.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Algan, Y., & Cahuc, P. (2010). Inherited trust and growth. American Economic Review, 100(5), 2060–2092.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Algan, Y., & Cahuc, P. (2013). Trust, growth and well-being: New evidence and policy implications. Bonn: Institute for the Study of Labor.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ang, J. B. (2013). Institutions and the long-run impact of early development. Journal of Development Economics, 105, 1–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Review of Economic Studies, 58(2), 277–297.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arellano, M., & Bover, O. (1995). Another look at the instrumental-variable estimation of error-components models. Journal of Econometrics, 68, 29–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Basso, G., & Peri, G. (2015). The association between immigration and labor market outcomes in the United States. Bonn: Institute for Labor Study.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baum, C. F. (2013). EC 823 applied econometrics. Retrieved December 1, 2015, from http://fmwww.bc.edu/EC-C/S2013/823/EC823.S2013.nn05.slides.pdf.

  • Benhabib, J., & Jovanovic, B. (2012). Optimal migration: A world perspective. International Economic Review, 53(2), 321–348.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bennett, D. L. (2016). Subnational economic freedom and performance in the United States and Canada. Cato Journal, 36(1), 165–185.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berry, W. D., Fording, R. C., Ringquist, E. J., Hanson, R. L., & Klarner, C. (2010). Measuring citizen and government ideology in the American states: A re-appraisal. State Politics and Policy Quarterly, 10(2), 117–135.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berry, W. D., Fording, R. C., Ringquist, E. J., Hanson, R. L., & Klarner, C. (2012). A new measure of state government ideology, and evidence that both the new measure and an old measure are valid. State Politics and Policy Quarterly, 13(2), 164–182.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berry, W. D., Ringquist, E. J., Fording, R. C., & Hanson, R. L. (1998). Measuring citizen and government ideology in the American states, 1960–93. American Journal of Political Science, 42(1), 327–348.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell, R., & Bond, S. (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. Journal of Econometrics, 87, 115–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borjas, G. J. (2014). Immigration economics. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Borjas, G. J. (2015). Immigration and globalization: A review essay. Journal of Economic Literature, 53(4), 961–974.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Card, D. (2001). Immigrant inflows, native outflows, and the local labor market impacts of higher immigration. Journal of Labor Economics, 19(1), 22–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Card, D. (2007). How immigration affects US cities. In Discussion Paper Series CDP No. 11/07. London: Department of Economics, University College London, Centre for Research and Analysis of Migration.

  • Clark, J., Lawson, R., Nowrasteh, A., Powell, B., & Murphy, R. (2015). Does immigration impact institutions? Public Choice, 163(3), 321–335.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clemens, M. A. (2011). Economics and emigration: Trillion-dollar bills on the sidewalk? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 25(3), 83–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clemens, M., & Pritchett, L. (2016). The new economic case for migration restrictions: An assessment. Washington, DC: Center for Global Development.

    Google Scholar 

  • Compton, R. A., Giedeman, D. C., & Hoover, G. A. (2011). Panel evidence on economic freedom and growth in the United States. European Journal of Political Economy, 27(3), 423–435.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Council, Population. (2010). Alexander Hamilton on the naturalization of foreigners. Population and Development Review, 36(1), 177–182.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crissey, S. R., & File, T. (2012). Voting behavior of naturalized citizens: 1996–2010. Working paper, Washington DC: US Census Bureau.

  • di Giovanni, J., Levchenko, A. A., & Ortega, F. (2015). A global view of cross-border migration. Journal of the European Economic Association, 13(1), 168–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Docquier, F., Machado, J., & Sekkat, K. (2015). Efficiency gains from liberalizing labor mobility. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 117(2), 303–346.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easton, S. T., & Walker, M. A. (1997). Income, growth, and economic freedom. American Economic Review, 87(2), 328–332.

    Google Scholar 

  • Faria, H. J., & Montesinos, H. M. (2009). Does economic freedom cause prosperity? An IV approach. Public Choice, 141(1/2), 103–127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Franklin, B. (1904). The works of Benjamin Franklin, including the private as well as the official and scientific correspondence, together with the unmutilated and correct version of the autobiography, compiled and edited by John Bigelow. The federal edition in 12 volumes. Vol. 2, letters and misc. writings 17351753. New York: G.P. Putnam’s Sons.

  • George, H. (1899). Chinese immigration. In J. J. Lalor (Ed.), Cyclopaedia of political science, political economy, and of the political history of the United States by the best American and European authors (Vol. 1, pp. 409–414). New York: Maynard, Merrill, & Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gochenour, Z., & Nowrasteh, A. (2014). The political externalities of immigration: Evidence from the United States. Washington, DC: Cato Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grieco, E. M., Acosta, Y. D., de la Cruz, G. P., Gambino, C., Gryn, T., Larsen, L. J., et al. (2012). The foreign-born population in the United States: 2010. Washington, DC: US Census Bureau.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gwartney, J. D., Holcombe, R. G., & Lawson, R. A. (2004). Economic freedom, institutional quality, and cross-country differences in income and growth. Cato Journal, 24(3), 205–233.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, J. C., & Lawson, R. A. (2014). Economic freedom of the world: An accounting of the literature. Contemporary Economic Policy, 32(1), 1–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, B., & Whalley, J. (1984). Efficiency and distributional implications of global restrictions on labour mobility: Calculations and policy implications. Journal of Development Economics, 14(1), 61–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hero, R. E., & Preuhs, R. R. (2007). Immigration and the evolving American welfare state: Examining policies in the US states. American Journal of Political Science, 51(3), 498–517.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Higgins, M. J., Levy, D., & Young, A. T. (2006). Growth and convergence across the United States: Evidence from the county level data. Review of Economics and Statistics, 88(4), 671–681.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kennan, J. (2013). Open borders. Review of Economic Dynamics, 16(2), L1–L13.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lawson, R. A. (2010). Economic freedom and the wealth and well-being of nations. In E. Chamlee-Wright & J. Kodl (Eds.), The annual proceedings of the wealth and well-being of nations, 20092010. Beloit, WI: Beloit College Press.

  • Lewis, E., & Peri, G. (2015). Immigration and the economy of cities and regions. In G. Duranton, J. Henderson, & W. C. Strange (Eds.), Handbook of regional and urban economics (Vol. 5). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mayda, A. M., Peri, G., & Steingress, W. (2015). Immigration to the US: A problem for the republicans or the democrats?. Bonn: Institute for the Study of Labor.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moses, J. W., & Letnes, B. (2004). The economic costs to international labor restrictions: Revisiting the empirical discussion. World Development, 32(10), 1609–1626.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Müeller, D., Torgler, B., & Uslaner, E. M. (2012). A comment on “Inherited trust and growth”. Economics Bulletin, 32(2), 1481–1488.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murphy, R. H., & Nowrasteh, A. (2017). The deep roots of economic development in the US states: An application of Putterman and Weil (2010). Journal of Bioeconomics, 1–16. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10818-017-9255-x.

  • National Research Council. (1997). The new Americans: Economic, demographic, and fiscal effects of immigration. In J. P. Smith & B. Edmonston (Eds.), Panel on the demographic and economic impacts of immigration. Washington, DC: National Academy Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nickell, S. (1981). Biases in dynamic models with fixed effects. Econometrica, 49(6), 1417–1426.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ottaviano, G. I., & Peri, G. (2008). Immigration and national wages: Clarifying the theory and the empirics. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Powell, B., Clark, J., & Nowrasteh, A. (2016). Does mass immigration destroy institutions? 1990 Israel as a natural experiment. Lubbock: Texas Tech University, Free Market Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Putterman, L., & Weil, D. N. (2010). Post-1500 population flows and the long-run determinants of economic growth and inequality. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 125(4), 1627–1682.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ruggles, S., Genadek, K., Goeken, R., Grover, J., & Sobek, M. (2015). Integrated public use microdata series: Version 6.0 (machine-readable database). Minneapolis: University of Minnesota.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmidley, A. D. (2001). Profile of the foreign-born population in the United States: 2000. US Census Bureau; current population reports. US Government Printing Office: Washington DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sequeira, S., Nunn, N., & Qian, N. (2017). Migrants and the making of America: The short- and long-run effects of immigration during the age of mass migration. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Spilimbergo, A. (2009). Democracy and foreign education. American Economic Review, 99(1), 528–543.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spolaore, E., & Wacziarg, R. (2013). How deep are the roots of economic development? Journal of Economic Literature, 51(2), 325–369.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stansel, D., & Patrick Tuszynski, M. (2017). Sub-national economic freedom: A review and analysis of the literature. Journal of Regional Analysis and Policy, 1–20. https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2986353.

  • Stansel, D., Torra, J., McMahon, F., & Palac, W. (2016). Economic freedom of North America 2016. Vancouver: Fraser Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stansel, D., Torra, J., McMahon, F., & Palac, W. (2017). Economic freedom of North America 2017. Vancouver: Fraser Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stimson, J. A. (1999). Public opinion in America: Moods, cycles, and swings (2nd ed.). Boulder, CO: Westview Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Uslaner, E. M. (2012). Segregation and mistrust: Diversity, isolation and social cohesion. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Walmsley, T. L., & Winters, L. A. (2005). Relaxing the restrictions on the temporary movement of natural persons: A simulation analysis. Journal of Economic Integration, 20(4), 688–726.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wiseman, T. (2016). Economic freedom and growth in US state-level market incomes at the top and bottom. Contemporary Economic Policy, 35, 93–112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank the participants from the Free Market Institute at Texas Tech University research workshop for their comments. We owe a great deal of gratitude to Andrew T. Young, Jamie Bologna, and Audrey Redford for their comments and assistance in helping us improve on previous drafts of this paper. We also thank the anonymous referees, whose comments and suggestions have helped us to improve our article. The usual caveats apply. Padilla gratefully acknowledges financial support from the John Templeton Foundation.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Alexandre Padilla.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Robustness checks

This appendix discusses additional robustness checks to address possible issues with omitted variables when attempting to measure the impact of immigration on economic freedom.

1.1.1 Immigration and economic freedom: first differences

To address possible issues with omitted variables when evaluating the impact of immigration and economic freedom, we follow Spilimbergo’s (2009, pp. 535–536) empirical strategy and estimate our basic model in first differences to remove all possible state-specific effects in two ways. We control for state fixed effects by taking first differences; we control for state-specific trends with fixed effects in differences. To address simultaneity bias, our model in first differences enters all explanatory variables with lags of 10 years. In other words, we observe the change in economic freedom from 2000 to 2010, and our explanatory variables are for the period 1990–2000. Table 16 presents the results of our regressions on the impact of the change in the share of immigrants. Only in the subarea of taxes does an increase in the share of foreign-born citizens have a statistically significant negative impact on the change in economic freedom at the 10% level. It likewise is negative for government spending, but the results are not statistically significant. And while it is not statistically significant, the impact is positive on labor market freedom.

Table 16 Immigration and economic freedom: differences

1.1.2 Naturalized citizens and economic freedom: first differences

We again follow Spilimbergo’s (2009, pp. 535–536) empirical strategy to mitigate possible issues of omitted variables when assessing the impact of naturalized citizens on economic freedom. We estimate our basic model in first differences to remove all possible state-specific effects in two ways. First, we control for state fixed effects by taking first differences. Second, we control for state-specific trends with fixed effects in differences. To address the possibility of simultaneity bias, our model in first differences enters all explanatory variables lagged 10 years; that is, we look at the effect of the change in the share of naturalized US citizen immigrants on the change in economic freedom or one of its dimensions in the following decade.

Table 17 shows that the change in the share of naturalized US citizens doesn’t have a statistically significant impact on subsequent changes in economic freedom overall. But our fixed-effects regressions show that an increase in the share of naturalized US citizens has a negative impact on future changes in economic freedom for government spending (Area 1) and taxes (Area 2), while it has a positive impact on future changes in economic freedom for labor market freedom (Area 3). These results are statistically significant at the 5% level. Because each area of economic freedom has several components, we investigate these results further.

Table 17 Naturalized US citizen immigrants and economic freedom: differences

Table 18 displays the results of our regressions investigating the relationship between the change in the share of naturalized US citizens and government spending and its components. Our results show that an increase in the population share of naturalized US citizens is negatively correlated with economic freedom in the areas of general consumption expenditures by government as a percentage of income and for insurance and retirement payments as a percentage of income.Footnote 22 Those results are statistically significant at the 1 and 5% levels, respectively. However, while an increase in the share of naturalized US citizens is negatively correlated with transfers and subsidies, it is not statistically significant.

Table 18 Naturalized US citizen immigrants and government spending: differences

Table 19 shows the negative correlation between the change in the share of naturalized US citizens and taxes. Our results show that the negative correlation comes from revenues from property and other taxes.Footnote 23 These results are statistically significant at the 1% level: a standard deviation increase in the change of the share of naturalized US citizens leads to a reduction in change in economic freedom for property and other taxes by about half of a standard deviation.

Table 19 Naturalized US citizen immigrants and taxes: differences

We investigate the positive correlation between the share of naturalized US citizen immigrants and labor market freedom and present the results in Table 20. We run regressions with subcategories of the labor market freedom score as our dependent variables: minimum wage legislation, government employment as a percentage of total state employment, and union density. Our pooled and fixed-effects regressions show that the positive impact of an increase in the share of naturalized US citizen immigrants on future changes in labor market freedom comes from minimum wage legislation. A standard deviation increase in the change of the share of naturalized immigrants produces an increase of about 0.16 of a standard deviation of the change in economic freedom score for minimum wage legislation. On other dimensions of labor market freedom, namely government employment and union density, the results are not statistically significant.

Table 20 Naturalized US citizen immigrants and labor market freedom: differences

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Padilla, A., Cachanosky, N. The Grecian horse: does immigration lead to the deterioration of American institutions?. Public Choice 174, 351–405 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-018-0509-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-018-0509-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation