Skip to main content
Log in

Towards a theory of bicameralism: the neglected contributions of the calculus of consent

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In The Calculus of Consent (1962: 235) Buchanan and Tullock assert: (1) ceteris paribus, while a coalition controlling less than a majority of voters may control in either chamber, the greater the difference in the bases of representation in the two houses, the less likely is any given coalition of voters to control a majority of the seats in both chambers; (2) the potential of cross-chamber logrolls (on issues of unequal intensity) increases the likelihood that a minority may effectively control policy making. We link these ideas to social theory approaches to bicameralism and for the empirical study of legislatures.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Black, D., & Newing, R. A. (1951). Committee decisions with complementary valuation. London: W. Hodge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Borcherding, T. E. (2002). The contributions of James M. Buchanan to public finance and political economy. Public Finance Review, 30(6), 646–666.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brams, S. J. (1989). Are the two houses of congress really co-equal? In B. Grofman & D. Wittman (Eds.), The federalist papers and the new institutionalism (pp. 125–141). New York: Agathon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brauninger, T. (2003). When simple voting doesn’t work: multicameral systems for the representation and aggregation of interests in international organizations. British Journal Political Science, 33, 681–703.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brunell, T. L. (1999). Why the senate is usually more republican than the house of representatives: partisan bias in U.S. congressional elections, 1952–1996. American Politics Research, 27(3), 316–337.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent: logical foundations of constitutional democracy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bullock, C., & Brady, D. (1983). Party, constituency, and roll-call voting in the U.S. Senate. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 8, 29–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crain, W. M., & Tollison, R. D. (1977). Legislative size and voting rules. Journal of Legal Studies, 6(1), 235–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Denzau, A., & Mackay, R. (1983). Gate-keeping and monopoly power of committees: an analysis of sincere and sophisticated behavior. American Journal of Political Science, 24(4), 740–761.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diermeier, D., & Myerson, R. (1999). Bicameralism and its consequences for the internal organization of legislatures. American Economic Review, 89(5), 1182–1196.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper & Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feld, S. L., & Grofman, B. (1987). Necessary and sufficient conditions for a majority winner in n-dimensional spatial voting games: an intuitive geometric approach. American Journal of Political Science, 32(4), 709–728.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feld, S. L., & Grofman, B. (1988). Majority rule outcomes and the structure of debate in one issue at a time decision making. Public Choice, 59, 239–252.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feld, S. L., Grofman, B., Hartley, R., Kilgour, M. O., & Miller, N. (1987). The uncovered set in spatial voting games. Theory and Decision, 23, 129–156.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fenno, R. Jr. (1978). Homestyle: house members and their districts. Harlow: Longman.

    Google Scholar 

  • Froman, L. A. Jr. (1967). The congressional process: strategies, rules, and procedures. Boston: Little, Brown.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenberg, J. (1979). Consistent majority rules over compact sets of alternatives. Econometrica, 47, 627–636.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grofman, B. (2000). Lijphart and the new institutionalism. In M. L. Crepaz, T. Koelble & D. Wilsford (Eds.), Democracy and institutions: the life work of Arend Lijphart (pp. 43–73). Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grofman, B., Griffin, R., & Glazer, A., (1991). Is the Senate more liberal than the House? Another look. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 16(2), 281–295.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hammond, T. H., & Miller, G. J. (1987). The core of the constitution. American Political Science Review, 81, 1155–1174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kramer, G. H. (1977). A dynamic model of political equilibrium. Journal of Economic Theory, 16, 310–334.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krehbiel, K. (1988). Spatial models of legislative choice. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 13, 259–319.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCubbins, M. D., & Sullivan, T. (1984). Constituency influences on legislative policy choice. Quality and Quantity, 18(4), 299–319.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKelvey, R. D. (1976). Intransitivities in multidimensional voting models and some implications for agenda control. Journal of Economic Theory, 12, 472–482.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKelvey, R. D. (1979). General conditions for global intransitivities in formal voting models. Econometrica, 47, 1085–1112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKelvey, R. D. (1986). Covering, dominance, and institution free properties of social choice. American Journal of Political Science, 30, 283–315.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKelvey, R. D., Ordeshook, P. C., & Ungar, P. (1980). Conditions for voting equilibria in continuous voter distributions. SIAM Journal of Applied Mathematics, 39, 161–168.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller, G. J., Hammond, T. H., & Kile, C. (1996). Bicameralism and the core: an experimental test. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 21, 83–103.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller, N., Grofman, B., & Feld, S. L., (1989). The geometry of majority rule. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 1(4), 379–406.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D. C. (1996). Constitutional democracy. New York/London: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W. (1982). Liberalism against populism: a confrontation between the theory of democracy and the theory of social choice. San Francisco: Freeman.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sartori, G. (1968). Political development and political engineering. In J. D. Montgomery & A. O. Hirschman (Eds.), Public policy (Vol. 17, pp. 261–298). Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schofield, N., Grofman, B., & Feld, S. L. (1988). The core and the stability of group choice in spatial voting games. American Political Science Review, 88, 195–211.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shepsle, K. A. (1979). The role of institutional structure in the creation of policy equilibrium. In D. W. Rae & T. J. Rismeir (Eds.), Public policy and public choice (Vol. VI, pp. 249–282). Beverly Hills: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shepsle, K. A., & Weingast, B. (1981). Structure-induced equilibrium and legislative choice. Public Choice, 37(3), 503–519.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shugart, M., & Carey, J. (1992). Presidents and assemblies: constitutional design and electoral dynamics. New York and London: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis, G., & Money, J. (1997). Bicameralism. New York and London: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Wuffle, A. (1986). Reflections on academia. PS: Political Science & Politics 19(Winter), 57–61.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Bernard Grofman.

Additional information

A much earlier version of this paper was presented at the Liberty Fund Conference on “The ‘Calculus of Consent’,” Santa Cruz, California, June 23–25, 1988. Partial support of this research came through SSHRCC research grant #410-2007-2153 (Stanley Winer and Stephen Ferris, co-PIs). Grofman’s work was also supported by the Jack W. Peltason (Bren Foundation) Endowed Chair, University of California, Irvine, and by the UCI Center for the Study of Democracy.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Grofman, B., Brunell, T. & Feld, S.L. Towards a theory of bicameralism: the neglected contributions of the calculus of consent. Public Choice 152, 147–161 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-011-9859-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-011-9859-y

Keywords

Navigation