Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Optimum Currency Areas in Emerging Market Regions: Evidence Based on the Symmetry of Economic Shocks

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Open Economies Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper examines which emerging market regions form optimum currency areas (OCAs) by assessing the symmetry of macroeconomic shocks. We extend the output-prices-VAR framework by adding net exports and the real effective exchange rate as endogenous variables. Based on theoretical considerations, we derive which shocks affect these variables in the long run: shocks to labor productivity, foreign trade, labor supply, and money supply. The considered economies of Central and Eastern Europe, the Commonwealth of Independent States, East and Southeast Asia, and South Asia, exhibit large enough shock symmetry to form a currency union; the economies of Africa, Latin America, and the Middle East do not.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Saiki (2005) finds that the benefits from a higher trade volume are asymmetric between developing and developed countries in a currency union. While developed countries typically benefit from higher exports to developing countries in the currency union, developing countries do not necessarily benefit from higher exports.

  2. For excellent surveys of the OCA literature, see De Grauwe (2007), Dellas and Tavlas (2009), and Tavlas (2009) for the case of Southern African economies.

  3. Dellas and Tavlas (2005) show that countries with relatively rigid wages benefit from joining a common currency area, while countries with relatively flexible wages tend to be worse off.

  4. See Tavlas (2009) for an excellent survey on papers focusing on a possible monetary union in Southern Africa.

  5. An interesting extension of the model would be to include public spending shocks in the specification of the aggregate demand. However, since the model is trimmed to be tested using a VAR model in Section 4 and data on public spending is not available on a quarterly basis for most of the countries considered, we do not include public spending in the theoretical model.

  6. The nominal exchange rate is defined as the amount of domestic currency units to be paid for one foreign currency unit. For simplicity, we normalize foreign prices to one.

  7. The effect of a positive labor productivity shock on output growth is ambiguous (see the four components in brackets in Eq. 17a). Positive effects on output growth result from a higher aggregate supply. An increase in labor productivity yields higher real wages and thereby increases labor supply (first term). Higher labor productivity leads to real appreciation of the domestic currency, which raises the purchasing power of wages, producing greater labor supply (second term). Aggregate supply increases directly due to higher labor productivity (third term). Finally, the negative effect of a positive labor productivity shock is transmitted through aggregate demand (fourth term), as the positive productivity shock leads to real appreciation of the domestic currency and, thus, to falling net exports.

  8. The time series for net exports shows sign changes. To alleviate the problem of outliers, we calculate the growth rate of net exports by dividing the quarterly change in net exports by the absolute value of the mean of net exports during the last eight quarters.

  9. The time series for the Slovakian GDP growth rate and the Brazilian, Chinese, Colombian, Ecuadorian, Hungarian, Iranian, Omani, and Turkish CPI growth rate are detrended to obtain stationary time series. The ADF test does not reject the null of non-stationarity for the Armenian, Czech, Latvian, and Polish CPI growth rates, but the Phillips-Perron test does. To obtain stationary CPI growth rate series for Venezuela and Hong Kong, we calculate the inflation rate of both countries on a year-over-year basis.

  10. We test for structural breaks in the model coefficients using the Quandt-Andrews test but find very few structural breaks which indicates that our estimation results are robust.

  11. To calculate the aggregated shock symmetry measures, we use the (N-1)*N/2 lower triangular elements of the correlation matrix to avoid double counting of symmetrical elements.

  12. We thank two anonymous referees for this helpful suggestion.

  13. The dependent variable of the regression models is the average value of a country’s value-weighted relative shock symmetry measure taken from Table 2.

  14. The coefficient (robust t-value) of fiscal coordination is 0.042 (3.397). The coefficient (robust t-value) of the constant is 0.008 (0.805). The F-statistic is 9.213. The R-squared is 0.146. We have also estimated regression models using the average relative shock symmetry measure instead of the average value-weighted relative shock symmetry measure as the dependent variable, but the results are very similar.

  15. The coefficient (robust t-value) of central bank independence is 0.015 (1.004). The coefficient (robust t-value) of the constant is 0.029 (3.164). The F-statistic is 1.002. The R-squared is 0.018. Taiwan is not included in the regression since data on central bank independence is not available.

References

  • Abu-Qarn AS, Abu-Bader S (2008) On the optimality of a GCC monetary union: structural VAR, common trends, and common cycles evidence. World Econ 31:612–630

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ahn C, Kim H, Chang D (2006) Is East Asia fit for an optimum currency area? An assessment of the economic feasibility of a higher degree of monetary cooperation in East Asia. Dev Econ 44:288–305

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arnone M, Laurens BJ, Segalotto J-F, Sommer M (2007) Central bank autonomy: lessons from global trends. IMF Working Paper No. 07/88.

  • Babetskii I, Boone L, Maurel M (2004) Exchange rate regimes and shocks asymmetry: the case of the accession countries. J Comp Econ 32:212–229

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bayoumi T, Eichengreen B (1993) Shocking aspects of European Monetary Union. In: Giavazzi F, Torres F (eds) Adjustment and growth in the European Monetary Union. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 193–229

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Bayoumi T, Eichengreen B (1994) One money or many? Analyzing the prospects for monetary unification on various parts of the world, Princeton Stud Int Fin 76

  • Bayoumi T, Eichengreen B, Mauro P (2000) On regional monetary arrangements for ASEAN. J Jpn Int Econ 14:121–148

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bayoumi T, Ostry JD (1997) Macroeconomic shocks and trade flows within Sub-Saharan Africa: implications for optimum currency arrangements. J Afr Econ 6:412–444

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard O, Quah D (1989) The dynamic effects of aggregate demand and supply disturbances. Am Econ Rev 79:655–673

    Google Scholar 

  • Buigut SK, Valev NT (2005) Is the proposed East African monetary union an optimal currency area?: a structural vector autoregression analysis. World Dev 33:2119–2133

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buigut SK, Valev NT (2006) Eastern and Southern Africa monetary integration: a structural vector autoregression analysis. Rev Dev Econ 10:586–603

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Grauwe P (2007) Economics of monetary union. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Dellas H, Tavlas GS (2005) Wage rigidity and monetary union. Econ J 115:907–927

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dellas H, Tavlas GS (2009) An optimum-currency-area odyssey. J Int Money Fin 28:1117–1137

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demertzis M, Hallett AH, Rummel O (2000) Is the European Union a natural currency area, or is it held together by policy makers? Rev World Econ 136:657–679

    Google Scholar 

  • Fidrmuc J, Korhonen I (2003) Similarity of supply and demand shocks between the euro area and the CEECs. Econ Syst 27:313–334

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fidrmuc J, Korhonen I (2006) Meta-analysis of the business cycle correlation between the euro area and the CEECs. J Comp Econ 34:518–537

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fielding D, Shields K (2001) Modelling macroeconomic shocks in the CFA franc zone. J Dev Econ 66:199–223

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frankel JA, Rose AK (1998) The endogeneity of the optimum currency area criteria. Econ J 108:1009–1025

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frenkel M, Nickel C (2005) How symmetrical are the shocks and the shock adjustment dynamics between the euro area and Central and Eastern European countries? J Common Mark Stud 43:53–74

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Furceri D, Karras G (2008) Is the Middle East an optimum currency area? A comparison of costs and benefits. Open Econ Rev 19:479–491

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Horvath J, Rátfai A (2004) Supply and demand shocks in accession countries to the economic and monetary union. J Comp Econ 32:202–211

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huang Y, Guo F (2006) Is currency union a feasible option in East Asia? A multivariate structural VAR approach. Res Int Bus Fin 20:77–94

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karmann A, Weimann M (2004) A closer shock convergence under EMU? Results of a VAR analysis. Int Rev Econ Bus 51:65–77

    Google Scholar 

  • Kenen PB (1969) The theory of optimum currency areas: an eclectic view. In: Mundell RA, Swoboda AK (eds) Monetary problems of the international economy. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 41–59

    Google Scholar 

  • Kim D (2007) An East Asian currency union? The empirical nature of macroeconomic shocks in East Asia. J Asian Econ 18:847–866

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ling HYP (2001) Optimum currency areas in East Asia: a structural VAR approach. ASEAN Econ Bull 18:206–217

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKinnon RI (1963) Optimum currency areas. Am Econ Rev 53:717–724

    Google Scholar 

  • Mundell RA (1961) A theory of optimum currency areas. Am Econ Rev 51:657–664

    Google Scholar 

  • Saiki A (2005) Asymmetric effects of currency union for developing countries. Open Econ Rev 16:227–247

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tavlas GS (2009) The benefits and costs of monetary union in Southern Africa: a critical survey of the literature. J Econ Surv 23:1–43

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang Z, Sato K (2008) Whither a currency union in greater China? Open Econ Rev 19:355–370

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang Z, Sato K, McAleer M (2004) Is a monetary union feasible for East Asia? Appl Econ 36:1031–1043

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank two anonymous referees and the Editor for very helpful comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Alexander Karmann.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Eichler, S., Karmann, A. Optimum Currency Areas in Emerging Market Regions: Evidence Based on the Symmetry of Economic Shocks. Open Econ Rev 22, 935–954 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-010-9180-2

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-010-9180-2

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation