Skip to main content
Log in

PPP: Delusion or Reality? Evidence from a Nonlinear Analysis

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Open Economies Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper we analyze the validity of the purchasing power parity (PPP) in a nonlinear framework using data for 18 bilateral US dollar exchange rates. Following Enders and Ludlow (2002), we use unit root and cointegration tests that do not assume a specific nonlinear adjustment. We find evidence of non-linear mean reversion in deviations from the PPP equilibrium in 11 out of 18 currencies. Additionally, to disentangle the respective contribution of exchange rate and prices to the adjustment toward the long run equilibrium, we estimate a Vector Error Correction Model. According to our empirical analysis, there exists a nonlinear mechanism to correct for deviation from the PPP equilibrium that comes mainly from the exchange rates. This is consistent with theoretical arguments on international goods markets under transaction costs as well as with an emerging strand of empirical literature. These results highlight the importance of neglecting the possibility of nonlinearity in the debate about the PPP and provide empirical evidence that supports the scenario of the PPP hypothesis as a reality.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Enders and Loudlow (2002) have already provided an empirical evidence of the relative PPP, but it is applied only to the logarithm of the real French franc/DM exchange rate.

  2. Kapetanios et al. (2003), Enders and Siklos (2001) or Bec et al. (2008) propose testing procedures to detect the presence of nonstationarity against nonlinear stationarity when the nonlinear dynamics process leading the adjustment to the deviations of PPP is a function of the size of deviations that can be modelized by some kind of threshold model. The Enders and Ludlow’s tests we use in this paper will still detect nonlinearity in such a situation.

  3. There also exists the absolute version of PPP that posits equality between the price level in one country and the exchange rate adjusted price level in the other. Strictly speaking, the absolute PPP hypothesis states that the exchange rate between the currencies of two countries should equal the ratio of the price levels of the two countries. The measures of consumer prices published by national statistical agencies are typically reported as indexes relative to a base year (say, 1995 = 100). Thus, they only measure the rate of change of the price level from the base year, not its absolute level. Therefore, it does not make sense testing this version of PPP when working with consumer index prices as it is done in this paper.

  4. The US dollar exchange rate for participating currencies in the single European currency after January 1999 has been calculated using the official conversion rates announced on December 31, 1998 and the Euro/Dollar exchange rate. Greece joins the European Economic Community in April 1981. This leads the Bank of Greece to adjust the trade-weighted system adopted following the collapse of the Bretton-Woods agreement placing a greater weight on European currencies and smaller weight on the dollar. Greece is joining the euro group as the 12th member on January 1, 2001. The Netherlands fixes its currency to the German Mark until January 1981. After the country’s public finances went bankrupt in 1982, Mexico began a profound transformation. The foreign debt crisis of 1981-82 had a severe and irreversible effect on public finances and political thinking. Until that date, Mexico’s economy was heavily subsidized and protected from competition.

  5. Before 1991 the consumer prices refers only to West Germany.

  6. DF-GLS test has substantially improved power when an unknown mean or trend is present. As Elliott et al. (1996) prove, the modified test works well in small samples.

  7. All individual series (nominal exchange rates and prices) have also been tested for the presence of unit root using the ADF and DF-GLS tests. Consistent with the literature, the null hypothesis of a single unit root cannot be rejected in any case. To save space, these results are not reported here, but are available upon request.

  8. Some researchers, such as Cheung et al. (1998), and Koedijk et al. (1998), have found that the stochastic processes of some of the real exchange rates cannot be adequately modeled without the inclusion of a linear deterministic time trend. The linear deterministic time trend is generally interpreted as representing systematic differences in productivity growth between tradable and non-tradable goods in the two countries. On the other hand, other researchers, for example, Papell and Theodoridis (1998), and Amara and Papell (2006) consider a linear time trend in the real exchange rate as inconsistent with long-run PPP.

  9. Perron and Rodriguez (2001) analyze residual based tests for cointegration. Among other cases, they consider the standard ADF test, derive their asymptotic distribution assuming a general quasi-differencing parameter and tabulate its critical values. Their simulations reveal an important power gain from using GLS detrended data, especially if the quasi-difference parameter is set as suggested by Elliott et al. (1996).

  10. When the model is linear in parameters, it is not able to account for a number of important properties of time series data, such as the clustering of large and small errors or thick-tailed distributions. Models with asymmetric adjustment are able to obtain good forecasts for heteroskedastic time series. As Ludlow and Enders (2000) show, the Fourier approximation captures the conditional volatility present in the NYSE Transportation Index.

  11. Let the function α(t) have a Fourier expansion: \( \alpha \left( t \right) = a_0 + \sum\limits_{k = 1}^{\infty } {\left[ {ak\;\sin \left( {{{2\pi kt} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{2\pi kt} T}} \right. } T}} \right) + bk\;\cos \left( {{{2\pi kt} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{2\pi kt} T}} \right. } T}} \right)} \right]}, \) and define F s (t) to be the sum of the Fourier coefficients: \( F_s \left( t \right) = \sum\limits_{k = 1}^s {\left[ {a_k \sin \left( {{{2\,\pi \,k\,t} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{2\,\pi \,k\,t} T}} \right. } T}} \right) + b_k \cos \left( {{{2\,\pi \,k\,t} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{2\,\pi \,k\,t} T}} \right. } T}} \right)} \right]}, \) then for any arbitrary positive number h, there exists a number N such that: \( \left| {\alpha (t) - F_s \left( t \right)} \right|\kern1.5pt<\kern1.5pth \) for all \( s \ge N \).

  12. Half the sample size is a natural upper bound arising from the standard deterministic harmonic decomposition.

  13. For time series analysis the frequency domain often provides valuable information on the dynamics of the series. The frequency domain properties of an economic time series may provide a useful complement to its time domain properties. The frequency approach is useful to identify the length of business cycles and seasonal patters that may be important. There may also be unknown cycles at other frequencies that should be identified. The method allows quantitative definition of the cycle, and extraction of long, medium or short term components, according to the researcher’s wish. The frequency information gives quality insight to the function shape where rapid changes imply high frequencies and gradual changes imply low frequencies.

  14. We can represent \( \alpha \left( t \right) = a_0 + a_1 \;{ \sin }\left( {{{2\,\pi \,k\,t} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{2\,\pi \,k\,t} T}} \right. } T}} \right) + b_1 \;{ \cos }\left( {{{2\,\pi \,k\,t} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{2\,\pi \,k\,t} T}} \right. } T}} \right) \) as \( \alpha (t) = a_0 + r{ \cos }\left( {{{2\,\pi \,k\,t} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{2\,\pi \,k\,t} T}} \right. } T} + d} \right), \) where \( r = \sqrt {a_1^2 + b_1^2 } \) and \( d = \arcsin \left( {{{a_1 } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{a_1 } r}} \right. } r}} \right) \). If a 0 + r > 1, and since \( { \cos }\left( {{{2\,\pi \,k\,t} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{2\,\pi \,k\,t} {T + d}}} \right. } {T + d}}} \right) \) can equal unity, there will be k periods when α(t) exceed the unity, there being explosive periods. Oscillations appear when α(t) < 0, that being the case when a 0  < r and \( { \cos }\left( {{{2\,\pi \,k\,t} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{2\,\pi \,k\,t} {T + d}}} \right. } {T + d}}} \right) = - 1 \).

  15. Additionally, we apply the test on the demeaned real exchange rate. To save space, we only present the demeaned and detrended case, but results are available upon request.

  16. We use differenced data to allow for comparison with the Engle and Granger (1987) test for the linear case.

  17. However, if the F_trig test correctly indicates r > 0, rejecting the null of de c* test against the alternative hypothesis c < 0, is sufficient to guarantee reversion.

  18. We also analyze the demeaned unrestricted PPP. The results are almost the same that in the detrended case. For this reason, to conserve space, these results are not reported here, but are available upon request.

  19. The estimated models appear to pass all the standard diagnostic tests. To save space, we do not include these results but are available upon request.

  20. The explanatory variables in the long run relationship are highly correlated and this may affect the signs and values of the estimated parameters.

  21. Our previous results on the stability of deviations from PPP only allow to understand the α i1, i = 1,2,3 coefficients as adjustment coefficient to past disequilibria for those countries with evidence in favor of the PPP. For the other countries, these coefficients capture responses to changes in a nonstationary relation of the variables.

  22. We approximate the distribution of these significance test statistics by a normal standard distribution.

  23. To test the existence of short-term causality, we start from the estimated VECM in expression (11) and carry out a joint significance test of the lags of the causal variable in the equation of the caused one.

References

Download references

Acknowledgement

We are grateful to A. Novales and two anonymous referees for helpful comments. The paper has benefited of comments from seminar participants at the George Washington University and from participants in the Unit root and Testing Cointegration conference. We acknowledge the financial support of the Ministerio de Ciencia y Tecnología, Spain, through the Project SEJ2006-14354/ECON and the Comunidad de Madrid through the Project 940063.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to M. Dolores Robles-Fernandez.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Jiménez-Martin, J.A., Robles-Fernandez, M.D. PPP: Delusion or Reality? Evidence from a Nonlinear Analysis. Open Econ Rev 21, 679–704 (2010). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-009-9113-0

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-009-9113-0

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation