Skip to main content
Log in

The economics of collective knowledge and technological communication

  • Published:
The Journal of Technology Transfer Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Technological knowledge can be understood as a collective good when it is the outcome of the integration between internal to the firm investments in R&D and learning and the absorption of competencies and technologies provided by external organizations (such as, other firms, universities, R&D centers). Technological communication is a crucial strategy in such dynamic interaction between the firm and the system. Only under effective conditions of technological communication the private and social benefits derived from the exploitation of spillovers are higher than the private losses due to partial inappropriability. The article presents a simple microeconomic framework to understand knowledge production and distribution, integrating the effects and conditions of technological communication within a knowledge production function. The interaction between internal investments in R&D and learning, partial inappropriability, the conditions for the access to external knowledge and the exploitation of spillovers explains increasing returns in the production of knowledge.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. This is for instance the case of large firms obtaining important scale and scope economies in R&D (Chandler 1990).

  2. Henkel and Von Hippel (2005) recently stretched this main line of analysis to include the effects of freely revealed innovations (p. 81) for user-driven innovation and the related welfare. Although this article does not address explicitly the role of users and consumers in the innovation process, it can be easily seen that implications for intermediary users are relevant, as far as firms need to access, use and adapt external technological competencies, often embodied in technologies and artifacts, in order to generate new knowledge and to innovate.

  3. Instead, the framework presented here is more consistent with Arrow (1969).

  4. The amount of external knowledge available in the system and potentially accessible by the firms is modeled as a function of the conditions of infrastructures and institutions enabling the diffusion of existing knowledge, such as technology transfer offices, standards, generic technologies and infra-technologies (Tassey 2000, 2005b). Here, g′ > 0, g″ > 0. In more formal terms, the effects of structural and institutional characteristics of the system on the availability and diffusion of external knowledge can be usefully appreciated with the percolation methodology. Percolation methodology can account for the variety of economic actors involved in knowledge and innovation dynamics, the connectivity and interactions between such actors and the way in which previous knowledge and innovation are diffused within the system in order to generate further technological knowledge and innovations. Here, it is possible to specify the different elements that enter in the percolation process in terms of the mixed percolation probability PP, as follows: PPZ = P(pf, pt, G, E). The mixed percolation probability PP is a non-decreasing function of pf and pt, respectively the receptivity and connectivity probabilities of a given network Z, of G, the number of firms in such a network and, finally, of E, the extent to which innovation opportunities, generic technology and external scientific and technological breakthroughs are able to impact the knowledge production in the system. For the formal exposition of percolation methodology see David and Foray (1994).

  5. In order to fully account for the strong complementarities at place between internal and external knowledge as inputs into the production of new knowledge, the relationship between these inputs has been modeled as multiplicative, along the lines of the models developed by Kremer (1993) and Caves (2000). Thus, the parameter θ for the amount of external knowledge the firm can absorb varies between 0 and 1.

  6. In this article I will consider the amount of external knowledge accessible by the firm and viable in the knowledge generation process of the firm as a given property of the system in which the firm plays. I will not articulate the case of proactive firms that are able to creatively react to the characteristics of the system in terms of, for instance, the relative input prices or poor connective structures. Hence, I will not articulate the implications of different relative prices for the way in which firms decide their investments in knowledge production. For this complementary analysis, see Patrucco (2009).

  7. Tassey’s article and this one share a departure point, that is the appreciation of the gap between social and private rates of return of innovation investments. Tassey then develops a microeconomic policy model to understand and react to the problem of underinvestment in innovation. In this article I leave aside specific policy issues and focus on the conditions of effective interaction between the firm and its environment—although policy implications could be derived from the present analysis, for instance in terms of investments in technological infrastructures and channels of technological communication. These deserve separate and careful treatment.

  8. The effect of the complementarity between internal and external knowledge on increasing returns is similar to that between generic and specific knowledge in Romer (1986, 1990), although the general working of the knowledge production process developed in this article is different from EGT models. Moreover, the complementarity between internal and external knowledge only accounts for potential increasing returns. When for instance γ2 is equal to zero, then standards decreasing returns do take place. Increasing returns are possible only when a minimum amount of internal and external knowledge is available in the firm and the system, along the lines, for instance, of the analysis developed by Cohen and Levinthal (1989).

  9. In the following, I will develop a qualitative analysis of the interactions between appropriability conditions and availability of external knowledge. For instance, with very strong IPRs regimes ensuring high levels of appropriation of the results of internal investments in R&D&L, there is limited scope for the exploitation of knowledge spillovers and the diffusion of external knowledge.

  10. Clearly, in Fig. 1a, \(\gamma_{{2}({\rm N}^{\prime})} < \gamma_{{2}({\rm N}^{\prime\prime})} < \gamma_{{2}({\rm N}^{\prime\prime\prime})} < \gamma_{{2}({\rm N}^{n})}\).

References

  • Allen, R. C. (1983). Collective invention. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 4(1), 1–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antonelli, C. (1999). The microdynamics of technological change. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Antonelli, C. (2006a). Diffusion as a process of creative adoption. Journal of Technology Transfer, 31(2), 211–226.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antonelli, C. (2006b). The business governance of localized knowledge: An information economics approach for the economics of knowledge. Industry and Innovation, 13(3), 227–261.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arora, A., Fosfuri, A., & Gambardella, A. (2001). The markets for technology. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J. (1962). Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention. In R. N. Richard (Ed.), The rate and direction of inventive activity (pp. 609–625). Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W. J. (2002). The free-market innovation machine: Analyzing the growth miracle of capitalism. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brusco, S. (1982). The Emilian model: Productive decentralisation and social integration. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 6(2), 167–184.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caves, R. E. (2000). Creative industries. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chandler, A. D. (1990). Scale and scope: The dynamics of industrial capitalism. Cambridge: Harvard Business Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, W., & Levinthal, D. (1989). Innovation and learning: The two faces of R&D. Economic Journal, 99(397), 569–596.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, W., & Levinthal, D. (1990). Absorptive capacity: A new perspective on learning and innovation. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35(1), 128–152.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cowan, R., & Jonard, N. (2003). The dynamics of collective invention. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 52(4), 513–532.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cowan, R., & Jonard, N. (2004). Network structure and the diffusion of knowledge. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 28(8), 1557–1575.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crémer, J., Garicano, L., & Prat, A. (2007). Language and the theory of the firm. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(1), 373–407.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • David, P. A., & Foray, D. (1994). Markov random fields, percolation structures and the economics of EDI standards diffusion. In P. Gerard (Ed.), Global telecommunications and technological changes (pp. 135–170). Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guilhon B. (Ed.). (2001). Technology and markets for knowledge: Knowledge creation, diffusion and exchange within a growing economy. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Griliches, Z. (1958). Research costs and social returns: Hybrid corn and related innovations. Journal of Political Economy, 66(5), 419–431.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henkel, J., & von Hippel, E. (2005). Welfare implications of user innovation. Journal of Technology Transfer, 30(1/2), 73–78.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klevorick, A. K., Levin, R. C., Nelson, R. R., & Winter, S. G. (1995). On the sources and significance of interindustry differences in technological opportunities. Research Policy, 24(2), 185–205.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kline, S. J., & Rosenberg, N. (1986). An overview of innovation. In L. Richard & R. Nathan (Eds.), The positive sum strategy: Harnessing technology for economic growth, (pp. 275–307). Washington: National Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kremer, M. (1993). The O-ring theory of economic development. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108(3), 551–575.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Link, A. N., Siegel, D. S., & Bozeman, B. (2007). An empirical analysis of the propensity of academics to engage in informal university technology transfer. Industrial and Corporate Change, 16(4), 641–655.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loasby, B. J. (1994). Organisational capabilities and interfirm relations. Metroeconomica, 45(3), 248–265.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield, E., Rapaport, J., Romeo, A., Wagner, S., & Beardsley, G. (1977). Social and private rates of returns from industrial innovations. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 91(2), 221–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Metcalfe, J. S. (2002). Knowledge of growth and the growth of knowledge. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 12(1/2), 3–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Patrucco, P. P. (2003). Institutional variety, networking and knowledge exchange: Communication and innovation in the case of the Brianza technological district. Regional Studies, 37(2), 159–172.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Patrucco, P. P. (2005). The emergence of technology systems: Knowledge production and distribution in the case of the Emilian plastics district. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 29(1), 37–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Patrucco, P. P. (2009). Collective knowledge production costs and the dynamics of technological systems. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 18(3), forthcoming.

  • Romer, P. M. (1986). Increasing returns and long-run growth. Journal of Political Economy 94(5), 1002–1037.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P. M. (1990). Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5), s71–s102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenberg, N. (1976). Perspectives on technology. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saxenian, A. (1994). Regional advantage: Culture and competition in silicon valley and route 128. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Siegel, D. S., Wright, M., & Lockett, A. (2007). The rise of entrepreneurial activity at universities: Organizational and societal implications. Industrial and Corporate Change, 16(4), 489–504.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tassey, G. (2000). Standardization in technology-based markets. Research Policy, 29(4–5), 587–602.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tassey, G., (2005a). Underinvestments in public good technologies. Journal of Technology Transfer, 30(1/2), 89–113.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tassey, G., (2005b). The disaggregated technology production function: A new model of university and corporate research. Research Policy, 34(3), 287–303.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teece, D. J. (2005). Technology and technology transfer: Mansfieldian inspirations and subsequent developments. Journal of Technology Transfer, 30(1/2), 17–33.

    Google Scholar 

  • Von Hippel, E. (2005). Democratizing innovation. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

Cristiano Antonelli, Davide Consoli, Stan Metcalfe, Francesco Quatraro, Ed Steinmueller and two anonymous referees of this Journal provided useful suggestions and comments. I acknowledge the financial support of the Collegio Carlo Alberto of the University of Torino through the funding of BRICK - Bureau of Research on Innovation, Complexity and Knowledge.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Pier Paolo Patrucco.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Patrucco, P.P. The economics of collective knowledge and technological communication. J Technol Transfer 33, 579–599 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10961-008-9085-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10961-008-9085-z

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation