Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Growth, Inequality and Tunnel Effects: A Formal Mode

  • Research Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Happiness Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Hirschman and Rothschild’s (Q J Econ 87(4):544–566, 1973) tunnel effect refers to the propensity for individuals to be pleased by the success of others if they believe this signals an improvement in their own prospects. According to the current literature, tunnel effects may offset the utility losses from increases in peer income levels and income inequality. I develop a simple model of tunnel effects to evaluate these two channels of influence. The analysis confirms that tunnel effects create a positive link between happiness and economic growth. In contrast, rising income inequality generates a tunnel effect that increases the happiness of the rich but decreases happiness among the poor. The analysis confirms Hirschman and Rothschild’s informal analysis indicating that that tunnel effects may increase the happiness of the poor in the case of uneven development that involves both growth and rising income inequality. The model also highlights the differential impact of tunnel effects across age and income groups within the population. I close by discussing the model’s implications for empirical investigations of tunnel effects.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Recent work has found evidence of a preference for status using a variety of comparison groups including co-workers (Brown et al. 2008; Clark and Oswald 1996), siblings (Kuegler 2009), those in the same neighborhood (Luttmer 2005), and others within one’s state of residence (Blanchflower and Oswald 2004). See Clark et al. (2008) for a review of the literature.

  2. For example, on page 17, Ngamaba et al., appear to assume that “people in developing countries…[observe] other people’s increasingly rapid progression.” However, on average, low income countries grow no more rapidly than rich ones, and over the long run, they have grown more slowly, e.g. Pritchett (1997).

  3. For the sake of symmetry, one could augment to the model to include retrospective utility, or the consumption of memories, for the old.

  4. I am grateful to an anonymous referee for pointing out this relationship.

  5. Inequality aversion is disutility from observed inequality and may arise from moral, ideological or psychological grounds. It differs from a taste for social status in that a rise in inequality increases the status and utility of the rich while decreasing the status and utility of the poor. In contrast, it reduces the utility of the inequality averse regardless of their position in the distribution of income. The model may be extended to incorporate pure inequality aversion, as was done in earlier versions of the paper. The current approach is preferred here as it facilitates the comparison with Hirschman and Rothschild.

  6. Some papers take a macroeconomic perspective, treating status as a function of the log of average income, as measure of the national standard of living. The equation used here is more microeconomic in nature, and may be thought of as deriving from a set of pairwise comparisons between an individual and her peers, where the status is equal to the difference in log income levels: \(u_{t}^{i} (x_{t} ) = (1 - \psi )\ln y_{t}^{i} + \psi \frac{1}{{N_{j} }}\sum\nolimits_{j \in J} {\left( {\ln y_{t}^{i} - \ln y_{t}^{j} } \right)} = \ln y_{t}^{i} - \psi \overline{{\ln y_{t} }}\), where J is the set of an individual’s peers.

  7. It may also be that mobility refers to the poor sector as a whole rather than its members. See Davis (2014) for a model along these lines.

  8. Ravallion and Lokshin (2000) find differential tunnel effects for the rich and poor in transition Russia. Their analysis differs from most of the work cited here in that they are concerned with support for redistribution rather than with happiness.

References

  • Alesina, A., Di Tella, R., & MacCulloch, R. (2004). Inequality and happiness: Are Europeans and Americans different? Journal of Public Economics, 88, 2009–2042.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bjørnskov, C., Dreher, A., Fischer, Justina A. V., Schnellenbach, J., & Gehring, K. (2013). Inequality and happiness: When perceived social mobility and economic reality do not match. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 91, 75–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchflower, D., & Oswald, A. (2004). Money, sex and happiness: An empirical study. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 106, 393–416.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown, G. D. A., Gardner, J., Oswald, A. J., & Qian, J. (2008). Does wage rank affect employees’ wellbeing? Industrial Relations, 47(3), 355–389.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen, K. (2013). The effect of language on economic behavior: Evidence from savings rates, health behaviors, and retirement assets. American Economic Review, 103(2), 690–731.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, A., Frijters, P., & Shields, M. (2008). Relative income, happiness, and utility: An explanation for the easterlin paradox and other puzzles. Journal of Economic Literature, 46(1), 95–144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, A. E., Kristensen, N., & Westergard-Neilsen, N. (2009). Job satisfaction and co-worker wages: Status or signal. Economic Journal, 119(536), 430–447.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, A., & Oswald, A. (1996). Satisfaction and comparison income. Journal of Public Economics, 61(3), 359–381.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis, L. (2014). Political economy of growth with a taste for status. SSRN Abstract # 2188643.

  • Davis, L., & Hopkins, M. (2011). Institutional foundations of inequality and growth. Journal of Development Studies, 47(7), 977–997.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis, L., & Wu, S. (2014). Social comparisons and happiness across racial and ethnic groups: The effects of status, information and solidarity. Social Indicators Research, 117, 849–869.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterlin, R. A. (1974). Does economic growth improve the human lot? Some empirical evidence. In P. A. David & M. W. Reder (Eds.), Nations and households in economic growth: Essays in honor of moses Abramowitz. Cambridge: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Easterlin, R. A. (1995). Will raising the incomes of all increase the happiness of all? Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 27(1), 35–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • FitzRoy, F. R., Nolan, M. A., Steinhardt, M. F., & Ulph, D. (2014). Testing the tunnel effect: Comparison, age and happiness in UK and German Panels. IZA Journal of European Labor Studies, 3, 24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Forbes, K. J. (2000). A reassessment of the relationship between inequality and growth. American Economic Review, 90, 869–887.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frank, R. H. (1985). The demand for unobservable and other nonpositional goods. American Economic Review, 75(1), 101–116.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frank, R. H. (2005). Positional externalities cause large and preventable welfare losses. American Economic Review, 95(2), 137–141.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grosfeld, I., & Senik, C. (2010). The emerging aversion to inequality. Evidence from Poland 1992–2005. Economics of Transition, 18(1), 1–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirschman, A. O., & Rothschild, M. (1973). The changing tolerance for income inequality in the course of economic development. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 87(4), 544–566.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hofstede, G. H. (2001). Culture’s consequences: Comparing values, behaviors, institutions, and organizations across nations (2nd ed.). Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuegler, A. (2009). A curse of comparison? Evidence on reference groups for relative income concerns. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 4820.

  • Luttmer, E. P. (2005). Neighbors as negatives: Relative earnings and well-being. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120(3), 963–1002.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ngamaba, K. H., Panagioti, M., & Amaritage, C. J. (2018). Income inequality and subjective well-being: A systematic review and meta-analysis. Quality of Life Research, 27(3), 577–596.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pritchett, L. (1997). Divergence, big time. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11(3), 3–17.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ravallion, M., & Lokshin, M. (2000). Who wants to redistribute? The tunnel effect in 1990s Russia. Journal of Public Economics, 76, 87–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schneider, S. M. (2016). Income inequality and subjective wellbeing: Trends, challenges, and research directions. Journal of Happiness Studies, 17, 1719–1739.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Senik, C. (2004). When information dominates comparison: Learning from Russian subjective panel data. Journal of Public Economics, 88(9–10), 2099–2123.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Senik, C. (2008). Ambition and jealousy: Income interactions in the ‘old’ Europe versus the ‘new’ Europe and the United States. Economica, 75(299), 495–513.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stevenson, B., & Wolfers, J. (2008). Economic growth and subjective well-being: Reassessing the Easterlin paradox. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Spring, 2008, 1–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Verme, P. (2011). Happiness and income inequality. Review of Income and Wealth, 57(1), 111–127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wunder, C., & Schwarze, J. (2009). Inequality and job satisfaction of full-time employees in Germany. Journal of Income Distribution, 18(2), 70–91.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I am grateful for the support of Faculty Resource Network at New York University, where I was a Scholar-in-Residence during initial work on this paper and to Ran Wang for excellent research assistance. I also wish to thank Claudia Senik, Stephen Wu and participants at the Southern Economic Association Meetings for the insightful comments on earlier versions of this paper. Any remaining errors are my own.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Lewis Davis.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Davis, L. Growth, Inequality and Tunnel Effects: A Formal Mode. J Happiness Stud 20, 1103–1119 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10902-018-9991-1

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10902-018-9991-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation