Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Indirect tax harmonization and global public goods

  • Published:
International Tax and Public Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper identifies conditions under which, starting from any tax-distorting equilibrium, destination- and origin-based indirect tax-harmonizing reforms are potentially Pareto improving in the presence of global public goods. The first condition (unrequited transfers between governments) requires that transfers are designed in such a way that the marginal valuations of the global public goods are equalized, whereas the second (conditional revenue changes) requires that the change in global tax revenues, as a consequence of tax harmonization, is consistent with the under/over-provision of global public goods relative to the (modified) Samuelson rule. Under these conditions, tax harmonization results in redistributing the gains from a reduction in global deadweight loss and any changes in global tax revenues according to the Pareto principle. And this is the case independently of the tax principle in place (destination or origin).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The EC Treaty, and under Article 93, requires the European Union Council of Ministers to adopt provisions for the harmonization of Member States’ rules in the area of indirect taxation. Indeed, tax harmonization has been quite pronounced for indirect taxation, following the adoption of a common VAT tax system. Although the discussions regarding indirect taxation in the EU context has shifted in recent years toward minimum taxation, tax harmonization remains high on the policy agenda regarding environmental taxation.

  2. The model is, in fact, general enough to encompass the case in which the public goods exhibit local characteristics. We turn to this later on.

  3. By existing inefficiencies we mean, in the broadest sense, those inefficiencies from taxation (and public goods provision) arising in any tax-distorting equilibrium, including, of course, the non-cooperative one. Since focusing on the non-cooperative equilibrium gives an important perspective, Appendix C characterizes this equilibrium and provides existence results for potential Pareto improvements. See also Navrouzoglou (2012) for an analysis of the cooperative equilibrium in the presence of a global pollution externality.

  4. There is a sizeable literature dealing with the efficiency properties of formula-based grants between asymmetric jurisdictions. These grants have been shown, if supplemented with lump sum transfers, to neutralize the efficiency loss caused by tax competition among lower-level governments. On this see, among others, Wildasin (1989, 1991), and Smart (1998, 2007). The transfers here perform a similar role.

  5. For a recent contribution that discusses issues of efficient provision of global public goods, see Sandmo (2006) and Keen and Kotsogiannis (2012).

  6. The weights, under the destination principle, being the demand responses of the participating countries. There is a fairly sizeable literature on piecemeal Pareto-improving tax reforms but Keen (1987, 1989) is the first to focus on tax-harmonizing ones.

  7. Meaning that the country that gains from tax harmonization compensates the one that loses, and still is better off. Section 3 returns to this.

  8. The weights, under the origin principle, being the supply responses of the participating countries.

  9. See also Lahiri and Raimondos-Møller (1998), and Lopez-Garcia (1998).

  10. Conditional revenue neutrality requires that, conditional on the tax-harmonizing reforms, global tax revenues remain unchanged.

  11. Lockwood (1997), specializing the production technology, has established alternative conditions for Pareto-improving harmonization.

  12. Derivatives are denoted by primes.

  13. Of course, different public goods require a different modeling framework. Here, it is taken that the global public goods affect the utility of consumers and not the production capabilities of firms.

  14. Notice that the analysis is not concerned with which country will provide the public good. What it is concerned with is whether, given that countries provide global public goods, tax harmonization can deliver a potential Pareto improvement. In this context, the assumption that both countries are equally efficient in the production of global public goods is not a restrictive one.

  15. Second-order conditions are assumed to hold. Appendix A discusses, though briefly, issues related to the stability of the equilibrium in the Cournot competition stage of the model.

  16. The underlying assumption here is that utility is additively separable between the (sub)utility from private and public goods, with the (sub)utility function associated with private goods being quasi-linear (with the linear part being the utility derived from the consumption of the numeraire good).

  17. It has to be noted that the tax-harmonizing reform in (12) is more general than the one that has frequently appeared in the literature, and in particular in Keen (1987, 1989). The generality here stems from the fact that the convergence of taxes is not uniform but it is weighted by ψ and ψ . Notice also that the weights of the target-tax H d , given by ψD′/(ψD′+ψ D ∗′) and ψ D ∗′/(ψD′+ψ D ∗′), are—following from the fact that D′,D ∗′<0 and ψ,ψ >0—strictly positive.

  18. It can be shown that, in general, reforms that deliver potential Pareto improvements do exist. It is the identification of these reforms, however, that is the difficult task. On this, see Karakosta (2009).

  19. This is the exact analogue of Kotsogiannis and Lopez-Garcia (2007), carrying over unchanged to the case in which tax revenues finance global public goods.

  20. And, in particular, so within the European Union where this particular form of tax harmonization has been central in policy discussions during the last two decades.

  21. These transfers can be rationalized by assuming that there is some intervention of some outside agency (for example, a supranational government). While this agency can make use of such transfers (in an optimal sense and satisfying its budget constraint), it cannot decide on tax issues. This, in some sense, is consistent with the workings of the European Union: While European Union decision-making on tax matters requires unanimity (implying that tax-harmonization will only be implemented if it delivers a potential Pareto improvement, a requirement imposed in the present analysis) intergovernmental transfers do not.

  22. To see this, notice that in this case (6) becomes G=t d D+B for the home country and \(G^{\ast}=t_{d}^{\ast}D^{\ast}-B\) for the foreign (where B denotes unrequited transfers in terms of the numeraire good). Perturbing (17) with respect to B implies that \(dV+dV^{\ast}= [ ( \varGamma_{G}+\varGamma_{G}^{\ast} ) - ( \varGamma_{G^{\ast}}+\varGamma_{G^{\ast }}^{\ast } ) ] dB\) which, upon setting equal to zero, gives (19).

  23. And to the marginal cost which is equal to 1 in both countries.

  24. Suppose for instance—something that, arguably, seems to be a very restrictive requirement—the reforms are conditional neutral (as in Delipalla 1997). In this case, d(G+G )=0, implying that the welfare loss of one country (as a consequence of tax harmonization) is exactly offset by the welfare gain of the other. In this case, (17) reduces to (18) and so the tax-harmonizing reforms in (12) and (13) deliver a potential Pareto improvement.

  25. This is easily seen from noticing that the slope of the Laffer curve in the home country is given by d(t d D)/dt d =(Q/e+t d )(De/Q). With De/Q<0, d(t d D)/dt d >0 (implying that the home country is on the left-hand side of the Laffer curve) if and only \(Q/e+t_{d}>\dot{0}\) (similarly, for the foreign country). For an example that demonstrates transparently the existence of potential Pareto improvements under the conditions of Proposition 2, see Appendix C. Examples for Proposition 1 and Corollary 1 are available upon request.

  26. This is in contrast to the linear demand and constant marginal cost case analyzed in Kotsogiannis and Lopez-Garcia (2007) where the weights A and A in (31) vanish leaving \(dt_{o}=-dt^{*}_{o}\).

  27. Appendix C develops an example that demonstrates the existence of potential Pareto improvements under the conditions of Proposition 4. Examples for Proposition 3 and Corollary 2 exist and are available upon request.

  28. It is nevertheless—as noted in the introductory section—used widely in the literature.

References

  • Bjorvatn, K., & Schjelderup, G. (2002). Tax competition and international public goods. International Tax and Public Finance, 9, 111–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Delipalla, S. (1997). Commodity tax harmonization and public goods. Journal of Public Economics, 63, 447–466.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hashimzade, N., Khovadaisi, H., & Myles, G. D. (2005). Tax principles, product differentiation and the nature of competition. International Tax and Public Finance, 12, 695–712.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hashimzade, N., Khovadaisi, H., & Myles, G. D. (2011). Country characteristics and preferences over tax principles. International Tax and Public Finance, 18, 214–232.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haufler, A., & Pfluger, M. (2004). International commodity taxation under monopolistic competition. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 6(3), 445–470.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haufler, A., Schjelderup, G., & Stahler, F. (2000). Commodity taxation and international trade in imperfect markets. CESifo Working Paper No. 376.

  • Karakosta, O. (2009). PhD Thesis, Athens University of Economics and Business.

  • Keen, M. J. (1987). Welfare effects of commodity tax harmonization. Journal of Public Economics, 33, 107–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keen, M. J. (1989). Pareto-improving indirect tax harmonization. European Economic Review, 33, 1–12.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keen, M. J., & Kotsogiannis, C. (2012). Coordinating climate and trade policies: Pareto efficiency and the role of border tax adjustments. Mimeo, University of Exeter.

  • Keen, M. J., & Lahiri, S. (1993). Domestic tax reform and international oligopoly. Journal of Public Economics, 51, 55–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keen, M., & Lahiri, S. (1998). The comparison between destination and origin principles under imperfect competition. Journal of International Economics, 45, 323–350.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keen, M. J., Lahiri, S., & Raimondos-Møller, P. (2002). Tax principles and tax harmonization under imperfect competition: A cautionary example. European Economic Review, 46, 1559–1568.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kotsogiannis, C., & Lopez-Garcia, M.-A. (2007). Imperfect competition, indirect tax harmonization and public goods. International Tax and Public Finance, 14, 135–149.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kotsogiannis, C., Lopez-Garcia, M.-A., & Myles, G. D. (2005). The origin principle, tax harmonization and public goods. Economics Letters, 87, 211–219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lahiri, S., & Raimondos-Møller, P. (1998). Public good provision and the welfare effects of indirect tax harmonization. Journal of Public Economics, 67, 253–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lockwood, B. (1997). Can commodity tax harmonization be Pareto-improving when governments supply public goods? Journal of International Economics, 43, 387–408.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lockwood, B. (2001). Tax competition and tax coordination under destination and origin principles: a synthesis. Journal of Public Economics, 81, 279–319.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lopez-Garcia, M.-A. (1996). The origin principle and the welfare gains from indirect tax harmonization. International Tax and Public Finance, 3, 83–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lopez-Garcia, M.-A. (1998). On welfare and revenue effects of indirect tax harmonization. Economics Letters, 60, 185–193.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Navrouzoglou, P. (2012). Pollution externalities and tax principles. Mimeo, University of Exeter.

  • Sandmo, A. (2006). Global public economics: Public goods and externalities. NHH discussion paper (SAM 32 2006).

  • Smart, M. (1998). Tax and deadweight loss in a system of intergovernmental transfers. Canadian Journal of Economics, 31, 189–206.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smart, M. (2007). Raising taxes through equalization. Canadian Journal of Economics, 40, 1188–1212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wildasin, D. (1989). Interjurisdictional capital mobility: Fiscal externality and a corrective subsidy. Journal of Urban Economics, 25, 193–212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wildasin, D. (1991). Income redistribution in a common labor market. American Economic Review, 81, 757–774.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank two anonymous referees and the editor of the journal for comments and advice on an earlier version of this paper. We also thank Paulina Navrouzoglou for insightful discussions and seminar participants at Athens University of Economics and Business and the XVIII Encuentro de Economia Publica held at the University of Malaga for comments. Any remaining errors are of course ours. This is a version of an earlier paper circulated as ‘Does indirect tax harmonization deliver Pareto improvements in the presence of global public goods?’ Financial support from the Catalan Government Science Network (2009SGR-600 and XREPP) and the Spanish Ministry of Education and Science Research Project (ECO2009-10003) is gratefully acknowledged (Kotsogiannis and Lopez-Garcia).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Miguel-Angel Lopez-Garcia.

Appendices

Appendix A

Proof of the statement that the reform in (12) and (13) implies that dP=dX=dX =0

Re-write, for convenience, the market clearing condition in (3) and the first-order conditions in (9) and (10) given by, respectively,

(A.1)
(A.2)
(A.3)

Equations (A.1)–(A.3) define the equilibrium of output and the world producer price of the tradeable good. Notice that sufficiency for the choice of X and X requires, respectively, that

$$ \varPi_{XX}\equiv\alpha_{d}=2P^{\prime}+XP^{\prime\prime}-C^{\prime \prime}<0 , $$
(A.4)

and

$$ \varPi_{X^{\ast}X^{\ast}}^{\ast}\equiv\alpha_{d}^{\ast}=2P^{\prime }+X^{\ast}P^{\prime\prime}-C^{\ast\,\prime\prime}<0 . $$
(A.5)

It is also assumed that

(A.6)
(A.7)

and so the firms’ best response functions are downward sloping in quantity space. Stability of equilibrium (in the Cournot stage) requires that

$$ \varDelta _{d}=\alpha_{d}\alpha_{d}^{\ast}- \beta_{d}\beta_{d}^{\ast }>0 . $$
(A.8)

Perturbation (abusing notation somewhat) of (A.1)–(A.3)—after using the fact that, following from the demand functions, dD=D′(dP+dt d ) (\(dD^{\ast}=D^{\ast\prime}(dP+dt_{d}^{\ast})\)), but also that P′=(D′+D ∗′)−1—gives in matrix form

$$ \left [ \begin{array}{c@{\quad }c@{\quad }c} 1 & -P^{\prime} & -P^{\prime} \\ 1 & \alpha_{d}-P^{\prime} & \beta_{d}-P^{\prime} \\ 1 & \beta_{d}^{\ast}-P^{\prime} & \alpha_{d}^{\ast}-P^{\prime}\end{array} \right ] \left [ \begin{array}{c} dP \\ dX \\ dX^{\ast}\end{array} \right ] =\left [ \begin{array}{c} -P^{\prime}D^{\prime}dt_{d}-P^{\prime}D^{\ast\prime}dt_{d}^{\ast} \\ 0 \\ 0\end{array} \right ] . $$
(A.9)

It can be easily verified that the determinant of the left-hand side matrix is given by (A.8). As is typically the case, without further restrictions on the structure of the model the comparative statics are indeterminate. This, in the present context, is not problematic: All that is required here is that the comparative statics are ‘well defined’ in the sense that the coefficients of the components of \(D^{\prime }dt_{d}+D^{\ast \prime}dt_{d}^{\ast}\), are non-zero. It is assumed this to be the case. Solving the system of equations in (A.9) for dP,dX, and dX , one obtains

(A.10)
(A.11)
(A.12)

Close inspection of (A.10) reveals that if \(D^{\prime }dt_{d}+D^{\ast \prime}dt_{d}^{\ast}=0\), then, dP=dX=dX =0. □

Appendix B

Proof of the statement that the reform in ( 27 ) and ( 28 ) implies that dQ=0

Re-write, for convenience, the market clearing condition in (3) and the first-order conditions in (25)

(B.1)
(B.2)
(B.3)

Equations (B.1)–(B.3) define the equilibrium of output and the world consumer price of the tradeable good. Notice that sufficiency for the choice of X and X requires, respectively, that

$$ \varPi_{XX}\equiv\alpha_{o}=2Q^{\prime}+XQ^{\prime\prime}-C^{\prime \prime}<0 , $$
(B.4)

and

$$ \varPi_{X^{\ast}X^{\ast}}^{\ast}\equiv\alpha_{o}^{\ast}=2Q^{\prime }+X^{\ast}Q^{\prime\prime}-C^{\ast\prime\prime}<0 . $$
(B.5)

It is also assumed that

(B.6)
(B.7)

and so the firms’ best response function are downward sloping in quantity space. Stability of equilibrium (in the Cournot stage) requires that

$$ \varDelta _{o}=\alpha_{o}\alpha_{o}^{\ast}- \beta_{o}\beta_{o}^{\ast }>0 . $$
(B.8)

Perturbing now (B.1)–(B.3) gives (again abusing notation somewhat) in matrix form

$$ \left [ \begin{array}{c@{\quad }c@{\quad }c} 1 & -Q^{\prime} & -Q^{\prime} \\ 1 & \alpha_{o}-Q^{\prime} & \beta_{o}-Q^{\prime} \\ 1 & \beta_{o}^{\ast}-Q^{\prime} & \alpha_{o}^{\ast}-Q^{\prime}\end{array} \right ] \left [ \begin{array}{c} dQ \\ dX \\ dX^{\ast}\end{array} \right ] =\left [ \begin{array}{c} 0 \\ dt_{o} \\ dt_{o}^{\ast}\end{array} \right ] . $$
(B.9)

Solving the system of equations in (B.9) for dQ, dX, and dX , one obtains

(B.10)
(B.11)
(B.12)

Since

$$ \alpha^{\ast}_o-\beta^{\ast}_o=Q^{\prime}-C^{\ast\,\prime\prime } \equiv A^{\ast} , $$
(B.13)

and

$$ \alpha_o -\beta_o =Q^{\prime}-C^{\prime\prime} \equiv A , $$
(B.14)

it is the case that, following from (31), the origin-based tax-harmonizing reforms imply that dQ=0. □

Appendix C

Destination principle: numerical example based on Proposition 2 To simplify matters, suppose that both demands and costs functions are linear and given, respectively, by

(C.1)
(C.2)

and so

$$ P^{\prime}=- \bigl( \beta+\beta^{\ast} \bigr)^{-1}, $$
(C.3)

and the utility the consumer derives from global public goods in the home (foreign) country is Γ(G,G ) (Γ (G ,G)). It can be easily shown, in this case, that (A.10)–(A.12) reduce to, respectively,

(C.4)
(C.5)

and that, by making use of,

$$ dD=-\beta ( dP+dt_{d} ) ,\qquad dD^{\ast}=- \beta^{\ast } \bigl( dP+dt_{d}^{\ast} \bigr) , $$
(C.6)

perturbation of the home country utility function in (11) gives

(C.7)

(An analogous condition applies to the foreign country). Non-cooperative taxes (denoted by the subscript N) are given by setting the derivative of (C.7) with respect to t d equal to zero, that is

(C.8)

(a similar expression holds for \(t_{d}^{\ast}\)).

Suppose now that the demand parameters are a=10, a =9, β=1.2, β =1.3, the marginal utilities of the public goods are Γ G =1.9, \(\varGamma_{G^{\ast}}=1.2\), \(\varGamma_{G}^{\ast }=1.1\), \(\varGamma_{G^{\ast}}^{\ast}=1.8\)—implying that \(\varGamma_{G}+\varGamma_{G}^{\ast}=3=\varGamma_{G^{\ast}}+\varGamma_{G^{\ast }}^{\ast}>1\) (and so global public goods are under-provided with respect to the Samuelson rule)—the costs are c=5>c =4, and the reform parameters are given by ψ=1=ψ and δ=1.

It is the case that (computation performed with MAPLE v12—and all numbers have been rounded to two decimal points) D=2.25, D =1.63, P=5.28, X=0.69, X =3.19, and \(t_{d}^{N}=1.18\), \(t_{d}^{\ast N}=0.39\) (and so it is the home country that is the high tax country). Adding (C.7) and its foreign counterpart gives dV+dV =0.56>0 and so tax harmonization is welfare improving. It is easy also to verify that (following (21)) d(G+G )=0.09 (with \(( Q/e+t_{d} ) - ( Q^{\ast }/e^{\ast}+t_{d}^{\ast} ) =0.17>0\)).

Origin principle: Numerical example based on Proposition 4 Following the same steps as above, it is the case that

(C.9)
(C.10)
(C.11)

Perturbing (11) the non-cooperative origin-based tax in the home country is given by

(C.12)

(an analogous condition holds for the foreign country).

Suppose now that demand parameters are a=20, a =14, β=1.8, β =1.9, the marginal utilities of the public goods are Γ G =1.7, \(\varGamma_{G^{\ast}}=1.6\), \(\varGamma_{G}^{\ast }=1.8\), \(\varGamma_{G^{\ast}}^{\ast}=1.9\), whereas the costs are c=2>c =1, and the reform parameters ψ=1, ψ =1, δ=1. Then it is the case that D=12.11, D =5.67, Q=4.38, X=8.28, X =9.50, and \(t_{o}^{\ast N}=0.81>t_{o}^{N}=0.14\) (so the foreign country is the high tax one). Then, in this case, dV+dV =2.29>0 (with dG+dG =0.42, and \(( t_{o}+AX ) - ( t_{o}^{\ast}+A^{\ast}X^{\ast} ) =-0.34<0\)). □

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Karakosta, O., Kotsogiannis, C. & Lopez-Garcia, MA. Indirect tax harmonization and global public goods. Int Tax Public Finance 21, 29–49 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-012-9246-8

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-012-9246-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation