Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Institutions of conflict management and economic growth revisited: a short note

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Empirica Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We study the effects of institutions of conflict management like corporatism, trust, civic norms and group membership on economic growth. By employing Schneider and Wagner’s (Kyklos 54:509–532, 2001) model and data from 1990–2011, we show that corporatism has (still) a positive coordination effect and a negative rent-seeking effect. The total effect is positive for most countries.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Compare, for example, de Grauwe and Skudelny (1999) and Rodrik (1999). De Grauwe and Skudelny (1999) specifically analyse inefficiencies of bureaucracy, corruption, the extent of political participation, rent seeking as well as the size of the state.

  2. Other studies analysing the effects of institutional factors on unemployment are Nickell et al. (2005), Amable et al. (2007), Bassanini and Duval (2006) and Baccaro and Rei (2007). Their results are not consistent, however, and the papers do not refer specifically to conflict management institutions, but to institutions somewhat related to it: Employment protection legislation, active labour market regulation, minimum wages, unemployment benefits, trade union power, wage inflexibility or taxes.

  3. Compare Alesina and Perotti (1996), Barro (1991), Easterly (2000), Easterly and Levine (1997), Rodrik (1999), Vis et al. (2012), Woldendorp (2011), Acocella et al. (2009) and Acocella et al. (2010).

  4. GINI indicators are not available for every year in the sample. Missing values are imputed by using the most recent available indicator. The number of available indicators varies considerably across countries. There are 20 values for Germany, but only 8 for Ireland, for example.

  5. As a matter of fact, the decision on which items to include in the index is arbitrary to some extent. The items we choose are, to the best of our knowledge, the best suitable ones among those available, both with respect to the content as well as for guaranteeing comparability with the results based on Tarantelli’s (1986) index. Moreover, we did some sensitivity analysis to see that our results are very robust to changes in the number of index-components.

  6. Index-values do not differ for each year, however. In Fig. 1 we indicate how many different values we have for each country.

  7. Remarkably, the lowest value of corporatism, according to our index, is to be found in Switzerland. This country, however, has a long tradition of social partnership and strikes are only seldom observed. We have, of course, checked the values of the components of our index, and presume that in Switzerland, a corporatist political culture is present, although the structure of the institutions does not enforce such a culture. In Switzerland, for example, only 48 % of employees are covered by wage bargaining agreements (Austria: 99 %), but this fact does not necessarily mean that trade unions and employer associations do not coordinate their actions. Since the index-values for Switzerland are somewhat awkward, we have carried out our estimations both with and without data on Switzerland. We see only very marginal differences.

  8. We acknowledge that in principal, we have too few observations (of the trust- and civil norms index-values as well as the group membership indicator) for profound panel-data analysis. Regressions on the cross-section, however, yield similar results.

References

  • Acocella N, de Bartolomeo G, Pauwells W (2010) Is there any scope for corporatism in macroeconomic policy. Empirica 37(4):403–424

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acocella N, de Bartolomeo G, Tirelli P (2009) Some macroeconomics of social pacts. J Econ Behav Organ 72(2):202–213

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Perotti R (1996) Income distribution, political instability, and investment. Eur Econ Rev 40(6):1203–1228

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amable B, Demmou L, Gatti D (2007) Employment performance and institutions: new answers to an old question, IZA Discussion Paper 2731

  • Baccaro L, Rei D (2007) Institutional determinants of unemployment in OECD countries: does the deregulatory view hold water? Int Organ 61:527–569

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro R (1991) Economic growth in a cross section of countries. Q J Econ 106(4):407–443

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bassanini A, Duval R (2006) The determinants of unemployment across OECD countries: reassessing the role of policies and institutions. OECD Econ Stud 42(1):7–86

    Google Scholar 

  • de Grauwe P, Skudelny F (1999) Social conflict and growth in Euroland. CES-discussion paper series 99.13

  • de Haan J (2007) Political institutions and economic growth reconsidered. Presidential address for the European public choice society conference in Turku. Public Choice 131:281–292

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterly W (2000) Can institution resolve an ethnic conflict? Econ Dev Cult Change 49(4):687–706

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterly W, Levine R (1997) Africa’s growth tragedy: policies and ethnic divisions. Q J Econ 112:1203–1250

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eurostat (2014) General government expenditure by function (COFOG). Eurostat-Database. http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/portal/page/portal/statistics/search_database

  • Haipeter T (2012) Sozialpartnerschaft in und nach der Krise: Entwicklungen und Perspektiven. Industrielle Perspektiven 19:387–411

    Google Scholar 

  • Knack S, Keefer P (1997) Does social capital have an economic pay off? A cross country investigation. Q J Econ 112(4):1251–1288

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levine R (2000) Bank-based or market-based financial systems: which is better? J Financ Intermed 11(4):398–428

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nickell S, Nunziata L, Ochel W (2005) Unemployment in the OECD since the 1960s. What do we know? Econ J 115:1–27

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • North DC (1990) Institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, MA

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2013a) Gross domestic product (expenditure approach) per head, US $, constant prices, constant PPPs, Annual data. OECD Stat, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2013b) Dataset: income distribution—inequality. Gini coefficient (after taxes and transfers). OECD Stat, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson M (1982) The rise and decline of nations: economic growth, stagflation, and social rigidities. Yale University Press, New Haven

    Google Scholar 

  • Putnam R (1993) Making democracy work. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik D (1999) Where did all the growth go? External shocks, social conflict and growth collapses. J Econ Growth 4:385–412

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sachs A (2010) A Bayesian approach to determine the impact of institutions on the unemployment rate. ZEW discussion paper 10-058

  • Schneider F, Wagner A (2001) Institutions of conflict management and economic growth in the European Union. Kyklos 54:509–532

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tarantelli E (1986) The regulation of inflation and unemployment. Ind Relat 25(1):1–15

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vis B, Woldendorp J, Keman H (2012) Economic performance and institutions, capturing the dependent variable. Eur Polit Sci Rev 4(1):73–96

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Visser J (2011) Data base on institutional characteristics of trade unions, wage setting, state intervention and social pacts 1960–2010. ICTWSS

  • Woldendorp J (2011) Corporatism in small north-west countries 1970–2006: business as usual, decline or a new phenomenon? Working paper series, Department of Political Science, VU University of Amsterdam

  • World Bank (2014a) Adjusted savings: education expenditure (% of GNI), 1960–2011. Data.worldbank.org, The World Bank Group

  • World Bank (2014b) Gross fixed capital formation (% of GDP), 1960–2011. Data.worldbank.org, The World Bank Group

  • World Bank (2014c) Exports and imports of goods and services (% of GDP). Data.worldbank.org, The World Bank Group

  • World Bank (2014d) Population growth (annual %). Data.worldbank.org, The World Bank Group

  • World Values Survey (2005) WVS five wave aggregated file 1981–2005. www.worldvaluessurvey.org

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Friedrich Schneider.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Schneider, F., Haigner, S.D., Jenewein, S. et al. Institutions of conflict management and economic growth revisited: a short note. Empirica 41, 577–587 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10663-014-9255-1

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10663-014-9255-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation