Skip to main content
Log in

Emission Reduction Technology Licensing and Diffusion Under Command-and-Control Regulation

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper, we discuss a patented emission reduction technology that a monopolistic upstream eco-industry licenses to the polluting firms in a downstream oligopolistic industry, which is subject to command-and-control regulation. We explicitly model the interaction between the outside innovator and the polluting firms, using a non-cooperative game-theoretical framework. We find that full and partial diffusion can both occur in equilibrium, depending on the relationship between environmental regulation stringency and cleanliness improvement of the new technology. Furthermore, we study the impacts of environmental regulation stringency and the improvement in cleanliness on the adoption and the diffusion of the emission reduction technology.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11
Fig. 12

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In the absence of environmental regulation, the resulting emission for each producer is \(a/(n+1)\).

  2. Strictly speaking, the optimal number of licensees should take integer values. In the following, we ignore the integer constraint on m and consider m as a continuous variable to facilitate the analysis. The introduction of integer constraint does not change the key insights in our model. A similar simplification is also made in Bagchi and Mukherjee (2014).

References

  • Ambec S, Cohen MA, Elgie S, Lanoie P (2013) The Porter hypothesis at 20: can environmental regulation enhance innovation and competitiveness? Rev Environ Econ Policy 7(1):2–22

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amir R, Germain M, van Steenberghe V (2008) On the impact of innovation on the marginal abatement cost curve. J Public Econ Theory 10(6):985–1010

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • André FJ (2015) Strategic effects and the Porter hypothesis. Munich Personal RePEc archive, MPRA Paper No. 62237

  • Arguedas C, Camacho E, Zofío JL (2010) Environmental policy instruments: technology adoption incentives with imperfect compliance. Environ Resour Econ 47(2):261–274

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bagchi A, Mukherjee A (2014) Technology licensing in a differentiated oligopoly. Int Rev Econ Finance 29:455–465

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baker E, Clarke L, Shittu E (2008) Technical change and the marginal cost of abatement. Energy Econ 30(6):2799–2816

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bauman Y, Lee M, Seeley K (2008) Does technological innovation really reduce marginal abatement costs? Some theory, algebraic evidence, and policy implications. Environ Resour Econ 40(4):507–527

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brännlund R, Lundgren T (2009) Environmental policy without costs? A review of the Porter Hypothesis. Int Rev Environ Resour Econ 3(2):75–117

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bréchet T, Jouvet PA (2008) Environmental innovation and the cost of pollution abatement revisited. Ecol Econ 65(2):262–265

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bréchet T, Meunier G (2014) Are clean technology and environmental quality conflicting policy goals? Resour Energy Econ 38:61–83

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Canton J, Soubeyran A, Stahn H (2008) Optimal environmental policy, vertical structure and imperfect competition. Environ Resour Econ 40(3):369–382

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • David M, Sinclair-Desgagné B (2005) Environmental regulation and the eco-industry. J Regul Econ 28(2):141–155

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • David M, Sinclair-Desgagné B (2010) Pollution abatement subsidies and the eco-industry. Environ Resour Econ 45(2):271–282

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • David M, Nimubona AD, Sinclair-Desgagné B (2011) Emission taxes and the market for abatement goods and services. Resour Energy Econ 33:179–191

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goeschl T, Perino G (2017) The climate policy hold-up: green technologies, intellectual property rights, and the abatement incentives of international agreements. Scand J Econ 119(3):709–732

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jung C, Krutilla K, Boyd R (1996) Incentives for advanced pollution abatement technology at the industry level: an evaluation of policy alternatives. J Environ Econ Manag 30(1):95–111

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kamien MI, Tauman Y (1984) The private value of a patent: a game theoretic analysis. Zeitschrift für Nationalokonomie/J Econ 4(Supplement):93–118

    Google Scholar 

  • Kamien MI, Tauman Y (1986) Fee versus royalties and the private value of a patent. Q J Econ 101(3):471–491

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kamien MI, Tauman Y (2002) Patent licensing: the inside story. Manch Sch 70(1):7–15

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kamien MI, Oren SS, Tauman Y (1992) Optimal licensing of cost-reducing innovation. J Math Econ 21(5):483–508

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katz ML, Shapiro C (1985) On the licensing of innovation. Rand J Econ 16(4):504–520

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katz ML, Shapiro C (1986) How to license intangible property. Q J Econ 101(3):567–590

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malueg DA (1989) Emission credit trading and the incentive to adopt new pollution abatement technology. J Environ Econ Manag 16(1):52–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McManus P (2009) Environmental regilation. Elsevier Ltd, Chatswood

    Google Scholar 

  • Milliman SR, Prince R (1989) Firm incentives to promote technological change in pollution control. J Environ Econ Manag 17(3):247–265

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Montero JP (2002) Permits, standards and technology innovation. J Environ Econ Manag 44(1):23–44

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perino G (2010) Technology diffusion with market power in the upstream industry. Environ Resour Econ 46(4):403–428

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perino G, Requate T (2012) Does more stringent environmental regulation induce or reduce technology adoption? When the rate of technology adoption is inverted U-shaped. J Environ Econ Manag 64(3):456–467

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Requate T (2005) Dynamic incentives by environmental policy instruments—a survey. Ecol Econ 54(2–3):175–195

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Requate T, Unold W (2001) On the incentives created by policy instruments to adopt advanced abatement technology if firms are asymmetric. J Inst Theor Econ 157(4):536–554

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Requate T, Unold W (2003) Environmental policy incentives to adopt advanced abatement technology: will the true ranking please stand up? Eur Econ Rev 47(1):125–146

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schwartz S, Stahn H (2014) Competitive permit markets and vertical structures: the relevance of imperfectly competitive eco-industries. J Public Econ Theory 16(1):69–95

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen D, Tauman Y (2007) General licensing schemes for a cost-reducing innovation. Games Econ Behav 59(1):163–186

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang XH (1998) Fee versus royalty licensing in a Cournot duopoly model. Econ Lett 60(1):55–62

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang XH, Yang BZ (1999) On licensing under Bertrand competition. Aust Econ Pap 38(2):106–119

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to Co-Editor and three anonymous referees, whose comments greatly improved the paper. The authors also acknowledge financial support from the National Natural Science Foundation of China (71202052, 71431004, 71573087, 71473085), Program for New Century Excellent Talents in University (NCET-11-0637), Humanities and Social Science Youth Foundation of the Ministry of Education of China (12YJC630240) and the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Haiyang Xia.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Proofs

Proof of Lemma 1

The first order conditions for each green and brown producer are given by

$$\begin{aligned} \left\{ {\begin{array}{l} a-(m+1)q_g -(n-m)q_b =0 \\ a-mq_g -(n-m+1)q_b =0 \\ \end{array}} \right. \end{aligned}$$

Hence the best response functions:

$$\begin{aligned} q_g^{*} (q_b )= & {} \frac{a-(n-m)q_b }{m+1}\\ q_b^{*} (q_g )= & {} \frac{a-mq_g }{n-m+1} \end{aligned}$$

Solving first order conditions simultaneously and we have \(q_g^{*} =q_b^{*} =a/{(n+1)}\). However \(q_b^{*} =a/{(n+1)}\) is not feasible since the carbon cap \(\kappa <a/{(n+1)}\) requires \(q_b <a/{(n+1)}\).

Take the first order derivative of \(q_b^{*} (q_g )\) on m:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial q_b^{*} (q_g )}{\partial m}=\frac{(n+1)}{(n-m+1)^{2}}(\frac{a}{n+1}-q_g ) \end{aligned}$$

Hence if \(q_g \ge a/{(n+1)}\), \({\partial q_b^{*} (q_g )}/{\partial m}\le 0\), which means the brown producer’s quantity will decline with mincreases. Therefore, if \(q_g \ge a/{(n+1)}\), we have

$$\begin{aligned} q_b^{*} (m;q_g )\ge q_b^{*} (n;q_g )=a-nq_g \ge \frac{a}{n+1} \end{aligned}$$

Hence with the constraint \(q_b \le \kappa <a/{(n+1)}\), the optimal output for the brown producer is \(q_b^{*} =\kappa \).

Now consider the case \(q_g <a/{(n+1)}\). In this case, \({\partial q_b^{*} (q_g )}/{\partial m}>0\), which means the brown producer’s quantity will increase with s increases. Therefore, if \(q_g <a/{(n+1)}\), we have

$$\begin{aligned} q_b^{*} (m;q_g )>q_b^{*} (1;q_g )=\frac{a-q_g }{n}>\frac{a}{n+1} \end{aligned}$$

Again with the constraint \(q_b \le \kappa <a/{(n+1)}\), the optimal output for the brown producer is \(q_b^{*} =\kappa \).

Therefore the optimal output for each brown producer is \(q_b^{*} =\kappa \).

Next let us consider the green producers’ production quantity. Since \(q_b^{*} =\kappa \), the green producer’s optimal output when there is no carbon emission constraint is

$$\begin{aligned} q_g^{*} (q_b =\kappa )=\frac{a-(n-m)\kappa }{m+1} \end{aligned}$$

And the emission constraint requires \(q_g \le \kappa /{(1-g)}\). Hence the optimal output for each green producer is \(q_g^{*} =\min \left\{ {\frac{a-(n-m)\kappa }{m+1},\frac{\kappa }{1-g}} \right\} \). \(\square \)

Proof of Corollary 1

Since \(e\in (0,1)\), \(\kappa /e>\kappa \) always holds. We only need to check if \(\frac{a-(n-m)\kappa }{m+1}>\kappa \).

Since \(\left[ {\frac{a-(n-m)\kappa }{m+1}} \right] ^{\prime }_m =\frac{n+1}{(m+1)^{2}}\left[ {\kappa -\frac{a}{n+1}} \right] <0\), we have

$$\begin{aligned} \left[ {\frac{a-(n-m)\kappa }{m+1}} \right]>\frac{a-(n-n)\kappa }{n+1}=\frac{a}{n+1}>\kappa \end{aligned}$$

\(\square \)

Proof of Lemma 2

In Case A1, from Lemma 1, each licensee’s equilibrium output level is \(\kappa /e\), and each non-licensee’s output level is \(\kappa \). Given fixed-fee contract F, the profit of a producer that accepts the contract to be a licensee is \(\pi _g^{A1} (m,F)=\left[ {a-(n+{(1-e)m}/e)\kappa } \right] \kappa /e-F\), where m is the total number of licensees. The profit of a producer that rejects the contract is \(\pi _b^{A1} (m)=\left[ {a-(n+{(1-e)m}/e)\kappa } \right] \kappa \). Hence, if the outside innovator wants m producers to accept its offer to be licensees, it is optimal for the innovator to set the upfront fee F high enough till \(\pi _g^{A1} (m,F)=\pi _b^{A1} (m)\). Thus, in Case A1, given that the number of licensees is m, the optimal fixed fee set by the patent holder is

$$\begin{aligned} F^{A1}(m)=\left[ {a-\left( n+\frac{(1-e)m}{e}\right) \kappa } \right] \frac{(1-e)\kappa }{e}. \end{aligned}$$

In Case A2, there exists a threshold \(\hat{{m}}\in [0,n]\); thus, the equilibrium output level of each green producer is \(\kappa /e\) for \(m\le \hat{{m}}\) and \({\left[ {a-(n-m)\kappa } \right] }/{(m+1)}\) for \(m\ge \hat{{m}}\). First, we consider the case \(m\le \hat{{m}}\). In this case, given fixed-fee contract F, the profit of a producer that accepts the contract to be a licensee is \(\left. {\pi _g^{A2} (m,F)} \right| _{m\le \hat{{m}}} =\left[ {a-(n+{(1-e)m}/e)\kappa } \right] \kappa /e-F\). The profit of a producer that rejects the contract is \(\left. {\pi _b^{A2} (m)} \right| _{m\le \hat{{m}}} =\left[ {a-(n+{(1-e)m}/e)\kappa } \right] \kappa \). Hence, if the outside innovator wants m producers to accept its offer to be licensees, it is optimal for her to set the upfront fee F high enough till \(\left. {\pi _g^{A2} (m,F)} \right| _{m\le \hat{{m}}} =\left. {\pi _b^{A2} (m)} \right| _{m\le \hat{{m}}} \). Thus, in the case of \(m\le \hat{{m}}\), the optimal fixed fee set by the patent holder is

$$\begin{aligned} F^{A2}(m)\left| {_{m\le \hat{{m}}} } \right. =\left[ {a-\left( n+\frac{(1-e)m}{e}\right) \kappa } \right] \frac{(1-e)\kappa }{e}. \end{aligned}$$

Now let us consider the case \(m\ge \hat{{m}}\). In this case, given the fixed-fee contract F, the profit of a producer that accepts the contract to be a licensee is \(\left. {\pi _g^{A2} (m,F)} \right| _{m\ge \hat{{m}}} =\left[ {{\left( {a-(n-m)\kappa } \right) }/{(m+1)}} \right] ^{2}-F\).

The profit of a producer that rejects the fixed-fee contract is \(\left. {\pi _b^{A2} (m)} \right| _{m\ge \hat{{m}}} \!=\!\big [ {\left( {a\!-\!(n\!-\!m)\kappa } \right) }/{(m+1)} \big ]\kappa \). If the outside innovator wants m producers to accept the fixed-fee contract, it is optimal for her to set the upfront fee F high enough till \(\left. {\pi _g^{A2} (m,F)} \right| _{m\ge \hat{{m}}} =\left. {\pi _b^{A2} (m)} \right| _{m\ge \hat{{m}}} \). Hence, in the case of \(m\ge \hat{{m}}\), given that the number of licensees is m, the optimal fixed fee set by the patent holder is

$$\begin{aligned} F^{A2}(m)\left| {_{m\ge \hat{{m}}} } \right. =\frac{\left[ {a-(n-m)\kappa } \right] }{(m+1)}\frac{\left[ {a-(n+1)\kappa } \right] }{(m+1)}. \end{aligned}$$

In Case A3, the equilibrium output of each green producer is \({\left[ {a-(n-m)\kappa } \right] }/{(m+1)}\). Given the fixed-fee contract F, the profit of a producer that accepts the contract to be a licensee is \(\pi _g^{A3} (m,F)=\left[ {{\left( {a-(n-m)\kappa } \right) }/{(m+1)}} \right] ^{2}-F\). The profit of a producer that rejects the contract is \(\pi _b^{A3} (m)=\left[ {{\left( {a-(n-m)\kappa } \right) }/{(m+1)}} \right] \kappa \). If the outside innovator wants the number of licensees to be m, it is optimal for her to set the upfront fee F high enough till \(\pi _g^{A3} (m,F)=\pi _b^{A3} (m)\). Hence, in Case A3, given that the number of licensees is m, the optimal fixed fee set by the patent holder is

$$\begin{aligned} F^{A3}(m)=\frac{\left[ {a-(n-m)\kappa } \right] }{(m+1)}\frac{\left[ {a-(n+1)\kappa } \right] }{(m+1)}. \end{aligned}$$

\(\square \)

Proof of Theorem 1

From Lemma 2, in Case A1 the optimal fixed fee is the equilibrium price \((\left[ {a-(n+{(1-e)m}/e)\kappa } \right] )\) multiplied by the output difference between each green producer and each brown producer \(({(1-e)\kappa }/e=q_g^{*} -q_b^{*} )\). In this case, the increase in m does not diminish the green producers’ competitive advantage in quantity over the brown producers since \(q_g^{*} -q_b^{*} \) is independent of m. However, with the increasing number of green producers, the total output will increase, and the equilibrium price for the product will decrease as a result. Thus, the optimal fixed fee set by the outside innovator decreases when the number of licensees increases, that is, \({\partial F^{A1}(m)}/{\partial m}<0\).

Next, let us consider the patent holder’s decision on the number of licensees (i.e., m), which can be formulated as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \mathop {max}\limits _{m\le n} \;\;\Pi ^{A1}(m)=m\left[ {a-\left( n+\frac{(1-e)m}{e}\right) \kappa } \right] \frac{(1-e)\kappa }{e}, \end{aligned}$$

where \(\Pi ^{A1}\) denotes the outside innovator’s profit in Region A1.

The first derivative of the function \(\Pi ^{A1}(m)\) is

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \Pi ^{A1}(m)}{\partial m}=\frac{(1-e)\kappa \left[ {ae-\left( {2(1-e)m+en} \right) \kappa } \right] }{e^{2}} \end{aligned}$$

The second derivative of the function \(\Pi ^{A1}(m)\) is

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^{2}\Pi ^{A1}(m)}{\partial m^{2}}=-\frac{2(1-e)^{2}\kappa ^{2}}{e^{2}} \end{aligned}$$

Since the second derivative of the function \(\Pi ^{A1}(m)\) is negative, using first order condition we have \(m^{A1}=\frac{e\left( {a-n\kappa } \right) }{2(1-e)\kappa }\). And \(m^{A1}\le n\) iff \(e\le \frac{2n\kappa }{a+n\kappa }\). Hence, if \(e\le \frac{2n\kappa }{a+n\kappa }\), the optimal number of licensees for the patent holder is \(m^{A1{*}}=\frac{e\left( {a-n\kappa } \right) }{2(1-e)\kappa }\), otherwise \(m^{A1{*}}=n\).

Let \(\hat{{\kappa }}=\frac{(n-1)}{n}\bar{{\kappa }}\), we have \(\hat{{\hat{{e}}}}(\kappa )=\kappa /{\bar{{\kappa }}}\ge \frac{2n\kappa }{a+n\kappa }\)for \(\kappa \ge \hat{{\kappa }}\). Hence, if \(\kappa \ge \hat{{\kappa }}\), then \(m^{A1{*}}=n\). If \(\kappa \le \hat{{\kappa }}\), then

$$\begin{aligned} m^{A1{*}}=\left\{ {\begin{array}{l@{\quad }l} \frac{e\left( {a-n\kappa } \right) }{2(1-e)\kappa },&{} \textit{if}\;\hat{{\hat{{e}}}}(\kappa )\le e\le \frac{2n\kappa }{a+n\kappa } \\ n,&{} \textit{if}\;e\ge \frac{2n\kappa }{a+n\kappa } \\ \end{array}} \right. . \end{aligned}$$

\(\square \)

Proof of Theorem 2

In Case A2, for \(m\le \hat{{m}}\), the optimal fixed fee set by the patent holder is

$$\begin{aligned} F^{A2}(m)\left| {_{m\le \hat{{m}}} } \right. =\left[ {a-\left( n+\frac{(1-e)m}{e}\right) \kappa } \right] \frac{(1-e)\kappa }{e} \end{aligned}$$

where \({(1-e)\kappa }/e=q_g^{*} -q_b^{*} \) is the output difference between each green producer and each brown producer, and \(\left[ {a-(n+{(1-e)m}/e)\kappa } \right] =p^{{*}}\) is the equilibrium price for the product. Since the equilibrium price for the product decreases with more producers become licensees, the optimal fixed fee set by the outside innovator will decrease in m, that is, \({\partial F^{A1}(m)}/{\partial m}<0\).

The problem encountered by the outside innovator can be formulated as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \mathop {max}\limits _{m\le \hat{{m}}} \;\;\Pi ^{A2}(m)=m\left[ {a-\left( n+\frac{(1-e)m}{e}\right) \kappa } \right] \frac{(1-e)\kappa }{e} \end{aligned}$$

where \(\Pi ^{A2}\) represents the outside innovator’s profit in Case A2.

For \(m\ge \hat{{m}}\), given that the number of licensees is m, the optimal fixed fee set by the patent holder is

$$\begin{aligned} F^{A2}(m)\left| {_{m\ge \hat{{m}}} } \right. =\frac{\left[ {a-(n-m)\kappa } \right] }{(m+1)}\frac{\left[ {a-(n+1)\kappa } \right] }{(m+1)} \end{aligned}$$

where \({\left[ {a-(n+1)\kappa } \right] }/{(m+1)}=q_g^{*} -q_b^{*} \) is the output difference between each green producer and each brown producer, and \({\left[ {a-(n-m)\kappa } \right] }/{(m+1)}=p^{{*}}\) is the equilibrium price for the product. In contrast to the case of \(m\le \hat{{m}}\), in the case of \(m\ge \hat{{m}}\), the output difference \(q_g^{*} -q_b^{*} \) is decreasing with the increasing number of green producers. This implies that the increase in the number of licensees does diminish each green producer’ competitive advantage in quantity over each brown producer.

Thus, for \(m\ge \hat{{m}}\), the problem faced by the outside innovator is

$$\begin{aligned} \mathop {max}\limits _{m\ge \hat{{m}}} \;\;\Pi ^{A2}(m)=m\frac{\left[ {a-(n-m)\kappa } \right] \left[ {a-(n+1)\kappa } \right] }{(m+1)^{2}}. \end{aligned}$$

In Case A2, from Lemma 1 the equilibrium output for each green producer is

$$\begin{aligned} q_g^{A2} =\left\{ {\begin{array}{l@{\quad }l} \frac{\kappa }{e},&{} \textit{if}\;\frac{(m+1)\kappa }{(n+1)\bar{{\kappa }}-(n-m)\kappa }\le e\le \hat{{\hat{{e}}}}(\kappa ) \\ \frac{a-(n-m)\kappa }{m+1},&{} \textit{if}\;\hat{{e}}(\kappa )\le e\le \frac{(m+1)\kappa }{(n+1)\bar{{\kappa }}-(n-m)\kappa } \\ \end{array}} \right. \end{aligned}$$

Equivalently, since \(\hat{{e}}(\kappa )\le e\le \hat{{\hat{{e}}}}(\kappa )\), the equilibrium output for each green producer is

$$\begin{aligned} q_g^{A2} =\left\{ {\begin{array}{l@{\quad }l} \frac{\kappa }{e},&{} \textit{if}\;m\le \hat{{m}} \\ \frac{a-(n-m)\kappa }{m+1},&{} \textit{if}\;m\ge \hat{{m}} \\ \end{array}} \right. \end{aligned}$$

where \(\hat{{m}}=\frac{(n+1)e\bar{{\kappa }}-(1+ne)\kappa }{(1-e)\kappa }\), and it is easily to verify that \(0\le \hat{{m}}\le n\) in Case A2.

First let us consider the case \(m\le \hat{{m}}\) and the resulting equilibrium output for each green producer is \(q_g^{A2} \left| {_{m\le \hat{{m}}} } \right. =\kappa /e\). Given \(m\le \hat{{m}}\), the optimal fixed fee for the patent holder is \(F^{A2}(m)\left| {_{m\le \hat{{m}}} } \right. =\left[ {a-(n+\frac{(1-e)m}{e})\kappa } \right] \frac{(1-e)\kappa }{e}\) and the problem facing by the outside innovator is

$$\begin{aligned} \mathop {max}\limits _{m\le \hat{{m}}} \;\;\Pi ^{A2}(m)=m\left[ {a-\left( n+\frac{(1-e)m}{e}\right) \kappa } \right] \frac{(1-e)\kappa }{e} \end{aligned}$$

Apply a similar analysis as in the proof of theorem 1 we have the following results:

  1. (i)

    if \(\kappa \ge \hat{{\kappa }}\), then \(m^{A2{*}}\left| {_{m\le \hat{{m}}} } \right. =\hat{{m}}\).

  2. (ii)

    if \(\kappa \le \hat{{\kappa }}\), then

    $$\begin{aligned} m^{A2{*}}\left| {_{m\le \hat{{m}}} } \right. =\left\{ {\begin{array}{l@{\quad }l} \frac{e\left( {a-n\kappa } \right) }{2(1-e)\kappa },&{} \textit{if}\frac{2\kappa }{a-n\kappa }\le e\le \hat{{\hat{{e}}}}(\kappa ) \\ \hat{{m}},&{} \textit{if}\;\hat{{e}}(\kappa )\le e\le \frac{2\kappa }{a-n\kappa } \\ \end{array}} \right. . \end{aligned}$$

Now let us consider the case \(m\ge \hat{{m}}\) and the resulting equilibrium output for each green producer is \(q_g^{A2} \left| {_{m\ge \hat{{m}}} } \right. =\frac{a-(n-m)\kappa }{m+1}\). Given \(m\ge \hat{{m}}\), the optimal fixed fee set by the patent holder is \(F^{A2}(m)\left| {_{m\ge \hat{{m}}} } \right. =\frac{\left[ {a-(n-m)\kappa } \right] \left[ {a-(n+1)\kappa } \right] }{(m+1)^{2}}\) and the problem facing by the outside innovator is

$$\begin{aligned} \mathop {max}\limits _{m\ge \hat{{m}}} \;\;\Pi ^{A2}(m)=m\frac{\left[ {a-(n-m)\kappa } \right] \left[ {a-(n+1)\kappa } \right] }{(m+1)^{2}} \end{aligned}$$

The results are following:

  1. (i)

    if \(\kappa \ge \hat{{\kappa }}\), then \(m^{A2{*}}\left| {_{m\ge \hat{{m}}} } \right. =n\).

  2. (ii)

    if \(\kappa \le \hat{{\kappa }}\), then

    $$\begin{aligned} m^{A2{*}}\left| {_{m\ge \hat{{m}}} } \right. =\left\{ {\begin{array}{l@{\quad }l} \hat{{m}},&{} \textit{if}\frac{2\kappa }{a-n\kappa }\le e\le \hat{{\hat{{e}}}}(\kappa ) \\ \frac{a-n\kappa }{a-(2+n)\kappa },&{} \textit{if}\;\hat{{e}}(\kappa )\le e\le \frac{2\kappa }{a-n\kappa } \\ \end{array}} \right. . \end{aligned}$$

Based on the above analysis we have:

  1. (i)

    if \(\kappa \ge \hat{{\kappa }}\), \(m^{A2{*}}=n\).

  2. (ii)

    if \(\kappa \le \hat{{\kappa }}\), then

$$\begin{aligned} m^{A2{*}}=\left\{ {\begin{array}{l@{\quad }l} \frac{e\left( {a-n\kappa } \right) }{2(1-e)\kappa },&{} \textit{if}\;{e}(\kappa )\le e\le \hat{{\hat{{e}}}}(\kappa ) \\ \frac{a-n\kappa }{a-(2+n)\kappa },&{} \textit{if}\;\hat{{e}}(\kappa )\le e\le {e}(\kappa ) \\ \end{array}} \right. . \end{aligned}$$

where\({e}(\kappa )=\frac{2\kappa }{a-n\kappa }\). \(\square \)

Proof of Theorem 3

From Lemma 2, in Case A3, given that the number of licensees is m, the optimal fixed fee set by the patent holder is

$$\begin{aligned} F^{A3}(m)=\frac{\left[ {a-(n-m)\kappa } \right] }{(m+1)}\frac{\left[ {a-(n+1)\kappa } \right] }{(m+1)} \end{aligned}$$

where \({\left[ {a-(n+1)\kappa } \right] }/{(m+1)}=q_g^{*} -q_b^{*} \) is the output difference between each green producer and each brown producer, and \({\left[ {a-(n-m)\kappa } \right] }/{(m+1)}=p^{{*}}\) is the equilibrium price for the product. In this region, the output difference \(q_g^{*} -q_b^{*} \) and the equilibrium price \(p^{{*}}\) are both decreasing with the increasing number of green producers. Hence, the optimal fixed fee set by the outside innovator will decrease in m, that is, \({\partial F^{A3}(m)}/{\partial m}<0\).

The problem encountered by the outside innovator can be formulated as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \mathop {max}\limits _m \;\;\Pi ^{A3}(m)=m\frac{\left[ {a-(n-m)\kappa } \right] \left[ {a-(n+1)\kappa } \right] }{(m+1)^{2}} \end{aligned}$$

Let \(\Lambda (m)=\frac{m\left[ {a-(n-m)\kappa } \right] }{(m+1)^{2}}\), to maximize \(\Pi ^{A3}(m)\) equals to maximize \(\Lambda (m)\). The first derivative of the function \(\Lambda (m)\) is

$$\begin{aligned} \Lambda '(m)=\frac{a(1-m)+\kappa \left[ {m\left( {2+n} \right) -n} \right] }{\left( {1+m} \right) ^{3}} \end{aligned}$$

Using first order condition we have

$$\begin{aligned} m^{A3}=\frac{a-n\kappa }{a-(2+n)\kappa } \end{aligned}$$

The second derivative of the function \(\Lambda (m)\) at \(m^{A3}\) is

$$\begin{aligned} {\Lambda }''(m^{A3})=-\frac{\left( {a-\kappa \left( {2+n} \right) } \right) ^{4}}{8\left( {a-\kappa \left( {1+n} \right) } \right) ^{3}}<0 \end{aligned}$$

which means \(\Lambda (m)\) is concave at \(m^{A3}\).

Firstly, if \(\kappa \ge \frac{a}{2+n}\), then \({\Lambda }'(m)=\frac{a(1-m)+\kappa \left[ {m\left( {2+n} \right) -n} \right] }{\left( {1+m} \right) ^{3}}\ge \frac{2a}{\left( {1+m} \right) ^{3}\left( {2+n} \right) }>0\), which means the patent holder’s profit is increasing with the number of licensee increases. Hence the optimal number of licensees for the outside innovator is \(m^{A3{*}}=n\). Secondly, if \(\kappa <\frac{a}{2+n}\), then we have\(m^{A3{*}}=\frac{a-n\kappa }{a-(2+n)\kappa }>0\). We know that \(m^{A3}=\frac{a-n\kappa }{a-(2+n)\kappa }\le n\) iff \(\kappa \le \hat{{\kappa }}\). And \(\hat{{\kappa }}<\frac{a}{2+n}\) holds for sure. Hence in Region A3, the optimal number of licensees for the patent holder is

$$\begin{aligned} m^{A3{*}}=\left\{ {\begin{array}{l@{\quad }l} \frac{a-n\kappa }{a-(2+n)\kappa },&{} \textit{if}\;\kappa \le \hat{{\kappa }} \\ n,&{} { otherwise} \\ \end{array}} \right. . \end{aligned}$$

\(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Xia, H., Fan, T. & Chang, X. Emission Reduction Technology Licensing and Diffusion Under Command-and-Control Regulation. Environ Resource Econ 72, 477–500 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-017-0201-0

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-017-0201-0

Keywords

Navigation