Skip to main content
Log in

Brown Growth, Green Growth, and the Efficiency of Urbanization

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We analyze the efficiency of urbanization patterns in a stylized dynamic model of urban growth with three sectors of production. Pollution, as a force that discourages agglomeration, is caused by domestic production. We show that cities are too large and too few in number in uncoordinated equilibrium if economic growth implies increasing pollution (‘brown growth’). If, however, production becomes cleaner over time (‘green growth’) the equilibrium urbanization path reaches the efficient urbanization path after finite time without need of a coordinating mechanism. We also generalize these results by taking other forms of congestion and urban land markets into account.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. With strong migration restrictions, as they prevail in many regions in China, cities may on the other hand be inefficiently small (Au and Henderson 2006).

  2. Thus, we neglect transport cost for the consumption good and assume that transport cost are infinite for the intermediate goods. Transport costs are important to consider if one is interested in global pollutants for example by greenhouse gases (Gaigné et al. 2012), but they are not in the core interest when studying the effects of local pollution.

  3. Without gaining further insights, we could model this trade-off in more detail by allowing for substitution between a cheap but relatively dirty resource input and an expensive but relatively clean resource input.

  4. In Appendix A.4 we consider an extension of the model where utility is also derived from consuming residential space. In this extension, individuals face a trade-off between commuting costs that increase, and housing prices that decrease, with the distance from the city center. We show that all our results generalize to this setting.

  5. It is possible to endogenize the rates of human capital growth and the distribution of the two types of human capital across the two sectors. We skip this complication to focus the analysis on the question of efficiency.

  6. Note that both issues are directly linked to the variable input in the SME sector: on the one hand, without intervention producers do not internalize the pollution effects from resource input use, on the other hand, the price of imported resource inputs might be too low relative to monopolistically supplied locally produced inputs. The government trades off these two externalities by determining the level of resource inputs that maximizes local welfare; it can implements this level by a quantity or tax/subsidy policy.

  7. Note that the fully optimal allocation can be achieved only if population size is optimal as well.

  8. See Appendix A.1. There we also show that the solution of (9a) exists and is unique.

  9. The assumed productivity differences in the traditional sectors coordinate migration, as workers would be indifferent between regions with identical productivities.

  10. Another type of stable equilibrium with one smaller and one larger city is also possible. In the right panel of Fig. 1, this would correspond to a situation where the two curves intersect more than three times. However, with increasing N(t), the two curves move apart and eventually the asymmetric equilibrium will disappear, while the symmetric equilibrium still exists and is stable. Thus, an asymmetric equilibrium can only exist for small N(t): as N(t) grows big enough, eventually only the symmetric equilibrium is stable.

  11. Note that this condition implies \(2\,\overline{n}_2>3\,n^{\text {opt}}\), or equivalently, \(v(\frac{3}{2}\,n^{\text {opt}})>\beta _3\), because \(v(\frac{3}{2}\,n^{\text {opt}})>v(2\,n^{\text {opt}})>\beta _2>\beta _3\).

References

  • Anas A (1992) On the birth and growth of cities. Reg Sci Urban Econ 22(2):243–258

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anas A, Xiong K (2005) The formation and growth of specialized cities: efficiency without developers or Malthusian traps. Reg Sci Urban Econ 35:445–470

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni J, Levinson A (2001) The simple analytics of the environmental Kuznets curve. J Public Econ 80:269–286

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arnott R, Hochman O, Rausser GC (2008) Pollution and land use: optimum and decentralization. J Urban Econ 64(2):390–407

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Au C-C, Henderson JV (2006) Are Chinese cities too small? Rev Econ Stud 73(3):549–576

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Behrens K, Duranton G, Robert-Nicoud F (2014) Productive cities: sorting, selection, and agglomeration. J Polit Econ 122(3):507–553

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Black D, Henderson JV (1999) A theory of urban growth. J Polit Econ 107(2):252–284

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Egli H, Steger TM (2007) A dynamic model of the environmental Kuznets Curve: turning point and public policy. Environ Resour Econ 36(1):15–34

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fujita M (1989) Urban economic theory—land use and city size. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gaigné C, Riou S, Thisse J-F (2012) Are compact cities environmentally friendly? J Urban Econ 72(2–3):123–136

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman G, Krueger A (1995) Economic growth and the environment. Q J Econ 110(2):353–377

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helsley RW, Strange WC (1997) Limited developers. Can J Econ 30(3):329–348

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henderson JV (1974) The sizes and types of cities. Am Econ Rev 64(4):640–656

    Google Scholar 

  • Henderson JV (1977) Externalities in a spatial context: the case of air pollution. J Public Econ 7:89–110

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henderson JV (1988) Urban development: theory, fact, and illusion. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Henderson JV (2002a) Urban primacy, external costs, and quality of life. Resour Energy Econ 24:95–106

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henderson JV (2002b) Urbanization in developing countries. World Bank Res Obs 17(1):89–112

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henderson JV, Venables AJ (2009) The dynamics of city formation. Rev Econ Dyn 12(2):233–254

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahn ME (2006) Green cities: urban growth and the environment. Brookings Institution Press, Washington, D.C.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahn ME, Schwartz J (2008) Urban air pollution progress despite sprawl: the ‘greening’ of the vehicle fleet. J Urban Econ 63(3):775–787

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P (1991) Increasing returns and economic geography. J Polit Econ 99:483–499

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kyriakopoulou E, Xepapadeas A (2011) Spatial location decisions under environmental policy and housing externalities. Environ Econ Policy Stud 13(3):195–217

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kyriakopoulou E, Xepapadeas A (2013) Environmental policy, first nature advantage and the emergence of economic clusters. Reg Sci Urban Econ 43(1):101–116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lange A, Quaas MF (2007) Economic geography and the effect of environmental pollution on agglomeration size. BE J Econ Anal Policy 1, Topics, Article 52

  • Lieb CM (2002) The environmental Kuznets curve and satiation: a simple static model. Environ Dev Econ 7(3):429–448

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lieb CM (2003) The environmental Kuznets curve: a survey of the empirical literature and of possible causes. University of Heidelberg, Department of Economics, Discussion Paper 391

  • Muller N, Mendelsohn R (2009) Efficient pollution regulation: getting the prices right. Am Econ Rev 99(5):1714–1739

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plassmann F, Khanna N (2006) A note on ’the simple analytics of the environmental Kuznets curve’. Environ Dev Econ 11(6):697–707

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Quaas MF (2007) Pollution-reducing infrastructure and urban environmental policy. Environ Dev Econ 12(2):213–234

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rossi-Hansberg EA, Wright ML (2007) Urban structure and growth. Rev Econ Stud 74:597–624

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shah JJ, Nagpal T (Dec 1997) Urban air quality management strategy in Asia—greater Mumbai report. World Bank Technical Paper 381, World Bank, Washington

  • Stern D (2004) The rise and fall of the environmental Kuznets curve. World Dev 32:1419–1439

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Trolley G (1979) Urban growth in a market economy. Academic Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • UN-Habitat (2003) The challenge of slums: global report on human settlements. United Nations Human Settlements Programme, Nairobi

  • UNFPA (2001) Footprints and milestones—population and environmental change. United Nations Population Fund

  • van Marrewijk C (2005) Geographical economics and the role of pollution on location. ICFAI J Environ Econ 3:28–48

    Google Scholar 

  • Verhoef ET, Nijkamp P (2002) Externalities in urban sustainability: environmental versus localization-type agglomeration externalities in a general spatial equilibrium model of a single-sector monocentric industrial city. Ecol Econ 40(2):157–179

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zeng D-Z, Zhao L (2009) Pollution havens and industrial agglomeration. J Environ Econ Manage 58(2):141–153

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Martin F. Quaas.

A Appendix

A Appendix

1.1 A.1 Characterizing the Equilibrium for Given \(n_i\)

The first-order condition for the problem to maximize \(v_i\) with respect to \(E_i\) is

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d v_i}{dE_i}= & {} \left( (1-\mu _i)\,D_i(t)\,n_i^{(1+\psi _i)\mu _i}\,e_i^{\eta _i\,(1-\mu _i)+\mu _i}\,E_i^{-\mu _i}-p(t)\right) \,\frac{1}{n_i e_i}\,\left( 1-E_i\right) ^{\phi }\nonumber \\&-\left( D_i(t)\,n_i^{(1+\psi _i)\mu _i}\,e_i^{\eta _i\, (1-\mu _i)+\mu _i}\,E_i^{-\mu _i}-p(t)\right) \,\frac{\phi \,E_i}{n_i e_i}\,\left( 1-E_i\right) ^{\phi -1}=0.\qquad \end{aligned}$$
(A.1)

Rearranging leads to (9a). Note that (9a) has a unique solution, as the right-hand side is monotonically increasing in \(E_i\) from zero at \(E_i=0\) to infinity as \(E_i\rightarrow 1/(1+\frac{\phi }{1-\mu _i})\).

The first-order condition for the problem to maximize \(v_i\) with respect to \(e_i\) is

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d v_i}{de_i}= & {} \bigg ((1-\eta _i)\,(1-\mu _i)\,D_i(t) \,n_i^{(1+\psi _i)\mu _i}\,e_i^{\eta _i\,(1-\mu _i)+\mu _i} \,E_i^{-\mu _i}-p(t)\bigg )\\&\times \,\frac{-1}{e_i^{2}}\,\frac{E_i}{n_i}\,\left( 1 -E_i\right) ^{\phi }\geqq 0, \end{aligned}$$

with equality for an interior solution and strict inequality for the corner solution \(e_i=e_i^{\max }\) (the lower corner solution \(e_i=0\) is impossible, as then \(c_i=0\)). Using \(E_i>0\), \(E_i<1\), and \(e_i>0\), this condition becomes (9b).

For an interior solution,

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{D_i(t)}{p(t)}\,n_i^{(1+\psi _i)\mu _i}\,e_i^{\mu _i+\eta _i\,(1-\mu _i)}&=\frac{E_i^{\mu _i}}{(1-\eta _i)\,(1-\mu _i)}. \end{aligned}$$
(A.2)

Combining this interior first-order condition for \(e_i\) with the first-order condition for \(E_i\),  (9a), we solve for \(e_i\) and \(E_i\) in the interior equilibrium as:

$$\begin{aligned} E_i =\frac{1}{1 +\frac{\phi }{1-\mu _i}\,\left( \frac{\mu _i+(1-\mu _i)\eta _i}{\eta _i}\right) } \equiv E_i^I \end{aligned}$$
(A.3)

and

$$\begin{aligned} e_i=\left( \frac{D_i(t)}{p(t)} \,n_i^{(1+\psi _i)\mu _i} \frac{(1-\eta _i)\,(1-\mu _i)}{(E_i^I)^{\mu _i}}\right) ^{-\frac{1}{\mu _i +(1-\mu _i)\,\eta _i}}, \end{aligned}$$
(A.4)

which substituted into the utility function implies

$$\begin{aligned} v_i(n_i)= & {} \left( n_i^{ -(\eta _i (1-\mu _i)-\mu _i \psi _i)} {p(t)^{-(1-\eta _i)(1-\mu _i)}} \,{D_i(t)} \right) ^{\frac{1}{\mu _i +(1-\mu _i)\,\eta _i}} \nonumber \\&\times (\xi _i-1)^{\xi _i - 1} \xi _i^{-\xi _i} (E_i^I)^{1-\mu _i \xi _i} (1-E_i^I)^\phi , \end{aligned}$$
(A.5)

where \(\xi _i \equiv 1/(\mu _i+(1-\mu _i)\eta _i)\). Equation (A.5) is equation (10b). Equation (A.4) gives \(e_i\) as a decreasing function of \(n_i\), so that the interior solution can apply only if the expression is below \(e_i^{\max }\). Hence, we find:

$$\begin{aligned} e_i = e_i^{\max } \Leftrightarrow n_i \le \left( \frac{p(t) }{D_i(t)} \frac{ \left[ E_i^I \right] ^{\mu _i} }{(e_i^{\max })^{\mu _i+(1-\mu _i)\,\eta _i}\,\left( 1- \mu _i)(1-\eta _i \right) }\right) ^{\frac{1}{(1+\psi _i)\mu _i}} \equiv n_i^I \end{aligned}$$
(A.6)

For a corner solution, the equilibrium level of \(E_i\) is given as the solution of (9a) with \(e_i=e_i^{\max }\). A similar argument as in Appendix A.2 shows that the optimal pollution level is increasing with \(e_i^{\max }\).

1.2 A.2 Proof that Efficient Pollution Level is Non-decreasing with Population

If the optimal emission intensity is in the interior, \({\hat{e}}_i<e_i^{\max }\), the efficient level of pollution is independent of \(n_i\) (cf. Appendix A.3). For the corner solution \({\hat{e}}_i=e_i^{\max }\), we take the total differential of equation (9a). This yields

$$\begin{aligned}&(D/p)\,(e_i^{\max })^{\eta _i\,(1-\mu _i)+\mu _i}\,(1+\psi _i)\, \mu _i\, n_i^{(1+\psi _i)\,\mu _i-1}\,dn_i\nonumber \\&\quad =\left( \frac{\mu _i\,{\hat{E}}_i^{\mu _i-1}}{(1-\mu _i)}\, \frac{1-(1+\phi )\,{\hat{E}}_i}{1-(1+\frac{\phi }{1-\mu _i})\,{\hat{E}}_i} +\frac{{\hat{E}}_i^{\mu _i}}{(1-\mu _i)}\,\frac{\phi \, \frac{\mu _i}{1-\mu _i}}{\left( 1-(1+\frac{\phi }{1-\mu _i}) \,{\hat{E}}_i\right) ^2} \right) \,dE_i\qquad \end{aligned}$$
(A.7)

For \({\hat{E}}_i<1/(1+\phi /(1-\mu _i))\), both the term in front of \(dn_i\) on the left hand side and the term in front of \(dE_i\) on the right hand side are strictly positive so that \(dE_i/dn_i>0\). For \(E_i=0\), we have \(n_i=0\); for \(E_i\rightarrow 1/(1+\phi /(1-\mu _i))\), we have \(n_i\rightarrow \infty \) from condition (9a). Hence in the corner solution, \(dE_i/dn_i>0\) for all positive values of \(n_i\) and a fortiori for the relevant range \(n_i \in (0,n_i^I)\). A similar argument leads to the conclusion that \({\hat{E}}_i\) increases if \(D_i(t)/p(t)\) increases, while \(n_i\) remains constant.

1.3 A.3 Proof of Result 1

By the envelope theorem, the total derivative of utility with respect to population equals the partial derivative of utility with respect to population. Hence,

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dv_i(n_i)}{dn_i}= & {} \frac{\partial v_i(n_i)}{\partial n_i} = -\frac{1}{n_i^2}\,\left( D_i(t)\,n_i^{(1+\psi _i)\mu _i} \,e_i^{\eta _i\,(1-\mu _i)+\mu _i}\,E_i^{-\mu _i}-p(t)\right) \,\frac{E_i}{e_i}\left( 1-E_i\right) ^\phi \nonumber \\&+\frac{1}{n_i^2}\,\mu _i\,(1+\psi _i)\, D_i(t)\,n_i^{(1+\psi _i) \mu _i}\,e_i^{\eta _i\,(1-\mu _i)+\mu _i}\,\frac{E_i^{1-\mu _i}}{e_i} \,\left( 1-E_i\right) ^\phi \nonumber \\= & {} -\frac{1}{n_i^2}\,\left( (1-\mu _i\,(1+\psi _i))\,D_i(t) \,n_i^{(1+\psi _i)\mu _i}\,e_i^{\eta _i\,(1-\mu _i)+\mu _i} \,E_i^{-\mu _i}-p(t)\right) \,\frac{E_i}{e_i}\nonumber \\&\times \left( 1-E_i\right) ^\phi \nonumber \\= & {} \frac{1}{n_i}\left[ -1+\frac{\mu _i\,(1+\psi )\,D_i(t) \,n_i^{(1+\psi _i)\mu _i}\,e_i^{\eta _i\,(1-\mu _i)+\mu _i} \,E_i^{-\mu _i}}{D_i(t)\,n_i^{(1+\psi _i)\mu _i}\,e_i^{\eta _i \,(1-\mu _i)+\mu _i}\,E_i^{-\mu _{i}}-p(t)}\right] \,v_i(n_i) \end{aligned}$$
(A.8)

Thus, utility has an interior maximum, if \(1-\mu _i\,(1+\psi _i)=1-\mu _i+\frac{1-\mu _i}{\sigma _i-1}=\frac{1-\mu _i}{\sigma _i-1}\,\left( \sigma _i-2\right) >0\), which is true by the above assumption \(\sigma _i>2\). Otherwise, utility would be monotonically increasing with \(n_i\) due to very strongly increasing returns to scale. The condition for an interior extremum is

$$\begin{aligned} (1-(1+\psi _i)\mu _i)\,\frac{D_i(t)}{p(t)}\,n_i^{(1+\psi _i) \mu _i}\,e_i^{\eta _i\,(1-\mu _i)+\mu _i} =E_i^{\mu _i} \end{aligned}$$
(A.9)

Note that an interior maximum must be at a population size where optimal emission intensity is at the corner \({\hat{e}}_i=e_i^{\max }\), as utility is montonically decreasing with \(n_i\) for an interior solution of emission intensity as becomes clear from equation (10b) under our assumption \(1<(\sigma -1)\eta \Leftrightarrow \mu \psi < (1-\mu )\eta \). Combining (9a) and (A.9), we find that the pollution level at the interior extremum of utility satisfies

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{1-\mu _i\,(1+\psi _i)}{1-\mu _i}\,\frac{1-(1+\phi ) \,E_i}{1-(1+\frac{\phi }{1-\mu _i})\,E_i}=1, \end{aligned}$$
(A.10)

which can be rearranged to obtain

$$\begin{aligned} E_i=\frac{\psi _i}{\phi +\psi _i+\phi \,\psi _i} \equiv E_i^{FB}. \end{aligned}$$
(A.11)

Plugging into (A.9), we obtain the result (11).

To show that (11) is a maximum of utility, we show that the elasticity of utility with respect to \(n_i\) is monotonically declining from a positive to a negative value when \(n_i\) increases from zero to infinity, so that utility has a single peak at \(n_i=n_i^{\text {opt}}\). First we rewrite (A.8) as an elasticity condition

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dv_i (n_i)}{dn_i} \frac{n_i}{v_i}= \frac{f_i^* - f_i}{f_i^*(f_i-1)} \end{aligned}$$
(A.12)

with

$$\begin{aligned} f_i \equiv (D_i/p)n_i^{(1+\psi _i)\mu _i}(e_i)^{\mu _i+(1-\mu _i)\eta _i} E_i^{-\mu _i} \end{aligned}$$
(A.13)

and

$$\begin{aligned} f_i^* \equiv (1-(1+\psi _i)\mu _i)^{-1} \end{aligned}$$
(A.14)

Thus, the elasticity declines monotonically with \(f_i\). From (9a) we know that \(f_i\) is non-decreasing in \(E_i\) and from Appendix A.2 we know that \(E_i\) is non-decreasing in \(n_i\). Hence, the elasticity of utility with respect to \(n_i\) is non-increasing in \(n_i\). Equation (9a) shows that the lower bound for \(f_i\) is \(1/(1-\mu _i)\), which substituted in (A.12) gives that \(\psi _i>0\) is the upper bound of the elasticity of utility with respect to \(n_i\). Equation (9b) shows that for \(n_i\) critically large, an interior solution implies, so that \(f_i=1/(1-\eta _i)(1-\mu _i)\) and the elasticity of utility with respect to \(n_i\) becomes the constant \(-[(1-\mu _i)\eta _i - \psi _i \mu _i]/[\mu _i+(1-\mu _i)\eta _i]<0\), consistent with both (A.12) and (10b). Hence the elasticity is negative for all \(n_i>n_i^{\text {opt}}\) so that \(\lim \limits _{n_i\rightarrow \infty }v_i(n_i)=0\).

To determine utility for \(n_i=0\), we use the lower bounds (\(f_i=1/(1-\mu _i)\), \(E_i=0\), \(e_i=e_i^{\max }\), \(n_i=0\)) into (10a) to find

$$\begin{aligned} \lim \limits _{n_i\rightarrow 0}v_i(n_i) = \lim \limits _{n_i\rightarrow 0}\frac{p}{e_i^{\max }} \frac{\mu _i}{1-\mu _i} \frac{E_i}{n_i}, \end{aligned}$$
(A.15)

and use \(f_i=1/(1-\mu _i)\) into (A.13) to find

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{E_i}{n_i}=\left( (1-\mu _i) \frac{D_i}{p} (e_i^{\max })^{\mu _i+(1-\mu _i)\eta _i} \right) ^{1/\mu _i}n_i^{\psi _i}. \end{aligned}$$
(A.16)

Combining the two displayed results we find \(\lim \limits _{n_i\rightarrow 0}v_i(n_i)=0\). We state this finding in Result 1.

Similarly we find \(\lim \limits _{n_i\rightarrow 0}v'_i(n_i) \propto \psi _i (E_i/n_i^2)\propto n_i^{\psi _i-1}\). This result implies that a sufficient condition for stability of the Malthusian urbanization pattern is \(\psi _i<1\), so that \(v'_i(0)\) is infinitely large and small new cities attract workers from large old cities.

1.4 A.4 Considering the Urban Spatial Structure

We consider the following extension where urban spatial structure is described by an Alonso-Muth-Mills monocentric city model (e.g. Fujita 1989), closely following Behrens et al. (2014, Appendix F). Production does not need space and is concentrated in the central business district (CBD) in the city center. Each worker commutes from his place of residence in a distance z from the CBD, causing transport costs \(T(z)=\tau (t)\,\frac{1+\gamma }{\gamma }\,2^\gamma \,z^\gamma \), with \(\tau (t),\gamma >0\), and \(\gamma \le (1+\psi _i)\,\mu _i-1\). We allow the transport cost parameter \(\tau (t)\) to change over time, capturing potential improvements in commuting technology. We consider a linear city with residences of unit length, such that the total extension of a city with \(n_i\) inhabitants is \(z^*=n_i/2\) to both sides of the CBD. In residential equilibrium, all households have the same income net of land rent r(z) and commuting costs T(z), i.e. \(r(z)+T(z)\) is a constant. Normalizing opportunity costs of land to zero, \(r(z^*)=0\), and thus \(r(z)=T(z^*)-T(z)\). All differential rent is taxed and redistributed in a lumb-sum fashion to current urban citizens. Aggregate differential land rent is

$$\begin{aligned} A(n_i)=2\,\int _0^{z^*} r(z)\,dz=\tau (t)\,\frac{1+\gamma }{\gamma }\,2^{1+\gamma }\,\int _0^{z^*} \left( (z^*)^\gamma -z^\gamma \right) \,dz=\tau (t)\,n_i^{1+\gamma } \end{aligned}$$
(A.17)

Disposable income of an individual living at a distance z from the CBD thus is increased by a share \(n_i\) in \(A(n_i)\) and decreased by \(r(z)+T(z)=T(z^*)\). Equation (8) is thus replaced by

$$\begin{aligned} c_i(t)=\;&\frac{1}{n_i}\,\left( D_i(t)\,n_i^{(1+\psi _i) \,\mu _i}\,e_i^{\eta _i\,(1-\mu _i)+\mu _i}\,\frac{E_i^{1 -\mu _i}}{e_i}-p(t)\,\frac{E_i}{e_i}-{\hat{T}}_i(n_i)\right) , \end{aligned}$$
(A.18)

where

$$\begin{aligned} {\hat{T}}_i(n_i)=A(n_i)-n_i\,T(z^*)=\tau (t) \,n_i^{1+\gamma }-n_i\,\tau (t)\,\frac{1+\gamma }{\gamma } \,2^\gamma \,\left( \frac{n_i}{2}\right) ^\gamma =\frac{\tau (t)}{\gamma } \,n_i^{1+\gamma } \end{aligned}$$
(A.19)

Within the model, the following variant of Result 1 holds:

Result 7

When pollution is at a locally optimal level, utility has a unique interior maximum at a population size determined as the solution of

$$\begin{aligned} (1-\mu _i\,(1+\psi _i))\,D_i(t)\,n_i^{(1+\psi _i)\,\mu _i} \,e_i^{\eta _i\,(1-\mu _i)+\mu _i}\,\frac{{\hat{E}}_i^{1-\mu _i}}{e_i}-p(t) \,\frac{{\hat{E}}_i}{e_i}-\tau (t)\,n_i^{1+\gamma }=0\qquad \quad \end{aligned}$$
(A.20)

Furthermore, utility \(v_i(n_i)\) tends to zero for \(n_i\rightarrow 0\) and \(n_i\rightarrow \infty \).

The optimal population size decreases with the level of economic development \(D_i(t)\), and increases with the relative import price, p(t).

Proof

The proof is structured as follws. We first characterize optimal pollution and its comparative statics. Then we derive the optimal population size and show that it is a maximum. Finally we derive the comparative static results of \(n_i^{opt}\).

Optimal pollution is determined by the condition

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dv_i}{dE_i}= & {} \left( (1-\mu _i)\,D_i(t)\,n_i^{(1+\psi _i)\,\mu _i} \,e_i^{\eta _i\,(1-\mu _i)+\mu _i}\,E_i^{-\mu _i}-p(t)\right) \,\frac{1}{e_i} \,\left( 1-E_i\right) ^{\phi }\\&-\left( D_i(t)\,n_i^{(1+\psi _i)\,\mu _i}\,e_i^{\eta _i\,(1-\mu _i) +\mu _i}\,\frac{E_i^{1-\mu _i}}{e_i}-p(t)\,\frac{E_i}{e_i} -{\hat{T}}_i(n_i)\right) \,\phi \,\left( 1-E_i\right) ^{\phi -1}=0. \end{aligned}$$

Rearranging leads to

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{D_i(t)}{p(t)}\,n_i^{(1+\psi _i)\,\mu _i}\,e_i^{\eta _i \,(1-\mu _i)+\mu _i}=\frac{{\hat{E}}_i^{\mu _i}}{1-\mu _i}\,\frac{1 -(1+\phi )\,{\hat{E}}_i-\frac{e_i}{p(t)}\,\phi \,{\hat{T}}_i(n_i)}{1 -\left( 1+\frac{\phi }{1-\mu _i}\right) \,{\hat{E}}_i}. \end{aligned}$$
(A.21)

The derivative of the last term on the right-hand side of this condition with respect to \({\hat{E}}_i\) is

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d}{d{\hat{E}}_i} \frac{1-(1+\phi )\,{\hat{E}}_i -\frac{e_i}{p(t)}\,\phi \,{\hat{T}}_i(n_i)}{1-\left( 1+\frac{\phi }{1 -\mu _i}\right) \,{\hat{E}}_i}=\frac{\frac{\mu }{1-\mu }\,\phi -\left( 1+\frac{\phi }{1-\mu _i}\right) \,\frac{e_i}{p(t)} \,\phi \,{\hat{T}}_i(n_i)}{\left( 1-\left( 1+\frac{\phi }{1-\mu _i}\right) \,{\hat{E}}_i\right) ^2} \end{aligned}$$
(A.22)

A positive level of consumption requires (cf. Eq. A.18)

$$\begin{aligned} e_i\,{\hat{T}}_i(n_i)&<p(t)\,{\hat{E}}_i\,\left( \frac{D_i(t)}{p(t)} \,n_i^{(1+\psi _i)\,\mu _i}\,e_i^{\eta _i\,(1-\mu _i)+\mu _i} \,{\hat{E}}_i^{-\mu _i}-1\right) \nonumber \\&\mathop {=}\limits ^{(A.21)}{\hat{E}}_i \,\left( \frac{1}{1-\mu _i}\,\frac{1-(1+\phi )\,{\hat{E}}_i-\frac{e_i}{p(t)} \,\phi \,{\hat{T}}_i(n_i)}{1-\left( 1+\frac{\phi }{1-\mu _i}\right) \,{\hat{E}}_i}-1\right) \nonumber \\&\Leftrightarrow \frac{e_i}{p(t)}\,\phi \,{\hat{T}}_i(n_i) <\frac{\mu _i}{1-\mu _i}\,\phi \,{\hat{E}}_i. \end{aligned}$$
(A.23)

Using this result in (A.22), we find that the right hand side (RHS) of (A.21) is increasing with \({\hat{E}}_i\), as

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\mu }{1-\mu }\,\phi -\left( 1+\frac{\phi }{1-\mu _i}\right) \,\frac{e_i}{p(t)}\,\phi \,{\hat{T}}_i(n_i)\nonumber \\&\quad>\frac{\mu }{1-\mu }\,\phi \,\left( 1-\left( 1+\frac{\phi }{1-\mu _i}\right) \,{\hat{E}}_i\right) >0. \end{aligned}$$
(A.24)

Thus, we have the following comparative static results: \(\partial {\hat{E}}_i/\partial n_i>0\)—the partial of the left-hand side (LHS) of (A.21) with respect to \(n_i\) is positive, while the partial of the RHS with respect to \(n_i\) is negative; \(\partial {\hat{E}}_i/\partial D_i>0\)—the partial of the LHS with respect to \(D_i\) is positive; \(\partial {\hat{E}}_i/\partial p(t)<0\)—the partial of the LHS with respect to p(t) is negative, while the partial of the RHS with respect to p(t) is positive; and \(\partial {\hat{E}}_i/\partial \tau (t)>0\)—the partial of the RHS with respect to \(\tau (t)\) is negative.

The properties of \(v_i(n_i)\) at the corners \(n_i=0\) and \(n_i=\infty \) follow according to exactly the same logic as for Result 1.

By the envelope theorem, the total derivative of utility with respect to population equals the partial derivative of utility with respect to population. Hence,

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dv_i(n_i)}{dn_i}= & {} \frac{\partial v_i(n_i)}{\partial n_i}\\= & {} -\frac{1}{n_i^2}\,\left( D_i(t)\,n_i^{(1+\psi _i)\,\mu _i} \,e_i^{\eta _i\,(1-\mu _i)+\mu _i}\,\frac{{\hat{E}}_i^{1-\mu _i}}{e_i}-p(t) \,\frac{{\hat{E}}_i}{e_i}-{\hat{T}}_i(n_i)\right) \,\left( 1-{\hat{E}}_i\right) ^\phi \nonumber \\&+\frac{1}{n_i^2}\,\left( \mu _i\,(1+\psi _i)\,D_i(t)\,n_i^{(1+\psi _i) \,\mu _i}\,e_i^{\eta _i\,(1-\mu _i)+\mu _i}\,\frac{{\hat{E}}_i^{1-\mu _i}}{e_i} -n_i\,{\hat{T}}_i'(n_i)\right) \nonumber \\&\times \left( 1-{\hat{E}}_i\right) ^\phi \nonumber \\= & {} -\frac{\left( 1-{\hat{E}}_i\right) ^\phi }{n_i^2}\, \bigg ((1-\mu _i\,(1+\psi _i))\,D_i(t)\,n_i^{(1+\psi _i)\,\mu _i} \,e_i^{\eta _i\,(1-\mu _i)+\mu _i}\,\frac{{\hat{E}}_i^{1-\mu _i}}{e_i}\nonumber \\&-p(t)\,\frac{{\hat{E}}_i}{e_i}-{\hat{T}}_i(n_i)+n_ i\,{\hat{T}}_i'(n_i)\bigg ) \end{aligned}$$

Using \(-{\hat{T}}_i(n_i)+n_i\,{\hat{T}}_i'(n_i)=\tau (t)\,n_i^{1+\gamma }\) from (A.19) and defining

$$\begin{aligned} \Psi (n_i)=(1-\mu _i\,(1+\psi _i))\,D_i(t)\,n_i^{(1+\psi _i) \,\mu _i}\,e_i^{\eta _i\,(1-\mu _i)+\mu _i}\,\frac{{\hat{E}}_i^{1 -\mu _i}}{e_i}-p(t)\,\frac{{\hat{E}}_i}{e_i}-\tau (t)\,n_i^{1+\gamma }, \end{aligned}$$
(A.25)

and with \(n_i^{opt}\) to denote the optimal population size, the first-order condition for the optimal population size is \(\Psi (n_i^{opt})=0\), as stated in (A.20). This is a maximum of utility, as second derivative is negative:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d^2v_i(n_i^{opt})}{dn_i^2}=-\frac{\left( 1-{\hat{E}}_i \right) ^\phi }{n_i^2}\,\Psi '(n_i^{opt})&<0. \end{aligned}$$
(A.26)

\(\Psi '(n_i^{opt})>0\) is true, because in the derivative of \(\Psi (n_i)\) with respect to \(n_i\), evaluated at \(n_i^{opt}\),

$$\begin{aligned} \Psi '(n_i^{opt})&=(1+\psi _i)\,\mu _i\, (1-\mu _i\,(1+\psi _i))\,D_i(t) \,n_i^{(1+\psi _i)\,\mu _i-1}\,e_i^{\eta _i\,(1-\mu _i)+\mu _i} \,\frac{{\hat{E}}_i^{1-\mu _i}}{e_i}\nonumber \\&\quad -(1+\gamma )\,\tau (t)\,n_i^{\gamma }\nonumber \\&\quad +\,\left( (1-\mu _i)\,(1-\mu _i\,(1+\psi _i))\,D_i(t)\,n_i^{(1+\psi _i) \,\mu _i}\,e_i^{\eta _i\,(1-\mu _i)+\mu _i}\,\frac{{\hat{E}}_i^{-\mu _i}}{e_i} -\frac{p(t)}{e_i}\right) \,\frac{\partial {\hat{E}}_i}{\partial n_i}, \end{aligned}$$
(A.27)

The expression in the second line is larger or equal to \((1+\psi _i)\,\mu _i\,p(t)\,\frac{{\hat{E}}_i}{e_i\,n_i^{opt}}>0\) (using the above assumption \((1+\psi _i)\,\mu _i\ge 1+\gamma \)), and the expression in brackets in the last line is positive, as follows from the first-order condition for the optimal level of \({\hat{E}}_i\), and \(\partial {\hat{E}}_i/\partial n_i>0\).

The comparative statics of \(n_i^{opt}\) with respect to \(D_i(t)\) is found by differentiating (A.20) with respect to \(D_i(t)\)

$$\begin{aligned}&\left( (1-\mu _i\,(1+\psi _i))\,(1-\mu _i)\,D_i(t)\,n_i^{(1+\psi _i) \,\mu _i}\,e_i^{\eta _i\,(1-\mu _i)}\,\left( \frac{{\hat{E}}_i}{e_i}\right) ^{-\mu _i} -p(t)\right) \,\frac{1}{e_i}\,\frac{\partial {\hat{E}}_i}{\partial D_i(t)}\nonumber \\&\quad +\,(1-\mu _i\,(1+\psi _i))\,n_i^{(1+\psi _i)\,\mu _i}\,e_i^{\eta _i \,(1-\mu _i)+\mu _i}\,\frac{{\hat{E}}_i^{1-\mu _i}}{e_i} +\Psi '(n_i^{opt})\,\frac{dn_i^{opt}}{d D_i(t)}=0 \end{aligned}$$
(A.28)

The expression in brackets in the first term is negative: Using (A.23) and (A.25), we have

$$\begin{aligned}&(1-\mu _i\,(1+\psi _i))\,(1-\mu _i)\,D_i(t)\,n_i^{(1+\psi _i)\,\mu _i} \,e_i^{\eta _i\,(1-\mu _i)+\mu _i}\,\frac{{\hat{E}}_i^{-\mu _i}}{e_i}-p(t)\\&\quad =(1-\mu _i)\,\left( p(t)+\frac{e_i\,\tau (t)\,n_i^{1+\gamma }}{{\hat{E}}_i}\right) -p(t)\\&\quad <(1-\mu _i)\,\left( p(t)+\frac{\frac{\mu _i}{1-\mu _i}\,p(t)\,{\hat{E}}_i}{{\hat{E}}_i}\right) -p(t)=0 \end{aligned}$$

We thus can use the following to get the sign of \(\partial n_i^{opt}/\partial D_i(t)\),

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial {\hat{E}}_i}{\partial D_i(t)}&=\frac{1}{D_i(t)}\,\frac{\frac{D_i(t)}{p(t)}\,n_i^{(1+\psi _i) \,\mu _i}\,e_i^{\eta _i\,(1-\mu _i)+\mu _i}}{\frac{\partial }{\partial {\hat{E}}_i}\left( \frac{{\hat{E}}_i^{\mu _i}}{1-\mu _i}\,\frac{1-(1+\phi ) \,{\hat{E}}_i-\frac{e_i}{p(t)}\,\phi \,{\hat{T}}_i(n_i)}{1-\left( 1+\frac{\phi }{1-\mu _i}\right) \,{\hat{E}}_i}\right) } <\frac{{\hat{E}}_i}{\mu _i\,D_i(t)} \end{aligned}$$
(A.29)

Thus the first two terms in (A.28) are positive, as

$$\begin{aligned}&\left( (1-\mu _i\,(1+\psi _i))\,(1-\mu _i)\,D_i(t)\,n_i^{(1+\psi _i)\,\mu _i} \,e_i^{\eta _i\,(1-\mu _i)}\,\left( \frac{{\hat{E}}_i}{e_i} \right) ^{-\mu _i}-p(t)\right) \,\frac{1}{e_i}\,\frac{\partial {\hat{E}}_i}{\partial D_i(t)}\nonumber \\&\qquad +\,(1-\mu _i\,(1+\psi _i))\,n_i^{(1+\psi _i)\,\mu _i}\,e_i^{\eta _i \,(1-\mu _i)+\mu _i}\,\frac{{\hat{E}}_i^{1-\mu _i}}{e_i}\nonumber \\&\quad =\left( (1-\mu _i)\,\frac{e_i\,\tau (t)\,n_i^{1+\gamma }}{{\hat{E}}_i} -\mu _i\,p(t)\right) \,\frac{1}{e_i}\,\frac{\partial {\hat{E}}_i}{\partial D_i(t)}+\frac{p(t)\,{\hat{E}}_i}{e_i\,D_i(t)} +\frac{\tau (t)\,n_i^{1+\gamma }}{D_i(t)}\nonumber \\&\quad>\left( (1-\mu _i)\,\frac{e_i\,\tau (t)\,n_i^{1+\gamma }}{{\hat{E}}_i} -\mu _i\,p(t)\right) \,\frac{{\hat{E}}_i}{e_i\,\mu _i\,D_i(t)} +\frac{p(t)\,{\hat{E}}_i}{e_i\,D_i(t)}+\frac{\tau (t) \,n_i^{1+\gamma }}{D_i(t)}\nonumber \\&\quad =\frac{\tau (t)\,n_i^{1+\gamma }}{\mu _i\,D_i(t)}>0 \end{aligned}$$
(A.30)

This implies that the optimal population size is decreasing with \(D_i(t)\), as \(\Psi '(n_i^{opt})>0\). In a similar fashion it can be shown that the optimal population size is increasing in p(t). \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Quaas, M.F., Smulders, S. Brown Growth, Green Growth, and the Efficiency of Urbanization. Environ Resource Econ 71, 529–549 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-017-0172-1

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-017-0172-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation