Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The effects of globalization and technology on the elasticity of substitution

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Review of World Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The elasticity of substitution between capital and labor (\(\sigma\)) is usually considered a “deep parameter”. This paper shows, in contrast, that \(\sigma\) is affected by both globalization and technology, and that different intensities in these drivers have different consequences for the OECD and the non-OECD economies. In the OECD, we find that the elasticity of substitution between capital and labor is below unity; that it increases along with the degree of globalization; but it decreases with the level of technology. Although results for the non-OECD area are more heterogeneous, we find that technology enhances the substitutability between capital and labor. We also find evidence of a non-significant impact of the capital-output ratio on the labor share irrespective of the degree of globalization (which would be consistent with an average aggregate Cobb–Douglas technology). Given the relevance of \(\sigma\) for economic growth and the functional distribution of income, the intertwined linkage among globalization, technology and the elasticity of substitution should be taken into account in any policy makers’ objective function.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. This type of production functions has also been used, among others, by Sato and Hoffman (1968) and Jones and Manuelli (1990). In addition to the VES production functions, Antony (2010) mentions the possibility of using flexible functional forms, such as translog or quadratic production functions. These flexible forms, however, share the problem of having a large number of parameters to be estimated or calibrated.

  2. Independent in spite that trade and associated activities, such as foreign direct investment (FDI), are among the main sources of technological transfer (Coe and Helpman 1995; Falvey et al. 2004), and it can also spur innovation by increasing the extent of the market (Sachs 2000).

  3. A detailed derivation of Eq. (2) from (1) can be found in Bentolila and Saint-Paul (2003), pp. 6–7, and Young and Lawson (2014), p. 23. For the sake of intuition, we follow the latter and define \(\sigma\) as a positive parameter.

  4. This is known as the “capital-skill complementarity hypothesis”. Formal and empirical evidence can be found in Griliches (1969), Goldin and Katz (1996) and Caselli and Coleman (2001).

  5. These production functions are based on the idea from de La Grandville (1989) of normalizing CES production functions.

  6. A dual elasticity of substitution is chosen in this section for the sake of simplicity. The important fact is that changes in the capital-labor ratio can affect the value of \(\sigma\). Antony’s-type production functions do not have any structural model behind and do not provide clear indications about how increases in the capital-labor ratio affect \(\sigma\). Our paper, therefore, has to be seen essentially as an empirical exercise on the determinants of \(\sigma\) leaving the specific policy implications for further research.

  7. For a detailed overview on System GMM, and its advantages over standard panel data techniques and Difference GMM, see Bond et al. (2001) and Roodman (2009).

  8. Accordingly, both samples are estimated allowing for just four lags of endogenous variables and using the “collapse” instruments option available in the xtabond2 Stata command developed by David Roodman. Table A4 and Figures A8 and A9 in the “Online Appendix” present the results when 3 and 5 lags are used.

  9. Tables A2 and A3 in the “Online Appendix” show the main descriptive statistics by group of countries. Given data availability, our analysis considers 24 OECD countries (621 observations) and 27 non-OECD countries (650 observations).

  10. To complement this information, Figure A1 in the “Online Appendix” shows the evolution of the labor income share, the capital-output ratio and the KOF index taking as initial value the weighted average at 1970. TFP is not included in this figure, as its variation is within country (the index is equal to 1 for all the countries in 2005), thus making different values between groups uninformative.

  11. To complement this general information, Figures A2–A4 in the “Online Appendix” present country specific correlation coefficients of the capital-output ratio, the KOF index of globalization, and TFP with respect to the labor income share (to provide the most global picture, these figures contain information for a wider sample than the one that we could actually use in the analysis due to data limitations). Clear pictures emerge in the first two cases, with worldwide positive and negative correlations across all economies. On the contrary, there is a much disperse result regarding TFP, with a negative correlation in most OECD countries, and a not so clear negative relationship in the non-OECD countries.

  12. As a goodness check, note that the persistence coefficients obtained by the BB estimator lie between the ones estimated by POLS and 2FE (see Bond 2002). They are the largest ones under the POLS estimation (0.84 in the OECD and 0.96 in the non-OECD areas, respectively), the lowest ones under the 2FE estimation (0.66 and 0.79), and take a middle position when estimated by System GMM (0.72 and 0.82). We credit the latter and conclude that the labor share in the non-OECD area is more persistent than in the OECD countries.

  13. The extent to which the process of globalization affects a particular country is certainly shaped by the trade policies and the institutional framework in which these policies are developed (which affect the costs and profits of economic activities). However, country-specific trade policies and the design of institutions are not forward looking but rather reactive to global and domestic changes. It is from this perspective that we consider globalization as an exogenous driver of the influence exerted by the capital-output ratio on the labor share. This interpretation is reinforced by the results presented in columns [2] and [6] in Table A4, and Figure A7 in the “Online Appendix”, which are robust when globalization is considered endogenous.

  14. Figure A5 in the “Online Appendix” shows the Kernel density functions of the KOF and TFP indices in the OECD and non-OECD countries, with the shaded areas indicating the selected values. For the OECD economies, they range from 40 to 100% for the KOF index, and from \(-0.35\) to 0.18 for the TFP; for the non-OECD economies, they go from 22 to 68% for the KOF index, and range between \(-0.34\) and 0.38 for the TFP. Note that the wider interval in the non-OECD group implies a larger volatility of the TFP, and does not reflect at all a better technological level.

  15. It is worth outlining the differences of significance between Table 2 and Fig. 2. While we find a significant impact of the marginal effects in Fig. 2, most of the coefficients in Table 2 are insignificant. For a benchmark model like \(Y=\beta _0+\beta _1X+\beta _2Z+\beta _3XZ+\epsilon\), Brambor et al. (2006) explain this result as follows: “even more important to remember is that the analyst is not directly interested in the significance or insignificance of the model parameters per se anyway. Instead, the analyst who employs a multiplicative interaction model is typically interested in the marginal effect of X on Y. In the case of [our model], this is \(\frac{\partial Y}{\partial X}=\beta _1+\beta _3Z\). As a result, the analyst really wants to know the standard error of this quantity and not the standard error of \(\beta _0\), \(\beta _1\), \(\beta _2\), or \(\beta _3\). The standard error of interest is:

    $$\begin{aligned} \hat{\sigma }_{\frac{\partial Y}{\partial X}}=\sqrt{\mathrm {var}(\hat{\beta _1})+Z^2\mathrm {var}(\hat{\beta _3})+2Z\mathrm {cov}(\hat{\beta _1}\hat{\beta _3}) } \end{aligned}$$

    If the covariance term is negative, as is often the case, then it is entirely possible for \(\beta _1+\beta _3Z\) to be significant for substantively relevant values of Z even if all of the model parameters are insignificant.” (Brambor et al. 2006, p. 70.)

  16. Given that Antony’s production functions lack an explicit transmission mechanism, it is worth noting that additional factors could also play a role on this relationship. Disentangling such factors is left for further research.

  17. In the event of slow capital stock changes and a counter-cyclical behavior of the labor share, yearly data analysis could reflect a spurious positive correlation between the capital-output ratio and the labor income share. To exclude this possibility, Figure A6 in the “Online Appendix” shows the marginal effects for a 3 years average static model estimated by System GMM. It can be observed that our results are robust both for the OECD and the non-OECD countries and, thus, we can safely rule out the possibility of a spurious positive correlation.

  18. Income and region classifications follows the World Bank system. Regarding income levels, we have created three groups in the following way: (i) high income \(=\) High Income OECD \(+\) High Income non-OECD, (ii) Middle Income \(=\) Upper Middle Income, and (iii) Low Income \(=\) Low Income \(+\) Lower Middle Income.

  19. We are aware that some authors have warned against the study of country-specific coefficients in an isolated way (Pedroni 2007; Eberhardt and Teal 2013). For this reason, we will not focus on the specific information obtained for a given country, but on the existence of potential patterns across countries for different average globalization levels. In any case, let us note that our results are robust to the estimation method and no significant differences appear when we use the Chudik and Pesaran (2015) Dynamic CMG estimator (CMG1 and CMG2). We use the CMG estimates because of the larger number of countries included in this estimation.

  20. The graphical analysis in this section is based on Eberhardt and Presbitero (2015). The replication files can be accessed at Markus Eberhardt’s personal website: https://sites.google.com/site/medevecon/publications-and-working-papers (by clicking “Replication data and do-files” below Eberhardt and Presbitero 2015).

  21. Although we have tried to use alternative proxies for technological change, we have not found an alternative that covers enough sample to undertake a reliable robustness check.

References

  • Abel, A. B., & Blanchard, O. J. (1983). An intertemporal model of saving and investment. Econometrica, 51(3), 675–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D. (2003). Labor and capital-augmenting technical change. Journal of the European Economic Association, 1(1), 1–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., & Guerrieri, V. (2008). Capital deepening and nonbalanced economic growth. Journal of Political Economy, 116(3), 467–498.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antony, J. (2009a). Capital/labor substitution, capital deepening, and FDI. Journal of Macroeconomics, 31(4), 699–707.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antony, J. (2009b). A dual elasticity of substitution production function with an application to cross-country inequality. Economics Letters, 102(1), 10–12.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antony, J. (2010). A class of changing elasticity of substitution production functions. Journal of Economics, 100(2), 165–183.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antràs, P. (2004). Is the US aggregate production function Cobb–Douglas? New estimates of the elasticity of substitution. Contributions to Macroeconomics, 4(1), 1–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Review of Economic Studies, 58(2), 277–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arpaia, A., Pérez, E., & Pichelmann, K. (2009). Understanding labour income share dynamics in europe. MPRA Paper 15649, University Library of Munich, Germany.

  • Barro, R., & Sala-i Martin, X. (2004). Economic Growth. McGraw-Hill Advanced Series in Economics. McGraw-Hill.

  • Bentolila, S., & Saint-Paul, G. (2003). Explaining movements in the labor share. The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics, 3(1), 1–33.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blundell, R., & Bond, S. (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. Journal of Econometrics, 87(1), 115–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bond, B., Hoeffler, A., & Temple, J. (2001). GMM estimation of empirical growth models. Economics Papers 2001-W21, Economics Group, Nuffield College, University of Oxford.

  • Bond, S. (2002). Dynamic panel data models: A guide to micro data methods and practice. Portuguese Economic Journal, 1(2), 141–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brambor, T., Clark, W. R., & Golder, M. (2006). Understanding interaction models: Improving empirical analyses. Political Analysis, 14, 63–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caselli, F., & Coleman, W. J. (2001). Cross-country technology diffusion: The case of computers. American Economic Review, 91(2), 328–335.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chirinko, R. S. (2008). \(\sigma\): The long and short of it. Journal of Macroeconomics, 30(2), 671–686. The CES Production Function in the Theory and Empirics of Economic Growth.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chirinko, R. S., & Mallick, D. (2014). The substitution elasticity, factor shares, long-run growth, and the low-frequency panel model. CESifo Working Paper Series 4895, CESifo Group Munich.

  • Chudik, A., & Pesaran, M. H. (2015). Common correlated effects estimation of heterogeneous dynamic panel data models with weakly exogenous regressors. Journal of Econometrics, 188(2), 393–420. Heterogeneity in Panel Data and in Nonparametric Analysis in honor of Professor Cheng Hsiao.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chudik, A., Pesaran, M. H., & Tosetti, E. (2011). Weak and strong crosssection dependence and estimation of large panels. Econometrics Journal, 14(1), C45–C90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coe, D. T., & Helpman, E. (1995). International R&D spillovers. European Economic Review, 39(5), 859–887.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de La Grandville, O. (1989). In quest of the slutsky diamond. American Economic Review, 79(3), 468–81.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dreher, A. (2006). Does globalization affect growth? Evidence from a new index of globalization. Applied Economics, 38(10), 1091–1110.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eberhardt, M., Helmers, C., & Strauss, H. (2013). Do spillovers matter when estimating private returns to R&D? The Review of Economics and Statistics, 95(2), 436–448.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eberhardt, M., & Presbitero, A. F. (2015). Public debt and growth: Heterogeneity and non-linearity. Journal of International Economics, 97(1), 45–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eberhardt, M., & Teal, F. (2011). Econometrics for grumblers: A new look at the literature on crosscountry growth empirics. Journal of Economic Surveys, 25(1), 109–155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eberhardt, M., & Teal, F. (2013). Structural change and cross-country growth empirics. Policy Research Working Paper Series 6335, The World Bank.

  • Falvey, R., Foster, N., & Greenaway, D. (2004). Imports, exports, knowledge spillovers and growth. Economics Letters, 85(2), 209–213.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feenstra, R., & Hanson, G. (2001). Global production sharing and rising inequality: A survey of trade and wages. NBER Working Papers 8372, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.

  • Feenstra, R. C., & Hanson, G. H. (1999). The impact of outsourcing and high-technology capital on wages: Estimates for the united states, 1979–1990. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(3), 907–940.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldin, C., & Katz, L. F. (1996). The origins of technology-skill complementarity. NBER Working Papers 5657, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.

  • Gollin, D. (2002). Getting income shares right. Journal of Political Economy, 110(2), 458–474.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griliches, Z. (1969). Capital-skill complementarity. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 51(4), 465–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hijzen, A., & Swaim, P. (2010). Offshoring, labour market institutions and the elasticity of labour demand. European Economic Review, 54(8), 1016–1034.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Irmen, A. (2008). Comment on “On the openness to trade as a determinant of the macroeconomic elasticity of substitution”. Journal of Macroeconomics, 30(2), 703–706.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jayadev, A. (2007). Capital account openness and the labour share of income. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 31(3), 423–443.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones, L. E., & Manuelli, R. E. (1990). A convex model of equilibrium growth: Theory and policy implications. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5), 1008–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones, R., & Kierzkowski, H. (1998). Globalization and the consequences of international fragmentation. In G. C. Rudiger Dornbusch & M. Obsfeld (Eds.), Money, factor mobility and trade: The Festschrift in honor of Robert A. Mundell. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Karabarbounis, L., & Neiman, B. (2014). The global decline of the labor share. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 129(1), 61–103.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klump, R., & de La Grandville, O. (2000). Economic growth and the elasticity of substitution: Two theorems and some suggestions. American Economic Review, 90(1), 282–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krusell, P., Ohanian, L. E., Ríos-Rull, J.-V., & Violante, G. L. (2000). Capital-skill complementarity and inequality: A macroeconomic analysis. Econometrica, 68(5), 1029–1054.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Madsen, J. (2010). Growth and capital deepening since 1870: Is it all technological progress? Journal of Macroeconomics, 32(2), 641–656.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nickell, S. J. (1981). Biases in dynamic models with fixed effects. Econometrica, 49(6), 1417–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pedroni, P. (2007). Social capital, barriers to production and capital shares: implications for the importance of parameter heterogeneity from a nonstationary panel approach. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 22(2), 429–451.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pesaran, M. (2004). General diagnostic tests for cross section dependence in panels. Cambridge Working Papers in Economics 0435, Faculty of Economics, University of Cambridge.

  • Pesaran, M. H. (2006). Estimation and inference in large heterogeneous panels with a multifactor error structure. Econometrica, 74(4), 967–1012.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pesaran, M. H. (2007). A simple panel unit root test in the presence of cross-section dependence. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 22(2), 265–312.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pesaran, M. H. (2015). Time series and panel data econometrics. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Pesaran, M. H., & Smith, R. (1995). Estimating long-run relationships from dynamic heterogeneous panels. Journal of Econometrics, 68(1), 79–113.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Raurich, X., Sala, H., & Sorolla, V. (2012). Factor shares, the price markup, and the elasticity of substitution between capital and labor. Journal of Macroeconomics, 34(1), 181–198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Revankar, N. S. (1971). A class of variable elasticity of substitution production functions. Econometrica, 39(1), 61–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, D. (1997). Has globalization gone too far?. Washington, DC: Peterson Institute for International Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rognlie, M. (2015). Deciphering the fall and rise in the net capital share. Brookings papers on economic activity, BPEA.

  • Roodman, D. (2009). How to do xtabond2: An introduction to difference and system GMM in stata. Stata Journal, 9(1), 86–136.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saam, M. (2008). Openness to trade as a determinant of the macroeconomic elasticity of substitution. Journal of Macroeconomics, 30(2), 691–702.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sachs, J. (2000). Globalization and patterns of economic development. Review of World Economics, 136(4), 579–600.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sato, R., & Hoffman, R. (1968). Production functions with variable elasticity of factor substitution: Some analysis and testing. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 50, 453–460.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shin, Y., Yu, B., & Greenwood-Nimmo, M. (2014). Modelling asymmetric cointegration and dynamic multipliers in a nonlinear ARDL framework. In W. Horrace & R. Sickles (Eds.), The Festschrift in honor of Peter Schmidt. New York, NY: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Slaughter, M. J. (2001). International trade and labor-demand elasticities. Journal of International Economics, 54(1), 27–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solow, R. M. (1957). Technical change and the aggregate production function. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 39(3), 312–320.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Srinivasan, T. N. (1995). Long-run growth theories and empirics: Anything new? In Growth theories in light of the East Asian experience, NBER-EASE, Volume 4, NBER Chapters, pp. 37–70. National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.

  • Young, A. T., & Lawson, R. A. (2014). Capitalism and labor shares: A cross-country panel study. European Journal of Political Economy, 33(C), 20–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We acknowledge helpful comments from three anonymous referees, which have led to significant improvements in the original version of this paper. Pedro Trivín acknowledges the warm hospitality received from the School of Economics and Finance of Queen Mary University of London, where the bulk of this work was developed. We are grateful to Ángel López, Matteo Fragetta, the participants in the XXIX Italian Conference of Labor Economics, the XI Spanish Conference of Labor Economics, the 39th SAEe, and the Economics Seminars at Ryerson University. We are also grateful to the Spanish Ministry of Economy and Competitiveness for financial support through Grant ECO2016-75623-R.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Hector Sala.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (pdf 277 KB)

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Sala, H., Trivín, P. The effects of globalization and technology on the elasticity of substitution. Rev World Econ 154, 617–647 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-018-0315-7

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-018-0315-7

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation