Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Identifying systemically important financial institutions: a network approach

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Computational Management Science Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The Basel Committee on Banking Supervision has proposed a methodology to identify Systemically Important Financial Institutions based on a series of indicators that should account for the externalities that these institutions place into the system. In this article we argue that the methodology chosen by Basel III maintains the micro-prudential focus of Basel I and II. We show how the PageRank algorithm that operates behind the Google search engine can be modified and applied to identify Systemically Important Financial Institutions. Being a feedback measure of systemic importance, the PageRank algorithm evaluates more than individual exposures. The algorithm is able to capture the risks that individual institutions place into the system, while at the same time, taking into account how the exposures at the system-wide level affect the ranking of individual institutions. In accordance to the Basel III framework, we are able to distinguish between systemic importance due to exposures born on the asset and on the liability side of the balance sheet of banks.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Kashyap et al. (2008), Bank of England (2009), Brunnermeier et al. (2009), Haldane (2009), Hellwig (2010), Trichet (2011), Haldane and May (2011) and Rosengren (2013).

  2. See Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2013).

  3. The five categories are: size, crossjurisdictional activity, interconnectedness, substitutability financial institution infrastructure and complexity. Each category has the same weight (20%) in the overall measure which is rescaled such that an overall score is given in basis points. See Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2013) for further details.

  4. We explicitly distinguish systemic risk, understood as a byproduct of banks’ bilateral first and higher order exposures in the interbank market, from contagion that results from correlations in bank asset returns as in Adrian and Brunnermeier (2008) or co-movement in the deposit flow as in Diamond and Dybvig (1983), as well as interconnectedness at the producer-supplier level (including financial interlinkages between banks and its non-financial borrowers/depositors) as in Acemoglu et al. (2010). Undoubtedly the two concepts are closely related and interbank exposures can be a major source of contagion; e.g. Allen and Gale (2000). The key distinguishing factor however, is that interbank exposures are first and higher order balance sheet interlinkages between financial institutions, i.e. horizontal exposures between peers rather than vertical exposures with clients or exposures due to losses in similar investment portfolios. In the event that a financial institution defaults, a void is immediately created in the balance sheet of several other banks through the direct and indirect horizontal linkages. This type of exposures represents a risk for the entire system that is typically several orders of magnitude higher than that resulting from other contagion mechanisms.

  5. Their analysis can in fact be performed using stock prices from companies of any industry, provided that they are publicly traded, regardless of whether they have or not direct bilateral balance sheet exposures. One of their findings for instance is that insurance companies emerge as systemically important towards the end of the sample. Despite the fact that both banks and insurances are financial intermediaries, insurance companies do not have direct balance sheet exposures against its peers while banks do. This means that the sources of systemic risk differ in both industries, which greatly influences design policies to control systemic risk (see Thimann 2014).

  6. While a bank can be a systemically important borrower and lender at the same time, this does not need to be the case. A bank can borrow relatively small amounts in the interbank market and yet be systemically important as a result of its lending activities. The risks for such a bank lie, and will be transmitted to the rest of the system, through the asset side of its balance sheet. On the contrary, banks borrowing large volumes face and distribute risks to the system through the liability side of the balance sheet.

  7. Dungey et al. (2013) compute their rankings based on a matrix correlations, which by definition is symmetric. In our case, to have a symmetric matrix of exposures, it is required that every borrowing transaction between any two banks i and j is perfectly matched by a lending transaction between the same banks. While two banks certainly can, and often do, lend and borrow from one another, a situation of perfect bilateral matching would render the interbank market a redundancy.

  8. Some recent contributions reaching similar conclusions include: Babus (2007), Gai and Kapadia (2010).

  9. See Newman (2002) and Meyers (2007) for examples of the spread of infectious diseases on human networks, and Pastor-Satorras and Vespignani (2001a, b, b) for the analysis of the spread of viruses on computer networks.

  10. The degree of a bank is the number of partners that every bank has. See Sect. 2 below for further details. Assortative mixing refers to the property by which nodes in a network establish a relationship with similar nodes, according to a certain characteristic (size, degree, geographical location, etc). Disassortative mixing refers to the opposite situation, i.e. nodes connecting to nodes belonging to different groups.

  11. The small world effect refers to the property observed in a large number of social networks by which the distance between any two nodes grows at a speed \( {\text{log }}\left( n \right) \) as n → ∞, where n is the number of nodes. Cont et al. (2013) question this finding in the context of interbank networks.

  12. In the case of bipartite networks, the adjacency matrix is typically not squared. The adjacency matrix of bipartite networks receives the name of incidence matrix to distinguish it from the adjacency matrix.

  13. In other networks, most notably the internet, it is common to have selfedges.

  14. See Freeman (1978) and Borgatti and Everett (2006).

  15. The weighted version of the degree centrality is known in the network literature as strength centrality, for homogeneity we maintain the same degree denomination also for weighted networks.

  16. We are not the first to stress this issue. Albert and Barabási (2002), Newman (2004) and others have argued that the study of weighted networks has occupied a much smaller stage in the literature, than it probably should. Networks like the collaboration between authors, friendship networks, affiliation networks, biochemical and ecological networks, and the internet as well are networks in which the link between any two nodes might have different intensities. In other words, several networks are intrinsically weighted and in such cases, the network properties are better understood when using weighted instead of binary adjacency matrices.

  17. See Newman (2010) for further details.

  18. The term \(fd'_{out}\) is added to the matrix \(A\,\Phi\) to guarantee that the resulting matrix is irreducible.

  19. Notice that for α = 1, the irreducibility of the matrix \( \overline{\overline{P}}_{r} \) is no longer guaranteed. In this case the eigenvector in not uniquely defined. The same is true when the elements fi are not all larger than 0. For this reason, in most applications, f is chosen to be \( \frac{1}{n}1 \), such that fi > 0 is guaranteed ∀i = 1, …, n.

  20. The most widely used method to compute the eigenvector corresponding to the largest eigenvalue in the context of the PageRank is the power method.

  21. The former case corresponds to the eigencentrality measure, from which the PageRank measure is derived.

  22. When applying the algorithm, we set the parameter α = 0.85 and the elements fi = 1/n.

  23. The same principle applies to the matrix \( \overline{\overline{P}}_{l} \) of course.

  24. Acharya et al. (2012) argue that also market power is a potentially important factor driving the behavior of banks in the interbank market.

  25. Trust in the present context is directly related to the definition given in Fehr (2009): An individual trusts if she voluntarily places resources at the disposal of another party (the trustee) without any legal commitment from the latter. In addition, the act of trust is associated with an expectation that the act will pay off in terms of the investor’s goals. In particular, if the trustee is trustworthy the investor is better off than if trust were not placed, whereas if the trustee is not trustworthy the investor is worse off then if trust were not placed.

  26. As argued in Rochet and Tirole (1996) policies like lending of last resort reduce the incentives of banks to monitor their peers. This helps increasing the importance trust as a driver of interest rates.

  27. According to a 2007 ECB survey, the overnight market segment account for the 70% of the all unsecured market.

  28. The EONIA is a weighted average of all uncollateralised overnight loans processed by a portfolio of the most active credit institutions in the money market.

  29. ONL are contracts encompassing more than one day between two consecutive business days.

  30. We are aware that the e-MID dataset encompasses most of the transactions in which at least one partner in an Italian bank and thus it could potentially underestimate the relationships between foreign banks because they can transact using also other platforms. Unfortunately we do not have a dataset that contains all this information.

  31. To limit the potential noise in daily observations, we employ monthly averaged exposures.

  32. The Basel III was scheduled to be introduced from 2013 until 2015; however, changes from 1 April 2013 extended implementation until 31 March 2018 and again extended to 31 March 2019. This regulatory framework is not the actual methodology used to identify the SIFI but it is the first attempt of measuring the importance of interconnection between financial institutions.

  33. See Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2013, 2015).

  34. We have experimented with several cutoff values and the results remain qualitatively unchanged.

  35. We first rank the banks according to their systemic importance in decreasing order using the two different methodologies: PageRank and Basel III. Then we identify those banks that belong to the upper 20-th percentile of the ranking (the upper bucket) according to both methodologies. Finally we compute the percentage of banks that enter into the PageRank and Basel III buckets simultaneously, i.e. the banks that both methodologies ‘agree’ that belong to the upper bucket of systemic importance.

  36. We denote the PageRank vector with the general notation π because the findings of Langville and Meyer (2004) apply to both the lending and the borrowing ranks.

  37. It is in fact to be expected, that the variability of the rankings in the lower percentiles of the PageRank distribution will be higher. For this reason we focus here only on relatively high percentiles of the PageRank distribution.

  38. We also perform this same analysis considering the banks that enter into the largest 5‐th PageRank percentile. Our conclusions regarding the choice of the parameter α and the stability of the results due to changes in α remain unchanged.

References

  • Acemoglu D, Ozdaglar A, Tahbaz-Salehi A (2010) Cascades in networks and aggregate volatility. NBER Working Papers 16516, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc

  • Acemoglu D, Ozdaglar A, Tahbaz-Salehi A (2015) Systemic risk and stability in financial networks. Am Econ Rev 105(2):564–608

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acharya VV, Pedersen LH, Philippon T, Richardson M (2010) Measuring systemic risk. Working Paper 1002, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

  • Acharya VV, Gromb D, Yorulmazer T (2012) Imperfect competition in the inter-bank market for liquidity as a rationale for central banking. Am Econ J: Macroecon 4(2):184–217

    Google Scholar 

  • Adrian T, Brunnermeier MK (2008) Covar. Staff Reports 348, Federal Reserve Bank of New York

  • Albert R, Barabási A-L (2002) Statistical mechanics of complex networks. Rev Mod Phys 74(47):97

    Google Scholar 

  • Allen F, Gale D (2000) Financial contagion. J Polit Econ 108(1):1–33

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allen F, Babus A, Carletti E (2012) Asset commonality, debt maturity and systemic risk. J Financ Econ 104(3):519–534

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Babus A (2007) The formation of financial networks. Working Papers 2007.69, Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei

  • Bank of England (2009). The role of macroprudential policy. Discussion paper, Bank of England

  • Basel I (2004) International convergence of capital measurement and capital standards: a revised framework basle committee on banking supervision. http: //www. bis.org/publ/bcbs107.htm

  • Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2013) Global systemically important banks: Updated assessment methodology and the higher loss absorbency requirement. Technical report, Bank for International Settlements

  • Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2015) Implementation of Basel standards. A report to G20 Leaders on implementation of the Basel III regulatory reforms. Technical report, Bank for International Settlements

  • Battiston S, Delli Gatti D, Gallegati M, Greenwald B, Stiglitz JE (2012) Liaisons dangereuses: increasing connectivity, risk sharing and systemic risk. J Econ Dyn Control 36(8):1121–1141

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bech ML, Atalay E (2010) The topology of the federal funds market. Phys A 389(22):5223–5246

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borgatti SP, Everett MG (2006) A graph-theoretic perspective on centrality. Soc Netwo 28(4):466–484

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borio CEV (2003) Towards a macroprudential framework for financial supervision and regulation? BIS Working Papers 128, Bank for International Settlements

  • Borio CEV, Furfine C, Lowe P (2001) Procyclicality of the financial system and financial stability: Issues and policy options. BIS Working Papers 1, Bank for International Settlements

  • Boss M, Elsinger H, Summer M, Thurner S (2004) Network topology of the interbank market. Quantitative Finance 4(6):677–684

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brin S, Page L (1998) The anatomy of a large-scale hypertextual web search engine. Comput Netw ISDN Syst 30(1–7):107–117

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brownlees CT, Engle RF (2012) Volatility, correlation and tails for systemic risk measurement. Working paper, mimeo

  • Brunnermeier MK, Crockett A, Goodhart C, Persaud A, Shin H (2009) The Fundamental Principles of Financial Regulation. International Center for Monetary and Banking Studies Centre for Economic Policy Research, Geneva London

  • Castiglionesi F, Navarro N (2007) Optimal fragile financial networks. Discussion Paper 2007-100, Tilburg University, Center for Economic Research

  • Castro C, Ferrari S (2014) Measuring and testing for the systemically important financial institutions. J Empir Finance 25:1–14

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clauset A, Shalizi CR, Newman ME (2009) Power-law distributions in empirical data. SIAM Rev 51(4):661–703

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cocco JF, Gomes FJ, Martins NC (2009) Lending relationships in the interbank market. J Financ Intermed 18(1):24–48

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cont R, Moussa A, Santos EB (2013) Network structure and systemic risk in banking systems. In: Fouque J-P, Langsam JA (eds) Handbook on systemic risk. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Craig B, von Peter G (2010) Interbank tiering and money center banks. Working Paper 322, Bank for International Settlements

  • Crockett A (2000) Marrying the macro- and micro-prudential dimensions of financial stability. BIS Working Papers 1, Bank for International Settlements

  • De Masi G, Iori G, Caldarelli G (2006) Fitness model for the italian interbank money markets. Phys Rev E 74:066112

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Degryse H, Nguyen G (2007) Interbank exposures: an empirical examination of contagion risk in the belgian banking system. Int J Central Bank 3(123):171

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond DW, Dybvig PH (1983) Bank runs, deposit insurance, and liquidity. J Polit Econ 91(3):401–419

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diebold FX, Yilmaz K (2011) On the network topology of variance decompositions: Measuring the connectedness of financial firms. Working Paper 1124, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

  • Dijkstra EW (1959) A note on two problems in connexion with graphs. Numer Math 1(1):269–271

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drehmann M, Tarashev N (2013) Measuring the systemic importance of interconnected banks. J Financ Intermed 22(4):586–607

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dungey M, Luciani M, Veredas D (2013) Googling sifis. ULB Institutional Repository 2013/154950, ULB—Universite Libre de Bruxelles

  • Elsinger H, Lehar A, Summer M (2006) Risk assessment for banking systems. Manag Sci 52(9):1301–1314

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr E (2009) On the economics and biology of trust. J Eur Econ Assoc 7(2–3):235–266

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freeman LC (1978) Centrality in social networks conceptual clarification. Soc Netw 1:215

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freixas X, Holthausen C (2005) Interbank market integration under asymmetric infor-mation. Rev Financ Stud 18(2):459–490

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freixas X, Parigi BM, Rochet J-C (2000) Systemic risk, interbank relations, and liquidity provision by the central bank. J Money Credit Bank 32(3):611–638

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fricke D (2012) Trading strategies in the overnight money market: Correlations and clustering on the e-mid trading platform. Working Paper 1766, Kiel Institute for the World Economy

  • Fricke D, Lux T (2012) Core–periphery structure in the overnight money market: Evidence from the e-mid trading platform. Working Paper 1759, Kiel Institute for the World Economy

  • Fricke D, Lux T (2013). On the distribution of links in the interbank network: Evidence from the e-mid overnight money markets. Technical report, Kiel Institute for the World Economy

  • Fricke D, Lux T (2015) Core-periphery structure in the overnight money market: evidence from the e-mid trading platform. Comput Econ 45(3):359–395

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Furfine CH (2001) Banks as monitors of other banks: evidence from the overnight federal funds market. J Bus 74(1):33–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Furfine CH (2003) Interbank exposures: quantifying the risk of contagion. J Money Credit Bank 35:111–128

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gai P, Kapadia S (2010) Contagion in financial networks. Proc R Soc A 466:2401–2423

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haldane AG (2009) Rethinking the financial networks. Speech delivered at the financial student association, Amsterdam, Bank of England

  • Haldane AG, May R (2011) Systemic risk in banking ecosystems. Nature 469:351–355

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haldane AG et al (2009) Rethinking the financial network. Speech delivered at the Financial Student Association, Amsterdam, pp 1–26

    Google Scholar 

  • Hatzopoulos, V. and Iori, G. (2012). Information theoretic description of the e-mid interbank market: Implications for systemic risk. Discussion Paper 12/04, Department of Economics, School of Social Science, City University London

  • Hellwig M (2010) Capital regulation after the crisis: business as usual? CESifo DICE Rep 8(2):40–46

    Google Scholar 

  • Inaoka H, Ninomiya T, Taniguchi K, Shimizu T, Takayasu H (2004) Fractal network derived from banking transaction: An analysis of network structures formed by financial institutions. Technical Report 04-E-04, Bank of Japan

  • Iori G, Renò R, De Masi G, Caldarelli G (2007) Trading strategies in the italian interbank market. Phys A 376(467):479

    Google Scholar 

  • Iori G, De Masi G, Precup O, Gabbi G, Caldarelli G (2008) A network analysis of the Italian overnight money market. J Econ Dyn Control 32(259):278

    Google Scholar 

  • Kashyap AK, Rajan RG, Stein JC (2008) Rethinking capital regulation. In: Proceedings of the 2008 economic symposium. Maintaining stability in a changing financial system. Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, pp 431–471

  • Krause A, Giansante S (2012) Interbank lending and the spread of bank failures: a network model of systemic risk. J Econ Behav Organ 83(3):583–608

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Langville AN, Meyer CD (2004) Deeper inside pagerank. Internet Math 1:2004

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meyers LA (2007) Contact network epidemiology: bond percolation applied to infectious disease prediction and control. Bull Am Math Soc 44(63):86

    Google Scholar 

  • Mistrulli PE (2011) Assessing financial contagion in the interbank market: maximum entropy versus observed interbank lending patterns. J Bank Finance 35(5):1114–1127

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moore K, Zhou C (2012) Identifying systemically important financial institutions: Size and other determinants. Technical report, mimeo

  • Newman M (2002) Spread of epidemic disease on networks. Phys Rev E 66(1):016128

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newman M (2004) Analysis of weighted networks. Phys Rev E 70:056131

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newman ME (2010) Networks, an introduction. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Nier E, Yang J, Yorulmazer T, Alentorn A (2007) Network models and financial stability. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control. In: Tenth workshop on economic heterogeneous interacting agents, vol 31(6) pp 2033–2060

  • Pastor-Satorras R, Vespignani A (2001a) Epidemic dynamics and endemic states in complex networks. Phys Rev E 63:066117

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pastor-Satorras R, Vespignani A (2001b) Epidemic spreading in scale-free networks. Phys Rev Lett 86:14

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rochet J-C, Tirole J (1996) Interbank lending and systemic risk. J Money Credit Bank 28(4):733–762

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosengren ES (2013) Bank capital: Lessons from the U.S. financial crisis. Technical report, Bank for International Settlements Forum on Key Regulatory and Supervisory Issues in a Basel III World

  • Sheldon G, Maurer M (1998) Interbank lending and systemic risk: an empirical analysis for switzerland. Swiss J Econ Stat (SJES) 134(IV):685–704

    Google Scholar 

  • Soramäki K, Bech ML, Arnold J, Glass RJ, Beyeler WE (2007) The topology of interbank payment flows. Phys A 379(1):317–333

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tarashev NA, Borio CEV, Tsatsaronis K (2009) The systemic importance of financial institutions. BIS Q Rev. https://ssrn.com/abstract=1473007

  • Thimann C (2014) How insurers differ from banks: A primer on systemic regulation. Special Paper 3, Systemic Risk Centre. LSE

  • Trichet J-C (2011) Intellectual challenges to financial stability analysis in the era of macro-prudential oversight. Financ Stabil Rev 15(139):149

    Google Scholar 

  • Upper C (2011) Simulation methods to assess the danger of contagion in interbank markets. J Financ Stabil 7(3):111–125

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Upper C, Worms A (2004) Estimating bilateral exposures in the german interbank market: is there a danger of contagion? Eur Econ Rev 48(4):827–849

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Virkar Y, Clauset A et al (2014) Power-law distributions in binned empirical data. Ann Appl Stat 8(1):89–119

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wagner W (2010) Diversification at financial institutions and systemic crises. J Financ Intermed 19(3):373–386

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zawadowski A (2013) Entangled financial systems. Rev Financ Stud 26(5):1291–1323

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Alessandro Spelta.

Additional information

We are indebted to the European Commission for their financial support through the EU FP7 RASTANEWS project (research Grant No. 320278), and to the Research Foundation Flanders (FWO) for their financial support through the research Grant 1510413 N. All errors are ours.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Rovira Kaltwasser, P., Spelta, A. Identifying systemically important financial institutions: a network approach. Comput Manag Sci 16, 155–185 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10287-018-0327-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10287-018-0327-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation