Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Industrial heterogeneity and international product cycles

  • Published:
Journal of Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper proposes a model of quality ladder in the context of North–South trade to examine the emergence of product cycles in industries of different research and development (R&D) intensity levels. To acquire the dominant advantage, firms as a whole can strategically undertake either quality upgrades through R&D or cost saving through the channels of market penetration—foreign direct investment (FDI) or offshoring. In an infinite-horizon game, the uses of mixing moving-up and moving-out strategies in high-tech and medium-tech industries generate product cycles. Furthermore, in low-tech industries, FDI is a strongly dominant strategy for the industry leaders and followers. Under certain conditions, firms leapfrog over each other and product cycles thus emerge.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See, also, Hu and Jefferson (2002), Feenstra and Hanson (2005), Liu (2010) and Fu (2011).

  2. According to “Statistics Sweden” (http://www.scb.se/en), China is now the 10th-largest trading partner of Sweden with 3.1% share of its total exports of goods. Compared to other nine major trading partners with Sweden, China is the one whose gross domestic product (at purchasing power parity) per capita is less than 15,000 international dollars (Int$). See, World Bank 2015 data source: http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/.

  3. Krugman’s work has been extended by Dollar (1986) and Jensen and Thursby (1986). Dollar maintained Krugman’s assumption of an exogenous rate of product innovation, but related the rate of technology transfer to the North–South terms of trade, albeit in an entirely ad hoc manner. Jensen and Thursby assumed that all innovation is carried out by a single entrepreneur in the North, and that the allocation of resources in the South is performed by a social planner.

  4. In addition to the variety-based model and the quality ladder model, other frameworks can be used to analyze product cycles. For instance, Zhu (2004) extended the Dornbusch–Fischer–Samuelson (DFS) model with Northern product innovation and product-cycle-driven technology transfers. Antràs (2005) incorporated the model of incomplete contracts into the product cycle issue.

  5. In contrast to the strong scale effects in the earlier literature, economic growth in their model is characterized by weak scale effects. See, also, Gustafsson and Segerstrom (2010).

  6. See, also, Segerstrom (1991), Mukoyama (2003) and Horii and Iwaisako (2007).

  7. Specifically, Lu’s (2007, p. 326) Figure 1 in her introduction utilized the measurement and data of product-cycle trade from Zhu (2005), and then illustrated the product-cycle trade intensity and the R&D intensity across industries. The figure evidently showed that product cycle emerges in industries in almost all levels. Notice that, in her figure, industries are arranged along the axis according to their R&D intensities with the most R&D-intensive industry located at the far right.

  8. As the second trand we have shown above, R&D in this paper is to upgrade quality for the existing varieties of products.

  9. See, e.g., Grossman and Helpman (1991a, b, c) for details.

  10. Although the wages might be endogenously influenced by the results of strategic choices between R&D and FDI/outsourcing, we assume that the wage rates are exogenously fixed as traditional trade theories for solving outcomes in the present fairly complicated model.

  11. This is equivalent to the Schumpeterian “process of creative destruction.” In each period, a firm enjoys its temporary monopoly power until a more inventive challenger appears. See, e.g., Reinganum (1985).

  12. In Lu (2007), she considered only the production of final goods. Thereby, a multinational firm’s instantaneous profit in her model is \(\pi _{F}=pX-X\) with the wage rate in the South being 1. See, also, Suzuki (2015). In the present paper, we specifically separate the production line by two divisions respectively on intermediate and final goods. It follows that a multinational firm’s cost in its instantaneous profit function is 2X. Notice that each intermediate good is variety-specific by assumptions.

  13. See, also, Grossman and Helpman (1991b), Glass and Saggi (2002) and Lu (2007).

  14. Slightly different from Lu (2007) and Suzuki (2015) as we shown in the former footnote, the present paper considers two divisions of upstream and downstream production processes. It follows that the production cost in a Northern firm’s instantaneous profit function is \(w_{N}(1+\gamma )X\).

  15. This cost can be seen as a training cost equivalently. To undertake R&D, a firm requires skilled labors, and then pays for upgrading workers’ skills.

  16. We simply assume that the follower after the first period t learns and uses the same development path as the leader did, that is, move up, then move out, then move up, then move out, and so on. However, if the follower insists on undertaking R&D, then there is no chance for the leader to seek possible cost advantages via FDI or offshoring. Otherwise, the leader may lose the market at some point.

  17. Recall that \(a_{F}^{*}(z,y,j)\) denotes the unit Southern labor requirement per unit of FDI intensity for the version j of product (zy), and \(a_{R}\) denotes the number of skilled labors working for R&D. One can see also the Sects. 3.3 and 2.3.3 in detail.

  18. For instance, if \(\frac{1+w_{N}\tau }{\lambda }>2\) and J always undertakes offshoring and never engages in R&D, then J earns zero profit at the end.

  19. In low-tech industries, a dominant firm considers FDI as its strategy until it no longer earns profit, and then invests in R&D. The game mentions the rotation of the undertaking of FDI and R&D.

References

  • Antràs P (2005) Incomplete contracts and the product cycle. Am Econ Rev 95:1054–1073

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit A, Stiglitz J (1977) Monopolistic competition and optimum product diversity. Am Econ Rev 67:297–308

    Google Scholar 

  • Dollar D (1986) Technological innovation, capital mobility, and the product cycle in North–South trade. Am Econ Rev 76:177–190

    Google Scholar 

  • Etro F (2004) Innovation by leaders. Econ J 114:281–303

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feenstra RC, Hanson GH (2005) Ownership and control in outsourcing to China: estimating the property-rights theory of the firm. Q J Econ 120:729–761

  • Feenstra RC, Rose AK (2000) Putting things in order: trade dynamics and product cycles. Rev Econ Stat 82:369–382

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flam H, Helpman E (1987) Vertical product differentiation and North–South trade. Am Econ Rev 77:810–822

    Google Scholar 

  • Fu X (2011) Processing trade, FDI and the exports of indigenous firms: firm-level evidence from technology-intensive industries in China. Oxf Bull Econ Stat 73:792–817

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaulier G, Lemoine F, Unal-Kesenci D (2007) China’s emergence and the reorganization of trade flows in Asia. China Econ Rev 18:209–243

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glass A (1997) Product cycles and market penetration. Int Econ Rev 38:865–891

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glass A, Saggi K (1998) International technology transfer and the technology gap. J Dev Econ 55:369–398

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glass A, Saggi K (2002) Licensing versus direct investment: implications for economic growth. J Int Econ 56:131–153

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman G, Helpman E (1991a) Endogenous product cycles. Econ J 101:1214–1229

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman G, Helpman E (1991b) Quality ladders and product cycles. Q J Econ 106:557–586

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman G, Helpman E (1991c) Quality ladders in the theory of growth. Rev Econ Stud 58:43–61

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gustafsson P, Segerstrom P (2010) North–South trade with increasing product variety. J Dev Econ 92:97–106

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gustafsson P, Segerstrom P (2011) North–South trade with multinational firms and increasing product variety. Int Econ Rev 52:1123–1155

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hallak JC (2006) Product quality and the direction of trade. J Int Econ 68:238–265

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Horii R, Iwaisako T (2007) Economic growth with imperfect protection of intellectual property rights. J Econ 90:45–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hu A, Jefferson G (2002) FDI impact and spillover: evidence from China’s electronic and textile industries. World Econ 38:1063–1076

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen R, Thursby M (1986) A strategic approach to the product life cycle. J Int Econ 21:269–284

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen R, Thursby M (1987) A decision theoretic model of innovation, technology transfer, and trade. Rev Econ Stud 54:631–647

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones C (1995) R&D-based models of economic growth. J Polit Econ 103:759–784

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P (1979) A model of innovation, technology transfer, and the world distribution of income. J Polit Econ 87:253–266

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu X (2010) China’s development model: an alternative strategy for technological catch-up. In: Fu X, Soete L (eds) The rise of technological power in the South. Palgrave Macmillan, Basingstoke

    Google Scholar 

  • Lu C-H (2007) Moving up or moving out? A unified theory of R&D, FDI, and trade. J Int Econ 71:324–343

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mukoyama T (2003) Innovation, imitation, and growth with cumulative technology. J Monet Econ 50:361–380

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Naghavi A, Ottaviano G (2009) Offshoring and product innovation. Econ Theor 38:517–532

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Palokangas T (2008) Competition and product cycles with non-diversifiable risk. J Econ 94:1–30

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reinganum JF (1985) Innovation and industry evolution. Q J Econ 100:81–99

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Savsin S (2011) China’s integration in foreign trade: revealed comparative advantage analysis for Sweden in relation with China. Research paper. Örebro University, Sweden

    Google Scholar 

  • Segerstrom P (1991) Innovation, imitation, and economic growth. J Polit Econ 99:807–827

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Segerstrom P, Zolnierek J (1999) The R&D incentives of industry leaders. Int Econ Rev 40:745–766

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Suzuki K (2015) Legal enforcement against illegal imitation in developing countries. J Econ 116:247–270

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vernon R (1966) International investment and international trade in product cycle. Q J Econ 80:190–207

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yang G, Maskus K (2001) Intellectual property rights, licensing, and innovation in an endogenous product-cycle model. J Int Econ 53:169–187

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yeaple S (2003) The role of skill endowment in the structure of U.S. outward foreign direct investment. Rev Econ Stat 85:726–734

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhu SC (2004) Trade, product cycles and inequality within and between countries. Can J Econ 37:1042–1060

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhu SC (2005) Can product cycles explain skill upgrading? J Int Econ 66:131–155

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are indebted to the editor-in-chief, two referees, Haitao Mao, Wenshou Yan, Xiaopeng Yin and Qi Zhang for constructive comments and helpful suggestions. Also, we are grateful for many useful comments and discussions by conference participants at 2016 Asia Meeting of Econometric Society in Japan and 2017 Annual Meeting of Chinese Society of International Trade.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Tai-Liang Chen.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Zou, Y., Chen, TL. Industrial heterogeneity and international product cycles. J Econ 125, 1–25 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-017-0586-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-017-0586-9

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation