Skip to main content
Log in

Optimal taxation under a consumption target

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Social Choice and Welfare Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

While in the familiar problem of optimal commodity taxation the government faces a constraint on tax revenue, we consider the case of a consumption target on a group of commodities (i.e., a weak constraint on total consumption), instead. This optimal commodity tax problem with a consumption target brings about taxation rules that are mainly at variance with the standard results of commodity taxation. In our main theorem, we derive a general, though quite simple, rule of optimal commodity taxation under a target on total consumption: in particular, we establish that higher consumer prices should be charged for commodities with (1) high price elasticities of total demand and (2) low consumption shares in total demand. From this theorem we deduce three important corollaries: an anti-inverse elasticity result, an anti-Corlett–Hague result and a uniform-pricing result. All of these results are (generically) at variance with well-known rules of commodity taxation.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For example, since 2003 the WHO requests member states to increase influenza vaccination coverage of all people at high risk with the goal of attaining vaccination coverage of the elderly population of 75% by 2010 (56th WHA 2003). In 2009 the Council of the EU recommended member states to reach this goal by the winter of 2014/2015 (European Commission 2009). As a second example consider the governmental objective to reduce consumption of alcohol: in 2010 the Russian government, alarmed by Russians’ excessive alcohol consumption, pledged to reduce alcohol consumption by 55% by 2020.

  2. For instance, Article 6 of the WHO Framework Convention on Tobacco Control (FCTC, 2003–2005) states “..., each Party should take account of its national health objectives concerning tobacco control and adopt or maintain, as appropriate, measures which may include: (a) implementing tax policies and, where appropriate, price policies, on tobacco products so as to contribute to the health objectives aimed at reducing tobacco consumption.” Similarly, environmental taxes are frequently employed to meet predetermined emission or consumption targets. Notable examples are taxes on different types of fuel to accomplish specified \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\)- or \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\)-emission levels.

  3. Actual tax rates on different types of fuel (and also on energy products and electricity) in the EU are documented by the European Commission (2015). Using these figures it is simple to calculate prices of carbon contained in a specific type of fuel by using the fact that, for example, each gallon of petrol contains 2421 g of carbon; and each gallon of diesel, 2778 g (U.S. Environmental Protection Agency 2005).

  4. The quantity constraint is weak in the sense that it is not strictly binding, but may be violated provided that the decision maker is willing to carry the associated cost of missing the target.

  5. The inverse elasticity rule has two versions, one for compensated demand and one for ordinary demand. See, e.g., Sandmo (1987).

  6. For recent studies of this rule, see Kaplow (2010), who reconsidered the discussion of the rule in the presence of an income tax in the literature, and Kleven et al. (2000), who showed a modified Corlett–Hague rule for optimal taxation with household production.

  7. Deaton (1979), Besley and Jewitt (1995), and Barbie and Hermeling (2009) provided conditions on preferences for uniform commodity taxes to be optimal. In particular, these authors showed that uniform commodity taxes are optimal if, and only if, preferences are implicitly (or quasi) separable between leisure and consumption goods.

  8. This additive property is a general feature of optimal taxation problems with externalities (see, e.g., Kopczuk 2003).

  9. The function D reflects the case that the target level has to be reached from above (reduction of demand). More generally, to deal with the case that the target level has to be reached from below (increase of demand), we may redefine a cost (or damage) function by D(|Y|) with \(Y \in \mathbb {R}\).

  10. A special case of this problem is where there is a strictly binding constraint on consumption (i.e., \(X^{m} (q_{0}, \mathbf {q}, I) = \bar{Z}\)), rather than a target on which the government may compromise.

  11. It can be shown that the second-order conditions are satisfied in suitably chosen examples (e.g., with a Cobb-Douglas utility function and with \(D (Y) \equiv Y^{a}, a > 1\)).

  12. Sandmo (1974) also shows that this condition is satisfied when the utility function is weakly separable, written as \(u (x_{0}, f (\mathbf {x}))\), and the function f is homogeneous of some arbitrary positive degree. See also footnote 7.

  13. Similarly, Heady (1993, p. 33) states that “all goods have the same degree of complementarity or substitutability with leisure”; Sørensen (2007, p. 387), that “goods and services are equally substitutable for (complementary to) leisure”; and Boadway (2012, p. 54), that “all goods must be equally complementary with leisure.”

  14. Notice that we may rewrite Eq. (7) as \(q_{j} = - D^{\prime } k_{j} \varepsilon _{j0}^{h} / \theta , \, j = 1, 2, \dots , n\), by using the fact that \(\varepsilon _{j0}^{h} = - \varepsilon _{jj}^{h}, \; j = 1, 2, \dots , n\).

  15. The discussion on uniform commodity taxation in the Mirrlees review is based on Crawford et al. (2010), and it is further explored by Bastani et al. (2015) and others.

  16. This is similar to the demonstration of the uniformity of tax rates in the basic optimal commodity tax problem given by Sandmo (1974). See also Sadka (1977).

  17. The solution is unique if the matrix \((\partial x_{i}^{m} / \partial q_{j}) \; (i, j = 1, 2, \dots , n)\) is non-singular.

References

  • Auerbach AJ (1985) The theory of excess burden and optimal taxation. In: Auerbach AJ, Feldstein M (eds) Handbook of public economics, vol 1. North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp 61–127

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Auerbach AJ, Hines JR Jr (2002) Taxation and economic efficiency. In: Auerbach AJ, Feldstein M (eds) Handbook of public economics, vol 3. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 1347–1421

    Google Scholar 

  • Barbie M, Hermeling C (2009) The geometry of optimal taxation: a primal approach. Econ Theory 39(1):129–155

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bastani S, Blomquist S, Pirttilä J (2015) How should commodities be taxed? A counter-argument to the recommendation in the mirrlees review. Oxf Econ Pap 67(2):455–478

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley T, Jewitt I (1995) Uniform taxation and consumer preferences. J Public Econ 58(1):73–84

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boadway R (2012) From optimal tax theory to tax policy. The MIT Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Borcherding TE, Silberberg E (1978) Shipping the good apples out: the Alchian and Allen theorem reconsidered. J Polit Econ 86(1):131–138

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corlett WJ, Hague DC (1953) Complementarity and the excess burden of taxation. Rev Econ Stud 21(1):21–30

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crawford I, Keen M, Smith S (2010) Value added tax and excises. In: Mirrlees J, Adam S, Besley T, Blundell R, Bond S, Chote R, Gammie M, Johnson P, Myles G, Poterba J (eds) Dimensions of tax design: the mirrlees review. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Deaton A (1979) The distance function in consumer behaviour with applications to index numbers and optimal taxation. Rev Econ Stud 46(3):391–405

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diamond PA, Mirrlees JA (1971) Optimal taxation and public production: I-II. American Economic Review. 61(1):8–27 [(3): 261–278]

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission (2009) Proposal for a council recommendation on seasonal influenza vaccination. https://ec.europa.eu/health/vaccination/key_documents_en

  • European Commission (2015) Excise duty tables, REF 1044. https://ec.europa.eu/taxation_customs/index_en

  • Heady C (1993) Optimal taxation as a guide to tax policy: a survey. Fisc Stud 14(1):15–41

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hicks JR (1939) Value and capital. Clarendon Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Jacobs B, Boadway R (2014) Optimal linear commodity taxation under optimal non-linear income taxation. J Public Econ 117:201–210

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplow L (2010) Taxing leisure complements. Econ Inquiry 48(4):1065–1071

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kleven HJ, Richter WF, Sørensen PB (2000) Optimal taxation with household production. Oxf Econ Pap 52(3):584–594

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kopczuk W (2003) A note on optimal taxation in the presence of externalities. Econ Lett 80(1):81–86

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Minagawa J (2012) On Giffen-like goods. Econ Lett 115(2):282–285

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mirrlees J, Adam S, Besley T, Blundell R, Bond S, Chote R, Gammie M, Johnson P, Myles G, Poterba J (eds) (2011) Tax by design: the Mirrlees review. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Ramsey FP (1927) A contribution to the theory of taxation. Econ J 37(145):47–61

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sadka E (1977) A theorem on uniform taxation. J Public Econ 7(3):387–391

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sandmo A (1974) A note on the structure of optimal taxation. Am Econ Rev 64(4):701–706

    Google Scholar 

  • Sandmo A (1975) Optimal taxation in the presence of externalities. Swed J Econ 77(1):86–98

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sandmo A (1987) A reinterpretation of elasticity formulae in optimum tax theory. Economica 54(213):89–96

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Silberberg E, Suen W (2001) The structure of economics: a mathematical analysis, 3rd edn. McGraw-Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Sørensen PB (2007) The theory of optimal taxation: what is the policy relevance? Int Tax Public Fin 14(4):383–406

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz JE (2015) In praise of Frank Ramsey’s contribution to the theory of taxation. Econ J 125(583):235–268

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (2005) Emission facts. EPA420-F-05-001. https://www.epa.gov/nscep

  • World Health Assembly (2003) Prevention and control of influenza pandemics and annual epidemics. WHA56.19, 28. http://apps.who.int/iris/handle/10665/78320

  • World Health Organisation (2003–2005) WHO framework convention on tobacco control. http://www.who.int/fctc/en/

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to Ben Lockwood and two anonymous referees for their helpful and inspiring comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Junichi Minagawa.

Appendix: Proof of the generalised uniform-pricing result

Appendix: Proof of the generalised uniform-pricing result

We first prove the “only if.” For equal weighted consumer prices, \(q_{i} / k_{i} = r~\forall i=1,\ldots ,n\), the right-hand side of Eq. (9) becomes \((D^{\prime } / r) \sum _{i=1}^{n} \varepsilon _{ji}^{h}\). Using Hicks’ (1939) “third law,” we get \((D^{\prime } / r) \sum _{i=1}^{n} \varepsilon _{ji}^{h} = (D^{\prime } / r) (- \varepsilon _{j0}^{h})\). Then, all \(\varepsilon _{j0}^{h}\) (\(j \ne 0\)) must be equal. This implies that all \(\varepsilon _{i0}^{h}\) and \(\varepsilon _{0i}^{h}\) (\(\forall i \ne 0\)) have the same sign, since \(\partial x_{i}^{h} / \partial q_{j} = \partial x_{j}^{h} / \partial q_{i}\). Also, using Hicks’ “third law” and the fact that \(\varepsilon _{00}^{h} \leqq 0\), we obtain \(\sum _{i=1}^{n} \varepsilon _{0i}^{h} = - \varepsilon _{00}^{h} \geqq 0\). Therefore, all \(\varepsilon _{0i}^{h}\) and \(\varepsilon _{i0}^{h}\) (\(\forall i \ne 0\)) must be non-negative.

Next, we prove the “if.”Footnote 16 Suppose that all commodities are equally weakly substitutable with respect to the composite good, \(\varepsilon _{j0}^{h} = \alpha \geqq 0, \; \forall j \ne 0\). Then, by definition, \(\partial x_{j}^{h} / \partial q_{0} = \alpha x_{j} / q_{0}\). Thus, by symmetry, \(\partial x_{0}^{h} / \partial q_{j} = \alpha x_{j} / q_{0}\). Substituting this relation into the Slutsky equation yields

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial x_{0}^{m}}{\partial q_{j}} = \frac{\partial x_{0}^{h}}{\partial q_{j}} - \frac{\partial x_{0}^{m}}{\partial I} x_{j} = \left( \alpha - \frac{\partial x_{0}^{m}}{\partial I} q_{0} \right) \frac{x_{j}}{q_{0}}, \quad j = 1, 2, \dots , n. \end{aligned}$$
(A-1)

The term within the parentheses in Eq. (A-1) is independent of j, and we denote it by \(\beta \), that is, \(\partial x_{0}^{m} / \partial q_{j} = \beta x_{j} / q_{0}\). Now, differentiating both sides of the identity \(\sum _{i=0}^{n} q_{i} x_{i}^{m} (q_{0}, \mathbf {q}, I) \equiv I\) with respect to \(q_{j}\) and using the above relation, we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} x_{j} = - \frac{1}{1 + \beta } \sum _{i=1}^{n} q_{i} \frac{\partial x_{i}^{m}}{\partial q_{j}}. \end{aligned}$$
(A-2)

Substituting this into Eq. (2) yields

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{i=1}^{n} \left[ \frac{\mu }{(1 + \beta )} q_{i} - D^{\prime } k_{i} \right] \frac{\partial x_{i}^{m}}{\partial q_{j}} = 0, \quad j = 1, 2, \dots , n. \end{aligned}$$
(A-3)

Then, \([ \mu / (1 + \beta ) ] q_{i} - D^{\prime } k_{i} = 0, \; \forall i \ne 0\) is a solution of Eq. (A-3).Footnote 17 That is, \(q_{i} / k_{i} = (1 + \beta ) D^{\prime } / \mu , \; \forall i \ne 0\). The solution is independent of i and may be denoted by r.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Minagawa, J., Upmann, T. Optimal taxation under a consumption target. Soc Choice Welf 50, 663–676 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-017-1100-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-017-1100-6

Navigation