Skip to main content
Log in

Investment and financing in incomplete markets

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Economic Theory Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

I propose a model of production with incomplete financial markets, in which a firm can act as a financial innovator by issuing claims against its stock. In this environment, market value maximization may be against the firm’s shareholders’ interests. I propose instead a new measure of adjusted value, which is the sum between the market value and the shareholders’ surplus from their trades in the stock market. If a firm maximizes its adjusted value, then its financial policy is relevant (that is, Modigliani–Miller theorem does not hold), equilibrium outcomes are stable to shareholders’ renegotiation, and endogenously incomplete markets can arise at the equilibrium. If the firm is competitive, the adjusted value coincides with the objective proposed by Grossman and Hart (Econometrica 47(2):293–329, 1979). In a competitive market with no production-specific uninsurable risk (that is, spanning property holds), the adjusted value coincides with the market value.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Dierker et al. (2005) proved that when following Dréze’s (1974) objective, the firm may in fact select a production plan at which the initial shareholders’ surplus is minimized [see also Dierker et al. (2002)].

  2. Bonnisseau and Lachiri (2004) extend Dréze’s (1974) criterion to a multiperiod environment. The authors propose an objective for the firm that is derived from the first-order conditions of the non-convex constrained Pareto optimal problem (as Drèze’s objective is). However, the authors do not relate that objective to the preferences of any group of shareholders.

  3. As explained later, calling such price perceptions “competitive” may be misleading. I will use the term GH-price perceptions in the sequel.

  4. Note that Example 1 corresponds to the firm being forced to choose \(d=0\).

  5. Although this production set violates the condition \({\mathbf {0}}_{S+1}\in Y\) imposed later for the general model (and used to establish the existence of an equilibrium), the conclusion of Theorem 6.1 remains valid for this example because the production set is, trivially, compact.

  6. Profit (or value) maximization depends only on the market prices and thus is utility independent. However, it cannot be a candidate for such an objective because, as proved by Example 1, it is not consistent with the shareholders’ preferences.

  7. By the usual abuse of notation, the same symbol will be used to denote a finite set and the number of its elements. Therefore, \(I=\left\{ 1,2,\ldots ,I\right\} \) also denotes the set of consumers/investors.

  8. A more detailed description of such set will be provided in Sect. 4.

  9. With the notation of this paper, Dréze’s (1974) objective is \( \mathcal {D}_{\widetilde{y}}(y)=y_{0}+\left[ \sum _{i\in I}\theta ^{i}\left( \widetilde{y}\right) {\hbox {MRS}}^{i}\left( \widetilde{y}\right) \right] y^\mathbf{1},\) while Grossman and Hart’s (1979) is \(\mathcal {GH}_{\widetilde{y}}(y)=y_{0}+\left[ \sum _{i\in I}\delta ^{i}{\hbox {MRS}}^{i}\left( \widetilde{y}\right) \right] y^\mathbf{1}.\)

  10. The notion of minimal constrained efficiency was first introduced (to the best of my knowledge) by Dierker et al. (2005).

  11. On the one hand, allowing for degenerate as well as non-degenerate beliefs over possible equilibrium prices increases the generality of the model. On the other hand, it makes the equilibrium notion weaker. The discussion following the main Theorem in Sect. 6 gives more insights into this assumption.

  12. It is assumed that all portfolio payoffs and holdings are column vectors, while prices are row vectors.

  13. Examples of such firm-issued securities are convertibles, warrants, floating-rate debt, zero coupons, primes and scores.

  14. This assumption is made to simplify the technicalities of the model. However, since the firm is allowed to issue securities with zero payoff in all states, the constraint merely imposes an upper bound on the number of new securities the firm may issue.

  15. This restriction can be relaxed considerably by enlarging the set of “permissible” production plans to a superset of \(\widehat{Y}\). However, that level of generality is beyond the scope of this paper.

  16. Clearly, optimal portfolio holdings and consumption allocations depend on both \({\mathcal {P}}\) and the price selection \(\varPi \) and thus a more precise notation would be \(Z^i(\varPi ({\mathcal {P}}), {\mathcal {P}})\), \(c^i(\varPi ({\mathcal {P}}), \mathcal P)\). However, the notational simplification used above should create no confusion.

  17. The same point is made by Kreps (1987) in Essay II. Allen and Gale (1991) also argue that competition must be imperfect for the firms to have incentives to innovate in the financial markets.

  18. For a more recent model of competition under incomplete markets, see Bisin et al. (2016).

  19. Geanakoplos and Polemarchakis’s (1986) proof is given for economies with unlimited short-sales. Portfolio constraints only simplify the problem, as it is enough to prove existence of an equilibrium for the truncated economy.

References

  • Allen, F., Gale, D.: Arbitrage, short sales, and financial innovation. Econometrica 59(4), 1041–68 (1991)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aumann, R.J.: Markets with a continuum of traders. Econometrica 32(1/2), 39–50 (1964)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bejan, C.: The objective of a privately owned firm under imperfect competition. Econ. Theory 37(1), 99–118 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-007-0289-5

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bejan, C., Bidian, F.: Ownership structure and efficiency in large economies. Econ. Theory 50(3), 571 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-010-0585-3

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bisin, A.: General equilibrium with endogenously incomplete markets. J. Econ. Theory 82, 19–45 (1998)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bisin, A., Gottardi, P., Ruta, G.: Equilibrium corporate finance, SSRN (2016). https://ssrn.com/abstract=2815066 or https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2815066

  • Bonnisseau, J., Lachiri, O.: On the objective of firms under uncertainty with stock markets. J. Math. Econ. 40, 493–513 (2004)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carvajal, A., Rostek, M., Weretka, M.: Competition in financial innovation. Econometrica 80(5), 1895–1936 (2012)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Debreu, G.: New concepts and techniques for equilibrium analysis. Int. Econ. Rev. 3(3), 257–273 (1962)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dierker, E., Dierker, H., Grodal, B.: Nonexistence of constrained efficient equilibria when markets are incomplete. Econometrica 70(3), 1245–1251 (2002)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dierker, E., Dierker, H., Grodal, B.: Are incomplete markets able to achieve minimal efficiency? Econ. Theory 25(1), 75–87 (2005). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-003-0406-z

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dierker, E., Grodal, B.: The price normalization problem in imperfect competition and the objective of the firm. Econ. Theory 14(2), 257–284 (1999). https://doi.org/10.1007/s001990050293

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dréze, J.: Investment under private ownership: optimality, equilibrium and stability. In: Dréze, J. (ed.) Allocation Under Uncertainty: Equilibrium and Optimality. Macmillan, New York (1974)

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Duffie, D.: Security Markets: Stochastic Models. Academic Press Inc, Boston (1988)

    Google Scholar 

  • Ekern, S., Wilson, R.: On the theory of the firm in an economy with incomplete markets. Bell J. Econ. 5, 171–180 (1974)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geanakoplos, J., Polemarchakis, H.: Regularity and constrained suboptimality of competitive allocations when markets are incomplete. In: Heller, W., Ross, R., Starret, D. (eds.) Uncertainty, Information and Communication, Essays in Honor of Kenneth Arrow, vol. 3, pp. 65–95. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge (1986)

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Gollier, C.: The Economics of Risk and Time. The MIT Press, Cambridge (2004)

    Google Scholar 

  • Gretsky, N.E., Ostroy, J.M.: Thick and thin market nonatomic exchange economies. In: Aliprantis, C.D., Burkinshaw, O., Rothman, N.J. (eds.) Advances in Equilibrium Theory. Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems, vol 244. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg (1985)

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, S.J., Hart, O.D.: A theory of competitive equilibrium in stock market economies. Econometrica 47(2), 293–329 (1979)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hart, O.D.: On the existence of equilibrium in a securities model. J. Econ. Theory 9, 293–311 (1974)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hart, O.D.: On shareholder unanimity in large stock market economies. Econometrica 47(5), 1057–1083 (1979)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hildenbrand, W.: Core and Equilibria of a Large Economy. Princeton University Press, Princeton (1974)

    Google Scholar 

  • Kelsey, D., Milne, F.: The existence of equilibrium in incomplete markets and the objective function of the firm. J. Math. Econ. 25, 229–245 (1996)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kimball, M.: Precautionary savings in the small and in the large. Econometrica 58, 53–73 (1990)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kreps, D.: Three essays on capital markets. La Revista Espanola de Economia 4, 111–145 (1987)

    Google Scholar 

  • Leland, H.: Saving and uncertainty: The precautionary demand for saving. Q. J. Econ. 82, 465–473 (1968)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leland, H.: Production theory and the stock market. Bell J. Econ. Manag. Sci. 5, 125–144 (1974)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Magill, M., Quinzii, M.: The Theory of Incomplete Markets. The MIT Press, Cambridge (1996)

    Google Scholar 

  • Magill, M., Quinzii, M., Rochet, J.-C.: A theory of the stakeholder corporation. Econometrica 85(5), 1685–1725 (2015)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Makowski, L.: Competitive stock markets. Rev. Econ. Stud. 50, 305–330 (1983)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostroy, J.M., Zame, W.R.: Nonatomic economies and the boundaries of perfect competition. Econometrica 62(3), 593–633 (1994)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Radner, R.: A note on unanimity of stockholders’ preferences among alternative production plans: a reformulation of the Ekern–Wilson model. Bell J. Econ. 5(1), 181–184 (1974)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rustichini, A., Yannelis, N.: What is perfect competition? In equilibrium theory in infinite dimensional spaces. In: Khan, M., Yannelis, N. (eds.) Studies in Economic Theory, Volume 1 of Equilibrium Theory in Infinite Dimensional Spaces. Studies in Economic Theory. Springer, Berlin (1991)

    Google Scholar 

  • Sandmo, A.: The effect of uncertainty on saving decisions. Rev. Econ. Stud. 37, 353–360 (1970)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon, L., Zame, R.: Discontinuous games with endogenous sharing rules. Econometrica 58, 861–872 (1990)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zierhut, M.: Constrained efficiency versus unanimity in incomplete markets. Econ. Theory 64(1), 23–45 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-016-0968-1

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Camelia Bejan.

Additional information

I thank Beth Allen, Florin Bidian, Edward Schlee, and Jan Werner, as well as two anonymous referees and the Associate Editor for helpful comments and suggestions.

Appendix

Appendix

Lemma 8.1

The economy \(\mathcal {E}_{\mathcal {P}}\) has an equilibrium for every \( \mathcal {P\in }\widehat{\mathcal {F}}\).

Proof

Note first that, using part (iv) of Definition 4.1 and formula (3), the budget constraints (4) can be written, equivalently, as:

$$\begin{aligned}&c_{0}^{i}+q(b^{i}-\delta ^i b^f)+p(r^{i}-\delta ^i \mathbf {1}_N)+v(\theta ^{i}-\delta ^i (1+\theta ^f))=\omega _{0}^{i}+\delta ^{i} y_{0}\nonumber \\&c^{i\mathbf{1}}=\omega ^{i\mathbf{1}}+\delta ^i y^\mathbf{1}+A(b^{i}-\delta ^i b^f)+X(r^{i}-\delta ^i \mathbf {1}_N)+\theta ^f \cdot D(\theta ^{i}-\delta ^i) \nonumber \\&\quad c^{i}\ge 0,\quad \left( b^{i},r^{i},\theta ^{i}\right) \ge -L. \end{aligned}$$
(16)

Therefore, if the firm chooses policy \(\mathcal {P}=\left( y,D,X,b^{f},\theta ^{f}\right) \), having an initial endowment of \(\delta \) shares is equivalent, in terms of generating the same consumption streams, to receiving an additional endowment of goods \(\delta y\) and trading in an economy in which all the \(J+N+1\) securities are in zero net supply. Therefore, the economy \(\mathcal {E}_{\mathcal {P}}\) is equivalent to a standard stock-exchange economy, \(\mathcal {E}_{\mathcal {P}}^{0}\), in which

  1. 1.

    consumers’ endowments of goods are \(\left( \omega ^{i}+\delta ^{i}y\right) _{i\in I}\),

  2. 2.

    asset structure is given by \(\left( A,X,\theta ^f\cdot D\right) ,\)

  3. 3.

    there is no initial endowment of assets,

  4. 4.

    consumers face “personalized” short-sale bounds, \(L^{i,\mathcal {P} }\in \mathbb {R}^{J+N+1}\), given by:

    1. (a)

      \(L_{j}+\delta ^{i}b^{f}\) for every exogenously given security \(A^j\),

    2. (b)

      \(L_{n}+\delta ^{i}\) for every firm-issued security \(X^n,\)

    3. (c)

      \(L_{D}+\delta ^{i}\) for the security \(\theta ^f \cdot D\).

Since \(y\in \widehat{Y}\), every consumer’s endowment of goods in \(\mathcal {E} _{\mathcal {P}}^{0}\) is strictly positive.

The proof of the existence of an equilibrium for \(\mathcal {E}_{\mathcal {P} }^{0}\) is similar to standard general equilibrium existence proofs. The reader is referred to Debreu (1962) and, especially, Geanakoplos and Polemarchakis (1986) for the details.Footnote 19 An important step in the proof is the construction of an appropriate convex and compact price space. For this specification of the model, the set can be defined as follows.

Let \(\lambda _{0}\) be the price of date-0 consumption, expressed in some arbitrary unit of account, and let \(\pi \) be the price vector for the \(J+N+1\) assets (expressed in the same units). Let

$$\begin{aligned} Q:=\left\{ \left( \lambda _{0},\pi \right) \in \mathbb {R} _{+}\times \mathbb {R}^{J+N+1}\mid \exists \lambda \in \mathbb {R}_{+}^{S} \text { s.t. }\pi =\lambda \left( A,X,D\right) \right\} . \end{aligned}$$

If \((\lambda _0, \pi )\) are equilibrium prices for \(\mathcal E^0_{{\mathcal {P}}}\), then \((\lambda _0, \pi )\in Q.\) Clearly, Q is a convex and closed cone. If Q does not contain a full line then there exists a hyperplane \(H\subseteq \mathbb {R}^{J+N+2}\) (of dimension \(J+N+1)\) such that \(0\ne \left( \lambda _{0},\pi \right) \in Q\) if and only if \(\alpha \left( \lambda _{0},\pi \right) \in Q\cap H\) for some \(\alpha >0,\) and \(Q^0:=Q\cap H\) is compact. If Q contains a full line, take H to be half the unit sphere in \(\mathbb {R}^{J+N+2},\) centered at origin and let \(Q^{0}:=Q\cap H\) be the price space. Then \(Q^{0}\) is a convex and compact set (or an acyclic absolute neighborhood retract if H is the half sphere) and the technique used by Geanakoplos and Polemarchakis (1986) can be applied here. \(\square \)

Let \(\widetilde{\prod }^{0}\left( \mathcal {P}\right) \) be the set of normalized (to lie in \(Q^0\)) date-0 consumption and asset equilibrium prices of \(\mathcal {E}_{\mathcal {P}}^{0},\) so that \(\widetilde{\prod }^{0}:\widehat{\mathcal {F}}\rightrightarrows Q^{0}\). Then \( \widetilde{\prod }\left( \mathcal {P}\right) =\left\{ \frac{\pi }{\lambda _{0}} \mid \left( \lambda _{0},\pi \right) \in \widetilde{ \prod }^{0}\left( \mathcal {P}\right) \right\} \).

Lemma 8.2

The equilibrium price correspondence \(\widetilde{\prod }:\widehat{ \mathcal {F}}\rightrightarrows {\mathbb {R}}^{J+N+1}\) is upper hemi-continuous, with compact values.

Proof

It is enough to show that \(\widetilde{\prod }^{0}:\widehat{ \mathcal {F}}\rightrightarrows Q^{0}\) has closed graph. Since \(Q^{0}\) is compact, this implies that \(\widetilde{\prod }^{0}\) is upper hemi-continuous with compact values. On the other hand, since the utility functions of the agents are assumed to be strictly increasing in date-0 consumption, for every \({\mathcal {P}} \in \widehat{{\mathcal {F}}}\) and every \((\lambda _0, \pi )\in \widetilde{\prod }^{0}({\mathcal {P}})\), \(\lambda _0>0\). Thus, if \(\widetilde{\prod }^{0}\) is upper hemi-continuous and compact-valued, \({\mathcal {P}} \mapsto \widetilde{\prod }({\mathcal {P}})\) must be upper hemi-continuous and compact-valued as well.

To prove that \(\widetilde{\prod }^{0}:\widehat{ \mathcal {F}}\rightrightarrows Q^{0}\) has closed graph, notice first that the equilibrium portfolios are bounded, due to the short sale constraints. Let K be a cube in \(\mathbb {R}^{J+N+1},\) large enough so that it contains all the portfolio bounds. Consider the truncated portfolio demands \(Z_{K}^{i}:\widehat{\mathcal {F}}\times Q^{0}\rightrightarrows K.\) Then \(Z_{K}^{i}\) has non-empty, convex and compact values, and it is upper hemi-continuous at every \(\left( \mathcal {P} ,\pi \right) \in \widehat{\mathcal {F}}\times Q^{0}\) with \(\lambda _{0}\left( \omega _{0}+\delta ^{i}y_{0}\right) +\pi L^{i,\mathcal {P}}\ne 0.\)

To overcome the possible discontinuity of the demand at points \(\left( \mathcal {P},\pi \right) \in \widehat{\mathcal {F}}\times Q^{0}\) for which \( \lambda _{0}\left( \omega _{0}+\delta ^{i}y_{0}\right) +\pi L^{i,\mathcal {P} }=0,\) it is enough to construct a smoothed demand correspondence, \(\widehat{Z_{K}^{i}},\) and a quasi-equilibrium as in Debreu (1962). It can be shown that every quasi-equilibrium of \(\mathcal {E}_{\mathcal {P}}^{0}\) is an equilibrium, and that the smoothed demand correspondence is upper hemi-continuous everywhere.

The closed graph property of \(\widetilde{\prod }^{0}\) follows now immediately from the upper hemi-continuity of the smoothed aggregate demand. \(\square \)

Proof of Theorem 6.1

For a given \(\mu \in \mathcal {M}\), let \(\varGamma _{\mu }\) be the normal-form, two-player game defined as follows:

  • The strategy set of each player is

    $$\begin{aligned} \widehat{\mathcal {F}}^{^{\prime }}=\left\{ \mathcal {P=}\left( y,D,X,b^{f},\theta ^{f}\right) \in \widehat{\mathcal {F}}\mid \left( b^{f}, \mathbf {0}_{N},0\right) \in K\right\} , \end{aligned}$$

    where K is a cube in \({\mathbb {R}}^{J+N+1}\) which is large enough to contain all the portfolio bounds.

  • The first player’s payoff function is

    $$\begin{aligned} \varPhi _{\mu }^{1}\left( \mathcal {P}_{1},\mathcal {P}_{2}\right) :=\int _{ \mathcal {M}}\mathcal {V}_{\mathcal {P}_{2}}^{C}\left( \mathcal {P}_{1}\right) \mathrm{d}\mu \left( \varPi \right) . \end{aligned}$$
  • The second player’s payoff function is

    $$\begin{aligned} \varPhi _{\mu }^{2}\left( \mathcal {P}_{1},\mathcal {P}_{2}\right) : =-\left\| \mathcal {P}_{1}-\mathcal {P}_{2}\right\| , \end{aligned}$$

    where \(\left\| \cdot \right\| \) is the Euclidean norm on \(\mathbb {R} ^{2S+SN+J+2}\) (\(\mathcal {P}_{1}\) and \(\mathcal {P}_{2}\) are viewed as \(\left( 2S+SN+J+2\right) \)-dimensional vectors here).

It is easy to see that \(\mathcal {P}\) is an equilibrium production-financial plan consistent with the belief \(\mu \) if and only if \(\left( \mathcal {P,P} \right) \) is a Nash equilibrium of the game \(\varGamma _{\mu }\). Therefore, it is enough to prove that there exists \(\mu \in {\mathcal {M}}\) such that \(\varGamma _\mu \) has a Nash equilibrium. The proof will proceed in two steps.

Step 1: The strategy space \(\widehat{\mathcal {F}} ^{^{\prime }}\) is compact.

I prove first that \(\widehat{Y}\) is compact. Since \(\widehat{Y}\) is a closed subset of \(\mathbb {R}^{S+1},\) it is enough to prove that it is bounded. Suppose it is not. Then, there exists a sequence \(\left( y^{n}\right) _{n}\subseteq \widehat{Y}\) such that \(\left\| y^{n}\right\| >n,\)\(\forall n\ge 1.\) Convexity of \(\widehat{Y}\), together with \(0\in \widehat{Y} \), implies that:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{1}{\left\| y^{n}\right\| }y^{n}+\left( 1-\frac{1}{\left\| y^{n}\right\| }\right) 0\in \widehat{Y},\quad \forall n\ge 1. \end{aligned}$$

Since \(\left\| \frac{1}{\left\| y^{n}\right\| }y^{n}\right\| =1,\) it can assumed, without loss of generality, that \(\frac{1}{\left\| y^{n}\right\| } y^{n}\rightarrow {\hat{y}}\in \mathbb {R}^{S+1},\) with \(\left\| {\hat{y}}\right\| =1.\)\( \widehat{Y}\) closed implies then that \({\hat{y}}\in \widehat{Y}.\)

On the other hand, \(y^{n}\in \widehat{Y}\Longrightarrow y^{n}_s\ge -\min _{i}\frac{\omega _{s}^i}{\delta ^{i}}+\varepsilon \) for every \(s=0,1,\ldots ,S\) and therefore

$$\begin{aligned} \lim _{n\rightarrow \infty }\frac{1}{\left\| y^{n}\right\| }y^{n}\ge -\lim _{n\rightarrow \infty }\frac{\left( -\min _{i}\frac{\omega _{s}^i}{\delta ^{i}}+\varepsilon \right) _{s=0,\ldots ,S} }{\left\| y^{n}\right\| }={\mathbf {0}}_{S+1}. \end{aligned}$$

Since \(Y \cap {\mathbb {R}}^{S+1}_+=\{{\mathbf {0}}_{S+1}\}\), the above inequality implies that \({\hat{y}}={\mathbf {0}}_{S+1},\) which contradicts \(\left\| {\hat{y}}\right\| =1.\) Compactness of \(\widehat{\mathcal {F}}^{^{\prime }}\) follows now immediately from compactness of \( \widehat{Y}\) and K, and the assumption that \(y\longmapsto \mathcal {K}\left( y\right) \) is upper hemi-continuous with compact values.

Step 2: The game \(\varGamma _{\mu }\) has a Nash equilibrium, for some \(\mu \in {\mathcal {M}}\).

I will show that the family of games \(\left( \varGamma _{\mu }\right) _{\mu \in \mathcal {M}}\) induces a “game with endogenous sharing rules” which satisfies all the hypotheses of the main theorem in Simon and Zame (1990).

Define the payoff correspondences \(Q^{1},Q^{2}:\widehat{\mathcal {F}}^{^{\prime }}\times \widehat{\mathcal {F}} ^{^{\prime }}\rightrightarrows \mathbb {R}\) as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} Q^{1}\left( \mathcal {P}_{1},\mathcal {P}_{2}\right):= & {} \left\{ \int _{\mathcal {M} }\mathcal {V}^C_{\mathcal {P}_{2}}\left( \mathcal {P}_{1}\right) \mathrm{d}\mu \left( \varPi \right) \mid \mu \text {{ = rational belief} } \right\} , \\ Q^{2}\left( \mathcal {P}_{1},\mathcal {P}_{2}\right):= & {} -\left\| \mathcal {P}_{1}- \mathcal {P}_{2}\right\| . \end{aligned}$$

The game satisfies the hypotheses of the main theorem in Simon and Zame (1990) if: (a) the strategy sets are compact metric spaces, and (b) correspondences \(Q^{1}\) and \(Q^{2}\) are upper hemi-continuous with compact and convex values. The above conditions are indeed satisfied for the following reasons:

  1. a.

    The strategy space \(\widehat{\mathcal {F}}^{^{\prime }}\) can be organized as a metric space with the distance induced by the Euclidian metric of \(\mathbb {R}^{2S+SN+J+2}.\) According to step 1, \(\widehat{\mathcal {F}}^{^{\prime }}\) is also compact.

  2. b.

    \(Q^{2}\) is a continuous function and thus upper hemi-continuous as a correspondence. Clearly, it has compact and convex values. Upper hemi-continuity of \(Q^{1}\) (as well as compactness of its values) follows from the upper hemi-continuity and compactness of the values of \( \widetilde{\prod }\), together with the continuity of the optimal consumption as a function of prices and endowments. Convexity of values follows from the linearity of the integral with respect to \({\mu }.\)

Therefore, there exists \({\mu }\) such that the game \(\varGamma _{{\mu }}\) has a Nash equilibrium. \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bejan, C. Investment and financing in incomplete markets. Econ Theory 69, 149–182 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-018-1160-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-018-1160-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation