Skip to main content
Log in

“…then came Cisco, and the rest is history”: a ‘history friendly’ model of the Local Area Networking industry

  • Regular Article
  • Published:
Journal of Evolutionary Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We study the role that switching costs, compatibility, and mergers and acquisitions play in influencing the evolution of a multi-market industry. By looking at the case of the Local Area Networking industry, we propose a ‘history friendly model’ to replicate its evolution during the 1990s. Our model explains how a firm can start from a dominant position in one of the existing markets and exploit switching costs and compatibility to enter a new market. Mergers and acquisitions also play an important role as the new market is pioneered by a start-up, which is soon acquired by the dominant incumbent. As a result of the acquisition, the acquiring firm becomes the leader also in the new market.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Malerba et al.(1999) presents a model of the evolution of the computer industry. Other sectors that have been studied using this approach include pharmaceuticals and biotechnology (Malerba and Orsenigo 2002), and the DRAM industry (Kim and Lee 2003).

  2. Existing contributions have provided detailed evidence on the early history of the industry (von Burg 2001) and on the events that have characterized the most recent period especially concerning the optical networking market of the data communication industry (Carpenter et al. 2003).

  3. Multi-protocol routers embody several algorithms and support several communication protocols to deliver data packets intelligently to their destination. Access-routers provide customers with an interface between their end stations and the network.

  4. In a similar move, Cabletron Systems introduced the ‘Spectrum’ network management software.

  5. Again, major competitors did not stand still. 3Com responded with the Superstack and Office Connect line of equipment, the former targeting big users, and the latter customers with smaller networks. Bay Networks and Cabletron Systems marketed an entire new product line: the BayStack and Smartswitch, respectively.

  6. In those cases in which there is a ‘tie’ (i.e., we observe the same probability of mergers for all pairs in a subset of manufacturers), the first pair is formed by the manufactures with the highest indexes associated to each of them. The second pair is composed by the manufactures with the highest indexes associated to each of them, excluding the manufacturers in the first pair and so on. This ‘tie-breaking’ rule is adopted to save on computational time. Since ties basically occur when the probability of mergers is 0, the tie-breaking rule is almost irrelevant.

  7. The assumption that p is exogenous may appear too extreme. Indeed, in most evolutionary models it is common practice to assume that the probability to innovate is endogenous and depends (positively) on previous innovativeness, profits or firm size. While this assumption is made for simplifying purposes, we observe that, from a theoretical view point, incentives for product innovation depend less than process innovation on firm size (Cohen and Klepper 1996).

  8. This particular utility function borrows from Adner and Levinthal (2001), and many others, the idea that consumers differ in their marginal evaluation of quality. Differently from Adner and Levinthal, however, we do not explicitly consider prices. It can be noted, however, that Eq. (5) can be considered as a reduced form of a case where price is determined by a fixed mark-up over cost, and unit cost of production is quadratic in quality.

  9. The exponential rule for representing consumer choices has been often used in models of industrial and market dynamics (Weisbuch et al. 2000).

  10. The values of parameters that remain constant across simulations are reported in the Appendix.

  11. The results on the market shares of the leader firm across periods and markets mirror those just discussed for concentration (see Table S1 in Supplementary Material). For a given scenario, the leader’s shares increase over time in both markets 1 and 2, while the leader in market 3 has a lower share. The impact of switching cost level and compatibility is the same as in the case of concentration.

  12. We also considered the effect of our scenarios on another set of aspects that are relevant for describing the evolution of the LAN industry, namely: the frequency of runs in which the firm that was the first to introduce a product of type 3 was a start-up; the frequency of runs in which the start-up that pioneered a product of type 3 ends up being acquired and/or merged; the frequency of runs in which the start-up that starts the new market becomes the leader of the market. The detailed results of this exercise are available in Table S2 of the Supplementary Material.

  13. See Cowan and Foray (2002) and Tucker (1999) for a detailed discussion of this point.

  14. Within the ‘possible worlds’ view of counterfactuals we find exercises of ‘comparative dynamics’ in which key parameters are varied. Within the ‘branching’ view of counterfactuals, instead, one can include those experiments trying to verify the effect of specific public policies (which can be located in time) on industrial evolution. See the review of Garavaglia (2010), Section 4.2, for a selection of counterfactual exercises implemented in the literature.

  15. The detailed results of this exercise are presented in Table S3 of the Supplementary Material.

  16. The importance of switching costs is also confirmed by an experiment (nor reported here) in which, for each firm, the switching cost parameter was positive with probability 0.5, and null otherwise. Out of 100 simulations, it turns out that 97 % of the times a market leader emerges with positive switching costs in market 1, 94 % of the times in market 2, and 67 % of the times in market 3.

  17. See Table S4 of the Supplementary Material.

  18. It must be highlighted that M&As may not be needed if switching costs are high and compatibility low. In this case, first mover advantages (in a market, then extended to others through ‘system closure’) can be so strong as to lead to dominance without mergers.

  19. See Table S5 of the Supplementary Material.

  20. Fontana and Vezzulli (2015) show that technological leaders in the LAN industry were more likely to be persistent product innovators in their market. However, they do not investigate the relationship between innovation persistence and market leadership.

  21. We also observe that, although the effect is not particularly strong, our results that the presence of demand heterogeneity tends to mitigate market concentration are consistent with some recent works on the dynamics of some industries characterized by the presence of sub-markets and the absence of shake-outs (Klepper and Thompson 2006; Buenstorf and Klepper 2010).

  22. Moreover, based on the original HF exercise, extensions of the model may be used to investigate issues of more general interest. For an example of this strategy, see Garavaglia et al. (2012).

References

  • Adner R, Levinthal D (2001) Demand heterogeneity and technology evolution: implications for product and process innovation. Manag Sci 47(5):611–628

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Agarwal R, Echambadi R, Franco AM, Sarkar MB (2004) Knowledge transfer through inheritance: spin-out generation, development, and survival. Acad Manag J 47(4):501–522

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhaskarabhatla A, Klepper S (2014) Latent submarket dynamics and industry evolution: lessons from the US laser industry. Industrial and Corporate Change, forthcoming

  • Bottazzi G, Dosi G, Rocchetti G (2001) Modes of knowledge accumulation, entry regimes and patterns of industrial evolution. Ind Corp Chang 10(3):609–638

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bresnahan TF, Greenstein S (1999) Technological competition and the structure of the computer industry. J Ind Econ 1–40

  • Buenstorf G, Klepper S (2010) Submarket dynamics and innovation: the case of the US tire industry. Ind Corp Chang 19(5):1563–1587

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carpenter M, Lazonick W, O’Sullivan M (2003) The stock market and innovative capability of the new economy: the optical networking industry. Ind Corp Chang 12(5):963–1034

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen P, Forman C (2006) Can vendors influence switching costs and compatibility in an environment with open standards? MIS Q 30:1–22

    CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Christensen KJ, Haas LC, Noel FE, Strole NC (1995) Local area networks. Evolving from shared to switched access. IBM Syst J 34:347–374

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen W, Klepper S (1996) Firm size and the nature of innovation within industries: the case of process and product R&D. Rev Econ Stat 78(2):232–243

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cowan R, Foray D (2002) Evolutionary economics and the counterfactual threat: on the nature and role of counterfactual history as an empirical tool in economics. J Evol Econ 12(5):539–562

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cowan R, Jonard N, Zimmerman JB (2006) Evolving networks of inventors. J Evol Econ 16:155–174

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doms M (2003) Communications equipment: what has happened to prices? Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, Working Paper n° 15, June

  • Elster J (1978) Logic and society: contradictions and possible worlds. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Fagiolo G, Moneta A, Windrum P (2007) A critical guide to empirical validation of agent-based models in economics: methodologies, procedures, and open problems. Comput Econ 30(3):195–226

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fogel R (1964) Railroads and American economic growth: essays in econometric history. John Hopkins Press, Baltimore

    Google Scholar 

  • Fontana R (2008) Competing technologies and market dominance: standard ‘battles’ in the Local Area Networking industry. Ind Corp Chang 17(6):1205–1238

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fontana R, Nesta L (2006) Product entry in a fast growing industry: the LAN switch market. J Evol Econ 16(1-2):45–64

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fontana R, Nesta L (2009) Product innovation and survival in a high-tech industry. Rev Ind Organ 34(4):287–306

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fontana R, and Vezzulli, A. (2015) An empirical study of technological leadership and persistence in product innovation, mimeo

  • Garavaglia C (2010) Modelling industrial dynamics with “History-friendly” simulations. Struct Chang Econ Dyn 21(4):258–275

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garavaglia C, Malerba F, Orsenigo L, Pezzoni M (2012) Technological regimes and demand structure in the evolution of the pharmaceutical industry. J Evol Econ 22 (4) 4: 677–709

  • Gawer A, Cusumano M (2002) Platform leadership: how intel, microsoft and Cisco drive industry innovation. Harvard University Press, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Jain S (2012) Pragmatic agency in technology standards setting: the case of Ethernet. Res Policy 41(9):1643–1654

    Article  ADS  Google Scholar 

  • Kim C, Lee K (2003) Innovation, technological regimes and organizational selection in industry evolution: a ‘history friendly model’ of the DRAM industry. Ind Corp Chang 12(6):1195–1221

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • King AA, Tucci CL (2002) Incumbent entry into new market niches: the role of experience and managerial choice in the creation of dynamic capabilities. Manag Sci 48(2):171–186

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klepper S (2002) The capabilities of new firms and the evolution of the US automobile industry. Ind Corp Chang 11(4):645–666

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klepper S, Simons KL (2000) Dominance by birthright: entry of prior radio producers and competitive ramifications in the US television receiver industry. Strateg Manag J 21(10-11):997–1016

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klepper S, Thompson P (2006) Submarkets and the evolution of market structure. RAND J Econ 37:861–886

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis D (1973) Counterfactuals. B. Blackwell, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Malerba F (2002) Sectoral systems of innovation and production. Res Policy 31(2):247–264

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malerba F, Orsenigo L (1996) The dynamics and evolution of industries. Ind Corp Chang 5(1):51–87

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malerba F, Orsenigo L (2002) Innovation and market structure in the dynamics of the pharmaceutical industry and biotechnology: towards a history-friendly model. Ind Corp Chang 11(4):667–704

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malerba F, Orsenigo L (2010) User–producer relations, innovation and the evolution of market structures under alternative contractual regimes. Struct Chang Econ Dyn 21(1):26–40

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malerba F, Nelson R, Orsenigo L, Winter S (1999) History friendly models of industry evolution: the computer industry. Ind Corp Chang 1:3–41

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malerba F, Nelson R, Orsenigo L, Winter S (2008) Vertical integration and disintegration of computer firms: a history-friendly model of the coevolution of the computer and semiconductor industries. Ind Corp Chang 17(2):197–231

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayer D, Kenney M (2004) Economic action does not take place in a vacuum: understanding Cisco’s acquisition and development strategy. Ind Innov 11(4):299–325

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller M (1994) Routers: poised to make the transition. Network World, pp 77–94

  • Miller M (1996) Routers take new root. Network World, pp 43–50

  • Nelson R, Winter S (1982) An evolutionary theory of economic change. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.

  • Paulsen E (2001) Inside Cisco. The real story of sustained M&A growth. Wiley and Sons, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Silverberg G, Verspagen B (1994) Learning, innovation and economic growth. A long run model of industrial dynamics. Ind Corp Chang 3:199–224

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tucker A (1999) Historiographical counterfactuals and historical contingency. Hist Theory 38(2):264–276

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • von Burg U (2001) The triumph of Ethernet. Stanford University Press, Stanford

    Google Scholar 

  • Weisbuch G, Kirman A, Herreiner D (2000) Market organisation and trading relationships. Econ J 110(463):411–436

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Windrum P (2005) Heterogeneous preferences and new innovation cycles in mature industries: the amateur camera industry 1955–1974. Ind Corp Chang 14:1043–1074

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Winter SG, Kaniovski YM, Dosi G (2003) A baseline model of industry evolution. J Evol Econ 13(4):355–383

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

we have greatly benefited from the comments of the editor and two anonymous referees. Shane Greenstein, the late Steven Klepper, William Lazonick, and Franco Malerba commented on a very early version of this paper. Preliminary versions were also presented at the 2006 Schumpeter Society Conference in Nice, at the October 2008 DIME workshop on ‘Demand, Innovation, and Industrial Dynamics’ in Milano, and at a seminar at CIRCLE, Lund University in December 2012. The usual disclaimers apply.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Roberto Fontana.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

ESM 1

(DOCX 26 kb)

Appendix 1

Appendix 1

Table 8 Numerical values for invariant parameters

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Fontana, R., Zirulia, L. “…then came Cisco, and the rest is history”: a ‘history friendly’ model of the Local Area Networking industry. J Evol Econ 25, 875–899 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-015-0422-8

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-015-0422-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation