Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The creative class, its preferences, and unbalanced growth in an urban economy

  • Regular Article
  • Published:
Journal of Evolutionary Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We theoretically analyze unbalanced growth in an urban economy arising from the preferences of the creative class concerning the relative desirability of agricultural, manufacturing, and service goods. We study two cases. In the first case, the production functions for the three categories of goods are identical. Our analysis leads to four results. First, we compute the equilibrium physical to creative capital ratios and the relationships between the neutral productivity shifters and the output prices. Second, we show that agricultural and services consumption are a constant multiple of manufacturing consumption. Third, we note that under certain conditions, an equilibrium in which all sectors of our urban economy grow at a constant rate does not exist. Fourth, we show that a constant growth path (CGP) equilibrium exists in which, across the three sectors, the pattern of consumption changes and there is a reallocation of creative capital. In the second case, the production functions for the three categories of goods are dissimilar. In this more realistic setting, we study generalizations of the previously described four results.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. To the best of our knowledge, the two papers by Batabyal and Nijkamp (2010, 2011) are the only papers in the literature that have shed theoretical light on some of Florida’s ideas. In this regard, the reader should note that the Batabyal and Nijkamp (2010) paper studies the creative capital accumulation decision faced by individuals in a regional economy. In contrast, the Batabyal and Nijkamp (2011) paper analyzes the effects of neutral and non-neutral productivity growth on creative capital in a trading regional economy. The point to note here is that there is no overlap between the questions studied in the above two papers and the questions we analyze in this paper.

  2. See Florida (2002, 2005a, b, 2008) and Anonymous (2011) for additional details on the body of work we have in mind.

  3. Petrov (2007) focuses on Canada and provides empirical support for this stylized fact.

  4. This document was accessed from the world wide web on 17 October 2011. Richard Florida is the director of the Martin Prosperity Institute which is a part of the Rotman School of Management at the University of Toronto.

  5. Structural change in this paper refers to changes in the composition of factor use and of production.

  6. See Deaton and Muellbauer (1980, pp. 60–67) for additional details on the Stone-Geary utility function and the linear expenditure system.

  7. If this urban economy were open then it would be necessary to model other issues explicitly. Some of these issues are discussed in Oladi (2004) and in Beladi and Oladi (2011).

  8. See Aghion and Howitt (2009, p. 22) for a textbook discussion of the Inada conditions.

  9. As noted in Section 1, the case of dissimilar production functions is analyzed in Section 4 of this paper.

  10. See Eq. 1 and recall the Section 1 discussion about the three stylized facts concerning the creative class in cities.

  11. Supply side forces can also lead to unbalanced growth in an urban economy of the sort we are analyzing in this paper.

References

  • Acemoglu D (2009) Introduction to modern economic growth. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ

    Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Howitt P (2009) The economics of growth. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Andersen KV, Hansen HK, Isaksen A, Raunio M (2010) Nordic city regions in the creative class debate—putting the creative class thesis to a test. Ind Innovat 17:215–240

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anonymous (2011) The rise of the creative class, since 1800, Martin Prosperity Insights, Rotman School of Management, University of Toronto, March 16. Accessed from the World Wide Web on 17 October 2011

  • Batabyal AA, Nijkamp P (2010) Richard Florida’s creative capital in a trading regional economy: a theoretical investigation. Ann Reg Sci 44:241–250

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Batabyal AA, Nijkamp P (2011) The impact of neutral and non-neutral productivity growth on creative capital in a trading regional economy. Geogr Anal 43:61–77

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beladi H, Oladi R (2011) An elementary proposition on technical progress and non-traded goods. J Math Econ 47:68–71

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Comunian R, Faggian A, Li QC (2010) Unrewarded careers in the creative class: the strange case of bohemian graduates. Pap Reg Sci 89:389–410

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deaton AS, Muellbauer J (1980) Economics and consumer behavior. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Donegan M, Lowe N (2008) Inequality in the creative city: Is there still a place for ‘oldfashioned’ institutions? Econ Dev Q 22:46–62

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Florida R (2002) The rise of the creative class. Basic Books, New York, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Florida R (2005a) The flight of the creative class. HarperCollins Publishers, New York, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Florida R (2005b) Cities and the creative class. Routledge, New York, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Florida R (2008) Who’s your city? Basic Books, New York, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones CI (2002) Introduction to economic growth, 2nd edn. Norton, New York, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Kongsamut P, Rebelo S, Xie D (2001) Beyond balanced growth. Rev Econ Stud 68:869–882

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lorenzen M, Andersen KV (2009) Centrality and creativity: does Richard Florida’s creative class offer new insights into urban hierarchy? Econ Geogr 85:363–390

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markusen A (2006) Urban development and the politics of a creative class: evidence from a study of artists. Environ Plann A 38:1921–1940

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marlet G, Van Woerkens C (2007) The Dutch creative class and how it fosters urban employment growth. Urban Stud 44:2605–2626

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McGranahan D, Wojan T (2007) Recasting the creative class to examine growth processes in rural and urban counties. Reg Stud 41:197–216

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oladi R (2004) Strategic quotas on foreign investment and migration. Econ Theor 24:289–306

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olfert MR, Partridge M (2011) Creating the cultural community: ethnic diversity vs. agglomeration. Spatial Econ Anal 6:25–55

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peters M, Simsek A (2009) Solutions manual for introduction to modern economic growth. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ

    Google Scholar 

  • Petrov AN (2007) A look beyond the metropolis: exploring creative class in the Canadian periphery. Can J Reg Sci 30:451–474

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

For their helpful comments on an earlier version of this paper, we thank (i) the Editor Luigi Orsenigo, (ii) an anonymous referee, (iii) participants in the “Complex City” workshop in Amsterdam, The Netherlands in December 2011, and (iv) participants in a session at the annual meeting of the Southern Regional Science Association in Charlotte, North Carolina in March 2012. In addition, Batabyal acknowledges financial support from the Gosnell endowment at RIT. The usual disclaimer applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Amitrajeet A. Batabyal.

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of Theorem 1

We begin by claiming that if the condition α A/B A = α S/B S is not satisfied then a CGP equilibrium in our urban economy does not exist. To this end, consider a CGP equilibrium in which c M(t) grows at the constant rate β c after some time T. From the consumption Euler equation (20), we deduce that \(k\left( t \right)=k^{\ast} =\left( {f^l} \right)^{-1}\left\{ {\left( {\theta \beta_c +\rho } \right)/B^M} \right\}\) is constant ∀ t ≥ T. Then the constraint (21) at any time t ≥ T can be expressed as

$$ B^Mf\left( {k^{\ast} } \right)-\left( {\zeta +\beta } \right)k^{\ast} =\frac{c^M\left( T \right)e^{\left( {\beta_c -\beta } \right)\left( {t-T} \right)}}{\eta^M}+\frac{e^{-\beta \left( {t-T} \right)}}{X\left( T \right)}B^M\left( {\frac{\alpha^A}{B^A}-\frac{\alpha^S}{B^S}} \right). $$
(39)

If β c  > β then the RHS of Eq. 39 exceeds the LHS for sufficiently large t and this leads to a contradiction. On the other hand if β c  < β then the RHS goes to 0 but the LHS is positive which again leads to a contradiction. From this it is clear that we must have β c  = β. In this case, \(\exp \left\{ {-\beta \left( {t-T} \right)} \right\}\left( {\alpha^A/B^A-\alpha^S/B^{S} } \right)\) is constant only if α A/B A = α S/B S = 0, that is, only if the condition α A/B A = α S/B S in Theorem 1 holds. Therefore, we conclude that this last condition is necessary for a CGP equilibrium in our urban economy to exist.

Having demonstrated necessity, we now claim that the Theorem 1 condition is sufficient for a unique CGP to exist. To this end, suppose that the Theorem 1 condition holds. Let the normalized manufacturing consumption be \(\overline c^M\left( t \right)=c^M\left( t \right)/X\left( t \right)\). Then, the differential equation system given by Eqs. 20 and 21 can be written in normalized variables as

$$ \dot{{k}}\left( t \right)+\frac{\overline c^M\left( t \right)}{\eta ^M}=B^Mf\left\{ {k\left( t \right)} \right\}-\left( {\zeta +\beta } \right)k\left( t \right) $$
(40)

and

$$ \frac{d\overline c^M\left( t \right)/dt}{\overline c^M\left( t \right)}=\frac{1}{\theta }\left\{ {B^Mf^{\prime}\left\{ {k\left( t \right)} \right\}-\rho } \right\}-\beta . $$
(41)

The above system (40)–(41) has a unique steady state in which \(\overline c ^M\left( t \right)=\left( {c^M} \right)^{\ast}\) and k(t) = k * are constant and are implicitly defined by

$$ f^{\prime}\left( {k^{\ast} } \right)=\left( {\rho +\theta \beta } \right)/B^M\;\mbox{and}\;\left( {\overline c^M} \right)^\ast =\eta^M\left\{ {B^Mf\left( {k^{\ast}} \right)-\left( {\zeta +\beta } \right)k^{\ast} } \right\}. $$
(42)

In addition, for any k(0), there exists a saddle path \(\left\{ {\overline c ^M\left( t \right),k\left( t \right)} \right\}\), that converges to the steady state. Observe that the corresponding {c M(t), k(t)} t also satisfies the transversality condition in Eq. 22 because we have \(r^{\ast} -\zeta -\beta =\rho -\zeta +\left( {1-\theta } \right)\beta >0\) from assumption 4 in Acemoglu (2009, p. 310). From this it follows that the equilibrium path is saddle path stable in the normalized variables and c M(t) and K(t)/K c (t) grow asymptotically at rate β. In addition, if k(0) = k * then the equilibrium is at the steady state and c M(t) and K(t)/K c (t) grow exactly at rate β. Put differently, a CGP equilibrium exists.□

Proof of Theorem 2

We begin by combining the demand and the supply side equations for our urban economy and then derive the two conditions stated in Theorem 2. Suppose that there exists a CGP equilibrium in which consumption of the manufactured good c M(t) grows at the constant rate β c and the physical capital to effective creative capital ratio k(t) ≡ k * is constant. Then from the consumption Euler Eq. (36), the return to physical capital r(t) ≡ r * is also constant. This last fact and Eq. 32 together tell us that k M(t) ≡ (k M)* and w M(t) ≡ (w M)* are also constant. Because c M(t) grows at rate β c , the resource constraint (35) tells us that \(\beta_{c}=\beta^{M}\) and that the expression \(\alpha^Ap^A\left( t \right)-\alpha^Sp^S\left( t \right)\) is either zero for all time t or grows at the rate β M. Now, using Eqs. 30 and 31, we can write the last expression above as

$$ \begin{array}{rll} \alpha^Ap^A\left( t \right)-\alpha^Sp^S\left( t \right)&=&\alpha^A\chi ^A\left( {r^\ast } \right)^{\omega^A}\left( {w_\ast^M } \right)^{1-\omega ^A}\left\{ {\frac{B^M\left( t \right)}{B^A\left( t \right)}} \right\}^{1-\omega^A}\\&&- \ \alpha^S\chi^S\left( {r^\ast } \right)^{\omega ^S}\left( {w_\ast^M } \right)^{1-\omega^S}\left\{ {\frac{B^M\left( t \right)}{B^S\left( t \right)}} \right\}^{1-\omega^S}. \end{array} $$
(43)

Since the growth rates of the terms \(\{ {B^M( t )/B^A( t )} \}^{1-\omega^A}\) and \(\{ B^M( t )/B^S( t ) \}^{1-\omega^S}\) are strictly less than β M, the expression \(\alpha^Ap^A( t )-\alpha ^Sp^S\left( t \right)\) cannot grow at the rate β M and this tells us that this growth rate must be zero for all time t. This last finding has two implications. First, Eq. 43 implies that the terms \(\{ {B^M( t )/B^A( t )} \}^{1-\omega^A}\) and \(\{ {B^M( t )/B^S( t )} \}^{1-\omega^S}\) must grow at the same rate. Put differently, the growth rates of the creative capital augmenting productivity terms must satisfy the restriction that

$$ \beta^M=\frac{\beta^A\left( {1-\omega^A} \right)-\beta^S\left( {1-\omega ^S} \right)}{\omega^S-\omega^A}. $$
(44)

Second, the initial agricultural and service good prices must satisfy \(\alpha^Ap^A\left( 0 \right)-\alpha^Sp^S\left( 0 \right)\). Substituting for the ratio \(w_\ast^M /r^\ast \) from Eq. 29 into Eq. 43, the previous requirement can be written as

$$ \frac{\alpha^A\chi^A}{\alpha^S\chi^S}=\left\{ {\frac{1-\omega^M}{\omega ^M}\left( {k^M} \right)^\ast } \right\}^{\omega^A-\omega^S}\left\{ {\frac{B^S\left( 0 \right)^{1-\omega^S}B^M\left( 0 \right)^{\omega ^S-\omega^A}}{B^A\left( 0 \right)^{1-\omega^A}}} \right\}. $$
(45)

Note that Eqs. 44 and 45 are the two conditions specified in the statement of Theorem 2 in the body of this paper.

To characterize the ratio \(\left( {k^M} \right)^\ast \) endogenously in terms of the exogenous parameters, observe that the Euler equation implies that r  ∗  = ρ + θβ M. Using this last result in Eq. 32, we see that \(\left( {k^M} \right)^\ast \) satisfies \(\left( {k^M} \right)^\ast =\left\{ {\omega^M/\left( {\rho +\theta B^M} \right)} \right\}^{1/\left( {1-\omega ^M} \right)}\). Substituting this last expression for \(\left( {k^M} \right)^\ast \) in Eq. 45, the second condition on preferences that we seek can be written as

$$ \frac{\alpha^A\chi^A}{\alpha^S\chi^S}=\left[ {\frac{1-\omega^M}{\omega ^M}\left\{ {\frac{\omega^M}{\rho +\theta \beta^M}} \right\}^{1/\left( {1-\omega^M} \right)}} \right]^{\omega^A-\omega^S}\left\{ {\frac{B^S\left( 0 \right)^{1-\omega^S}B^M\left( 0 \right)^{\omega ^S-\omega^A}}{B^A\left( 0 \right)^{1-\omega^A}}} \right\}. $$
(46)

From the above discussion we conclude that if a CGP equilibrium is to exist then the parameters of the model described in Section  4 will need to satisfy the two requirements given in Eqs. 44 and 46. Conversely, when these two requirements hold, it can be seen that the results of Section 3 generalize to this dissimilar production functions case and there exists a CGP equilibrium in which consumption of the manufacturing good c M(t) grows at the constant rate β M.□

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Batabyal, A.A., Nijkamp, P. The creative class, its preferences, and unbalanced growth in an urban economy. J Evol Econ 23, 189–209 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-012-0270-8

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-012-0270-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation