Skip to main content
Log in

Advanced purchasing, spillovers and innovative discovery

  • Regular Article
  • Published:
Journal of Evolutionary Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Advanced product development distinguishes itself by being surrounded by a “cloud of technology spillovers” available to external users in proportion to their competence to commercialize them. The local capacity to commercialize spillovers is experience based and hence more narrow than the range of innovations. The cloud will therefore be incompletely explored. While the value of the cloud to society may be greater than the development investment, the value captured by the producer is often not sufficient to make the product development privately profitable. The producer faces the property rights problem of how to charge for the dual product it develops, the product itself and as much as possible for the technology cloud. The public and private customers, however, appreciate the situation differently. While the former appears in the double customer role of being interested in both the product procured and the spillover benefits to society, the latter is not interested in paying for spillovers that only benefit society. Marketing the product, therefore, involves the ability to present a credible case for the economic value to society of the spillovers. To do that, a theory is needed that demonstrates both the user value to the customer, and the entrepreneurial capacity of the economy to commercialize the spillovers. The theoretical argument is illustrated with the case of downstream industrial business formation around Swedish military aircraft industry.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. I define production to cover all value added creation in a firm, including product development. Manufacturing means factory production. Technology, furthermore, is used in the original Greek meaning of knowledge about techniques.

  2. Eliasson (2006) makes such an advanced work environment a unique competitive advantage of the industrial economies over the emerging low wage economies.

  3. For early surveys documenting the magnitudes involved, the related differences between estimated social and private rates of return and the corresponding underinvestment in private R&D, see Mohnen (1996), Eliasson (1997), Jones and Williams (1998).

  4. Mellander and Ysander (1990) use a similar method when they estimate productivity in a service sector without having access to output data. The key is the assumptions they make about the production system, that is specified such that the model has a unique neoclassical external equilibrium.

  5. For the nice mathematics behind this, see Jones (1995) and Jones and Williams (1998)

  6. See further Eliasson (2010, Technical Supplement S2).

  7. Or today, perhaps, rather the “Chinese way”.

  8. Competence bloc theory was conceived during my extensive interaction with industry people when working on Eliasson (1995), and together with my daughter on Eliasson and Eliasson (1996), where it was also first formulated. The currently most complete presentations can be found in Eliasson (2005:Ch I), Eliasson and Eliasson (2005, 2009). There is not space here to explain how a Schumpeterian type creative destruction process results in economic growth and ultimately determines the spillover multiplier. For that, see Eliasson (1996a:37ff). This is also the way endogenous growth occurs in the Swedish micro (firm) to macro model (Ballot and Taymaz 1998; Eliasson 1977, 1991a; Eliasson et al. 2004, 2005) that I use to explain how to aggregate dynamically from micro spillover cases to macro.

  9. As argued by Day (1986), this latter interdependence of demand and supply poses difficult methodological problems in economic theory.

  10. Again, to anticipate the innovation policy discussion below, there will always be a general policy argument for supporting the development of local commercialization/receiver competence to capture spillovers from public and private procurement. It is more difficult to argue generally for more advanced public purchasing, since it means arguing for a large public sector and it is by no means clear that the public purchaser is more competent as a customer than is the corresponding private one. Only if the market is not responding to a private demand, or if the product is a clear public good, will there be a rational argument for a representative public customer to step in, for instance in defense procurement. We leave this difficult issue at that here.

  11. A technical definition of the innovator makes most economic sense. It has its origin in von Mises (1949). On this, I prefer to think in terms of innovations as being generated by a technology system (Carlsson 1995) or a technology production function (Griliches 1979, 1984, 1986).

  12. cf the Griliches (1969) proposition about, and Gunnarson’s et al. (2004) results on a capital-skill complementarity.

References

  • Adams JD (2001) Comparative localization of academic and industrial spillovers, NBER Working Paper Nr 8292. NBER, Cambridge

  • Arrow KJ (1962) The economic implications of learning by doing. Rev Econ Stud 29(3):155–173

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ballot G, Taymaz E (1998) Human capital, technological lock-in and evolutionary dynamics. In: Eliasson G, Green CH (eds) The micro foundation of economic growth. University of Michigan Press, pp 301–330

  • Bernstein JI, Mohnen P (1994) International R&D spillovers between US and Japanese R&D intensive sectors. Working Paper No. 4682. NBER, Cambridge

  • Bernstein JI, Yan X (1995) International R&D spillovers between Canadian and Japanese industries. NBER Working Papers, Nr 5401. NBER, Cambridge

  • Braunerhjelm P, Feldman M (2006) Cluster genesis—the origin and emergence of technology-based economic development. Oxford University Press Burenstam-Linder, London, Staffan, 1961. An Essay on Trade and Transformation. Uppsala

  • Carlsson BO (ed) (1995) Technological systems and economic performance: the case of factory automation. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Caseli F, Wilson D (2003) Importing technology, NBER Working Paper Nr 9928. NBER, Cambridge

  • Cohen WM, Levinthal DA (1990) Absorptive capacity: a new perspective on learning and innovation. Adm Sci Q 35:128–152

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Day RH (1986) On endogenous preferences and adaptive economizing. In: Day RH, Eliasson G (eds) The dynamics of market economies. IUI, Stockholm and North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp 153–170

    Google Scholar 

  • Denison EF (1961) The sources of economic growth in the United States. Committee for Economic Development, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Denison EF (1967) Why growth rates differ. The Brookings Institution, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • Denison EF (1979) Accounting for slower economic growth: the United States in the 1970s. Basil Blackwell, New York, pp 48–89

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson G (1977) Competition and market processes in a simulation model of the Swedish economy. Am Econ Rev 67(1):277–281

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson G (1986) Kunskap, information och tjänster—en studie av svenska industriföretag (Knowledge, information and service production—a study of Swedish manufacturing firms). IUI, Stockholm

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson G (1990) The firm as a competent team. J Econ Behav Organ 13(3):275–298

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson G (1991a) Modeling the experimentally organized economy. J Econ Behav Organ 16(12):153–182

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson G (1991b) The international firm: a vehicle for overcoming barriers to trade and a global intelligence organization diffusing the notion of a nation. In: Mattson L-G, Stymne B (eds) Corporate and industry strategies for Europe. North-Holland, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson G (1995) En teknologigenerator eller ett nationellt prestigeprojekt?—svensk flygindustri (A technology generator or a national prestige project?—Swedish aircraft industry). City University Press, Stockholm

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson G (1996a) The firm, its objectives, its controls and its organization. Kluwer, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson G (1996b) Spillovers, integrated production and the theory of the firm. J Evol Econ 6:125–140

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson G (1997) General purpose technologies, industrial competence blocs and economic growth. In: Carlsson B (ed) Technological systems; cases, analyses, comparisons. Kluwer, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson G (2000) Industrial policy, competence blocs and the role of science in the economic development. J Evol Econ 10:217–241

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson G (ed) (2005) The birth, the life and the death of firms—the role of entreprenurship, creative destruction and conservative institutions in a growing and experimentally organized economy. The Ratio Institute, Stockholm

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson G (2006) From employment to entrepreneurship. J Ind Relat 48(5):633–656

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson G (2007) Entreprenörens roll i tillväxtteorin—en doktrinhistorisk översikt. The role of the Entrepreneur in Growth theory—a survey of economic doctrines), Stockholm: Itps R 2007:005. A opreliminary and revised version in English from 2007 is available

  • Eliasson G (2010) Advanced public procurement as industrial policy—the aircraft industry as a technical university. Springer, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson G, Eliasson Å (1996) The biotechnological competence bloc. Revue d’Economie Industrielle, 78-40, Trimestre

  • Eliasson G, Eliasson Å (2005) The theory of the firm and the markets for strategic acquisitions. In: Cantner U, Dinopoulos E, Lanzilotti RF (eds) Entrepreneurship, the new economy and public policy. Springer, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson G, Eliasson Å (2009) Competence and learning in the experimentally organized economy. In: Bjuggren P-O, Mueller DC (eds) The modern firm, corporate governance and investment, Elgars

  • Eliasson G, Wihlborg C (2003) On the macroeconomic effects of establishing tradability in weak property rights. J Evol Econ 13:607–632

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson G, Johansson D, Taymaz E (2004) Simulating the new economy. Struct Chang Econ Dyn 15(2004):289–314

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson G, Johansson D, Taymaz E (2005) Firm turnover and the rate of macroeconomic growth, Chapter VI. In: Eliasson G (ed) The birth, the life and the death of firms—the role of entrepreneurship, creative destruction and conservative institutions in a growing and experimentally organized economy. The Ratio Institute, Stockholm, pp 305–356

    Google Scholar 

  • Feldman M, Lichtenberg F (1997) The Impact and organization of publicly-funded research and development in the European community, NBER Working Paper Nr 6040. NBER, Cambridge

  • Fors G, Svensson R (2002) R&D and foreign sales in Swedish multinationals: a simultaneous relationship? Res Policy 31:95–107

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenstein SM, Spiller PT (1996) Estimating the welfare effects of digital infrastructure. NBER Working Paper Nr 5770. NBER, Cambridge

  • Griliches Z (1969) Capital–skill complementarity. Rev Econ Stat LI:465–468

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griliches Z (1979) Issues in assessing the contribution of R&D to productivity growth. Bell J Econ 10(1):92–116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griliches Z (1984) R&D patents, and productivity. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Griliches Z (1986) Productivity, R&D and basic research at the firm level in the 1970s. Am Econ Rev 76(1):143–154

    Google Scholar 

  • Gunnarsson G, Mellander E, Savvidou E (2004) Human capital is the key to the IT productivity paradox. IFAU, Uppsala, Working Paper 2004:13

  • Jaffe AB (1989) Real effects of academic research. Am Econ Rev 79(Nr 5, Dec.):957–970

    Google Scholar 

  • JEBO (2007) The whole issue of Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization devoted to academic entreprenurship and organized by Adam Jaffe, Josh Lerner, Scott Stam and Marie Thursby, vol 63

  • Jones CI (1995) R&D based models of economic growth. J Polit Econ 103(4):759–784

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones CI, Williams JC (1998) Measuring the social returns to R&D. Q J Econ 113(4):1119–1135

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jorgenson D, Fraumeni BM (1992) Investment in education and US economic growth. Scand J Econ 94:51–70, Supplement

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jorgenson DW, Griliches Z (1967) ‘The explanation of productivity change. Rev Econ Stud XXXIV(3):249–282

    Google Scholar 

  • Keller W (2001) International technology diffusion, NBER Working Paper No 8573. NBER, Cambridge

  • Kelley MR, Cook CR (1998) The institutional context and manufacturing performance: the case of the U.S. defense industrial network, NBER Working Paper Nr 6460. NBER, Cambridge

  • Klenow PJ, Rodriguez-Clare A (2004) Externalities and growth, NBER Working Paper Nr 11009. NBER, Cambridge

  • Lichtenberg FR (1993) The output contributions of computer equipment and personnel: a firm level analysis, NBER Working Paper Nr. 4540. NBER, Cambridge

  • Lucas RE Jr (1988) On the mechanics of economic development. J Monet Econ 22(1):3–42

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lundberg E (1961) Produktivitet och räntabilitet, Studier i kapitalets betydelse inom svenskt näringsliv. SNS, Stockholm

    Google Scholar 

  • Marshall A (1890) Principles of economics. Macmillan & Company, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Marshall A (1919) Industry and trade. Macmillan & Company, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Mellander E, Ysander B-C (1990) Analyzing productivity and efficiency in the absence of output measures. In: Carlsson H, Larsson B (eds) Problems of the mixed economy. Cooperation, efficiency, and stability. Elsevier Science Publishers B.V., Amsterdam etc

    Google Scholar 

  • Mohnen P (1996) R&D externalities and productivity growth. OECD Sci Technol Rev (STI) 18:39–66

    Google Scholar 

  • Mun S-B, Ishaq Nadiri M (2002) Information technology externalities: empirical evidence from 42 US industries. NBER Working Paper No. 9272. NBER, Cambridge

  • Nadiri I (1978) A dynamic model of research and development expenditure. In: Carlsson B, Eliasson G, Nadiri I (eds) The importance of technology and the permanence of structure in industrial growth. IUI Conference Reports, 1978:2, Stockholm

  • Nadiri I (1993) Innovations and technological spillovers. Working Paper No. 4423. NBER, Cambridge

  • Nelson RR (1986) Institutions supporting technical advance in industry. Am Econ Rev 76:186–189

    Google Scholar 

  • Prescott EC, Boyd JH (1987) Dynamic coalitions: engines of growth. Am Econ Rev Papers and Proceedings 77(2):63–67

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer PM (1986) Increasing returns and long-run growth. J Polit Econ 94(5):1002–1037

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1911) Theorie der Wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung, Dunker und Humblot, Jena. English ed., 1934, The theory of economic development: an inquiry into profits, capital, credit, interest and the business cycle, vol XLVI. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1942) Capitalism, socialism and democracy. Harper & Row, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow RM (1957) Technical change and the aggregate production function. Rev Econ Stud 39:312–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solow RM (1959) Investment and technical progress. In: Arrow K, Karlin S, Suppes P (eds) 1960, Mathematical methods in the social sciences. Stanford University Press, Stanford

    Google Scholar 

  • von Mises L (1949) Human action. Contemporary Books, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Gunnar Eliasson.

Additional information

This paper draws directly on Eliasson (1995), the industrial policy discussion in Eliasson (2000) and later complementary interviews and case analyses.

Earlier versions of parts of this paper have been discussed at a Ratio Institute seminar in Stockholm, at SNF in Bergen, in my seminar at the Rio Conference of the Joseph A. Schumpeter Society 2008 and in a seminar at Case Western Reserve University, Cleveland in 2009. Very useful comments from Carl-Henrik Arvidsson, Ole Bjerrefjord, Pontus Braunerhjelm, Bo Carlsson, Richard Day, Per Heum, Dan Johansson and Nils Karlson are acknowledged.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Eliasson, G. Advanced purchasing, spillovers and innovative discovery. J Evol Econ 21, 121–139 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-010-0194-0

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-010-0194-0

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation