Skip to main content
Log in

The opportunity cost of social relations: On the effectiveness of small worlds

  • Regular Article
  • Published:
Journal of Evolutionary Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The aim of this paper is to extend the theoretical literature on knowledge and network structure by studying the use of social networks as a learning mechanism. The novelty of this approach is suggested by the empirical evidence on informal trading of know-how. In the model, we consider a set of actors who create and diffuse knowledge with the aim of increasing their own personal knowledge. They are located on a lattice (identifying the social space) and are directly connected to a small number of other individuals. We assume that individuals can learn individually or socially, and that individuals choose how to learn on the basis of a cost-benefit comparison. Within this framework, we compare network structures in terms of efficiency and equity. We find that the opportunity cost of using the network affects its optimal structure in terms of aggregate performance and that the small world does not emerge unambiguously as being the most efficient.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. “Given that the amount of time and energy that a given individual has available for trading is limited each is likely to try to maximize the useful yield of his trading” (Carter 1989, p. 157).

  2. The discussion on cliques, structural holes and small worlds can be related to the concept of strong and weak ties (Granovetter 1973), where the strength of a tie depends on a combination of time, emotional intensity, intimacy and reciprocal service. Granovetter’s argument is based on the following assumption: if an individual (say A) has strong ties with other two persons (say B and C), then it is not possible for the tie between B and C to be absent. This assumption, based on some empirical results, has a logical implication: only weak ties can bridge two subsets of the network. “If each person’s close friends know one another, they form a closely knit clique. Individuals are then connected to other cliques through their weak rather than their strong ties. Thus, from an aerial view of social networks, if cliques are connected to one another, it is mainly by weak ties.” (Granovetter 2005, p. 34). Therefore it seems plausible to consider links inside cliques to be strong ties, and links outside cliques (bridging structural holes) as weak ties.

  3. The empirical literature on informal know-how trading often claims that individuals ask for help when they have to solve some technical or practical problem (e.g. which material is better to use). Our representation of a learning episode as the increase of an argument of vector V i (t) can be interpreted as the accumulation of a piece of knowledge that could be useful for the solution of a problem.

  4. In the long run, it is reasonable to assume that decreasing returns in learning prevail, so that the rate at which knowledge is accumulated through individual learning decreases. However, since we intend to model a situation of rapid technological or scientific change, we ignore this issue.

  5. Suppose, for instance, that there are five knowledge categories, α = 0.5 and \( \overline{\beta } = 0.02 \). For agent i, \( V_{{i,1}} {\left( t \right)} = 10 \) and \( V_{{i,k}} {\left( t \right)} = 8 \) for all the other k. For agent j, \( V_{{i,k}} {\left( t \right)} = 8 \) for all k. Total gain from bartering is 1; expected total gain from individual learning is 0.18. In this case, bartering does not occur, even if it is socially desirable. Side-payments are not allowed in this model. Consistent with the empirical evidence, we assume that the agent who gains more from the barter cannot compensate through monetary transfer the agent who gains less.

  6. For instance, Giuliani and Bell (2005) show that firms with more absorptive capacity have more external links. In their paper, absorptive capacity is proxied by education and experience of technical personnel and firms’ R&D intensity. Then, their result can also be interpreted in terms of firms’ capability to provide useful knowledge to their partners.

  7. This parameterization is the same as that adopted in Cowan and Jonard (2004).

  8. In terms of interpreting the time horizon, we note the following. Since each agent has a probability 1/250 to be drawn each period, in expected value every agent will have an opportunity to learn every 250 periods. Then, it is plausible to define this as the basic unit of time. If the empirical counterpart of this basic unit is one week, the time horizon considered will correspond to approximately 8 years.

  9. We ran other numerical experiments, but without any other economic insights than those reported in this paragraph. We also computed confidence intervals for the statistics reported in the paper, but since these turned out to be very small, we omit them from the graph for the sake of readability.

  10. This can be seen in the graphs for the non normalized Herfindhal index, not reported here.

  11. Figure 5 shows that. for high \( \overline{\beta } \), the coefficient of variation of small world increases compared to the coefficient of variation for the regular network; the trade off then presumably will vanish. What we maintain, however, is that, for a significant period of time, such a trade-off exists.

References

  • Allen R (1983) Collective invention. J Econ Behav Organ 4:1–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumol WJ, Blinder AS (2004) Economics: principles and policy. Thompson -South Western

  • Breschi S, Cusmano L (2004) Unveiling the Texture of a European Research Area: emergence of oligarchic networks under EU Framework Programmes. Int J Technol Manag 27:747–772

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burt RS (1992) Structural holes. The social structure of competition. Harvard University Press, Cambridge MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Carter AP (1989) Know-how trading as economic exchange. Res Policy 18:155–163

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen WM, Levinthal DA (1990) Absorptive capacity: a new perspective on learning and innovation. Adm Sci Q 35(1):128–152

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coleman JC (1988) Social capital in the creation of human capital. Am J Sociol 94:95–120

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cowan R, Jonard N (2003a) The dynamics of collective invention. J Econ Behav Organ 52(4):513–532

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cowan R, Jonard N (2003b) The workings of scientific communities. In: Geuna A, Salter A, Steinmueller E (eds) Science and innovation. Rethinking the rationales for funding and governance. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 309–334

    Google Scholar 

  • Cowan R, Jonard N (2004) Network structure and the diffusion of knowledge. J Econ Dyn Control 28(8):1557–1575

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cowan R, David P, Foray D (2000) The explicit economics of knowledge codification and tacitness. Ind Corp Change 9(2):211–253

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cowan R, Jonard N, Zimmermann JB (2002) The joint dynamics of networks and knowledge. In: Cowan R, Jonard N (eds) Heterogeneous agents interactions and economic performance. Lecture notes in economics and mathematical systems 521. Springer, pp 155–174

  • Cowan R, Jonard N, Ozman M (2004a) Knowledge dynamics in a network industry. Technol Forecast Soc Change 71:469–484

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cowan R, Jonard N, Zimmermann JB (2004b) On the creation of networks and knowledge. In: Gallegati M, Kirman A, Marsili M (eds) The complex dynamics of economic interaction. Springer, pp 337–353

  • Dahl M, Pedersen C (2004) Knowledge flows through informal contacts in industrial clusters: Myth or reality? Res Policy 33:1673–1686

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ehrhardt G, Marsili M, Vega-Redondo F (2006) Phenomemological models of socio-economic network dynamics. Phys Rev E 74

  • Fleming L, King C, Juda A (2006) Small worlds and regional innovation. Organization Science forthcoming

  • Gargiulo M, Benassi M (2000) Trapped in your own net: Network cohesion, structural holes, and the adaptation of social capital. Organ Sci 11:183–196

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giuliani E, Bell M (2005) The micro-determinants of meso-level learning and innovation: Evidence from a Chilean wine cluster. Res Policy 34:47–68

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goyal S, Moraga JL, van der Leij M (2006) Economics: An emerging small world? J Polit Econ 114:403–412

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Granovetter M (1973) The strength of weak ties. Am J Sociol 78(6):1360–1380

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Granovetter M (1985) Economic action and social structure: The problem of embeddedness. Am J Sociol 91:481–510

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Granovetter M (2005) The impact of social structure on economic outcomes. J Econ Perspect 19(1):33–50

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kirman A (1998) The economy as an interactive system. In: Arthur WB, Durlauf S, Lane D (eds) The economy as an evolving complex system II. Addison Wesley, Reading, MA, pp 491–531

    Google Scholar 

  • Lundvall B, Johnson B, Andersen ES, Dalum B (2002) National systems of production, innovation and competence building. Res Policy 31(2):213–231

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malerba F (2002) Sectoral systems of innovation and production. Res Policy 31(2):247–264

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milgram S (1967) The small world problem. Psychol Today 2:60–67

    Google Scholar 

  • Morone P, Taylor R (2003) Small world dynamics and the process of knowledge diffusion: The case of the metropolitan area of greater Santiago de Chile. JASSS 7(2)

  • Morone P, Taylor R (2004) Knowledge creation and network properties of face to face interactions. J Evol Econ 14(3):327–351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Powell WW, Koput KW, Smith-Doerr L (1996) Interorganizational collaboration and the locus of innovation: networks of learning in biotechnology. Adm Sci Q 41:116–145

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rogers E (1982) Information exchange and technological innovation. In: Sahal D (ed) The transfer and utilization of technical knowledge. Lexington, Mass, pp 105–123

  • Schrader S (1991) Informal technology transfer between firms: co-operation through information trading. Res Policy 20:153–170

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Uzzi B (1997) Social structure and competition in interfirm networks: the paradox of embeddedness. Adm Sci Q 42:35–67

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Uzzi B, Spiro J (2005) Collaboration and creativity: The small world problem. Am J Sociol 111:447–504

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Verspagen B, Duysters GM (2004) The small worlds of strategic technology alliances. Technovation 24:563–571

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • von Hippel E (1987) Cooperation between rivals: informal know-how trading. Res Policy 16:291–302

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Walker G, Kogut B, Shan W (1997) Social capital, structural holes and the formation of an industry network. Organ Sci 8:109–125

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Watts D, Strogatz SH (1998) Collective dynamics of “small world” networks. Nature 393:440–442

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Lorenzo Zirulia.

Additional information

A previous version of this paper has circulated under the title “Social networks as option and the creation and diffusion of knowledge”. We thank participants in the I-NECK meeting, May 2004, Pompeu Fabra University, Barcelona, the Druid PhD conference, January 2004, Aalborg, and a seminar at GREQAM, Marseille, November, 2005, for useful comments and suggestions. Moreover, we are indebted to two anonymous referees for valuable comments. The usual disclaimers apply.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Cassi, L., Zirulia, L. The opportunity cost of social relations: On the effectiveness of small worlds. J Evol Econ 18, 77–101 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-007-0073-5

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-007-0073-5

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation