Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Driving economic fluctuations in Peru: the role of the terms of trade

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper uses a common trend model, following King et al. (Am Econ Rev 81:819–840, 1991), Mellander et al. (J Appl Econ 7(4):369–394, 1992), and Warne (A common trends model: identification, estimation and inference. Seminar Paper 555, Institute for International Economic Studies, Stockholm University, 1993), to evaluate, for 1994–2015, the role of the terms of trade vis-à-vis domestic productivity in explaining macroeconomic fluctuations in Peru. Our results show that Peru’s macroeconomic aggregates share two common trends: an external one, associated with the evolution of the terms of trade; and a domestic one, linked to the evolution of domestic productivity. The external common trend has a larger impact on private investment and public expenditure than on consumption and output, a result consistent with the role of investment in absorbing income volatility. The permanent terms of trade (foreign) shocks account for most of the volatility in output, consumption, private investment, and public expenditure. This result appears more pronounced as the time horizon approaches the long term.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The cointegration restrictions (see below) determine the number of common trends and the way that the \(y_{t}\) vector is related to these restrictions.

  2. The series have been seasonally adjusted using the Tramo/Seats method developed by Gómez and Maravall (1996). This procedure was carried out for all variables with the exception of the terms of trade.

  3. Castillo and Salas (2010) perform their analysis for the period 1996–2007.

  4. It is important to mention that there may be other channels through which the terms of trade can affect the economy. One is through the balance of payments; i.e., through availability of international reserves, which can affect the real exchange rate. Furthermore, higher terms of trade can improve access of domestic firms to external funding by increasing the availability of collateral they can pledge under the form of future revenues.

  5. In 2011 and 2015 new local and regional authorities took office.

  6. Results are available upon request.

  7. Two dummy variables are used to control for the fall in consumption and private investment, respectively. It is performed to ensure normality in the residuals of private consumption and private investment, which is needed to estimate the VECM by maximum likelihood. All results of the evaluation of residuals are available upon request.

  8. All the restrictions (on all cointegrating vectors) have been imposed and have not been rejected by the data. For example, the first vector imposes long-run restrictions jointly with weak exogeneity of the terms of trade. We obtain \(\chi _{(3)}=6.370\) with a p value of 0.095.

References

  • Aghuiar M, Gopinath G (2007) Emerging markets business cycles: the cycle is the trend. J Political Econ 115:69–102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ahmed S, Murphy R (1994) Money, output and real business cycles in a small open economy. Can J Econ 27:982–993

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker T, Mauro P (2006) Output drops and the shocks that matter. Working Paper 06-172, International Monetary Fund

  • Blattman C, Hwang J, Williamson J (2004) The impact of the terms of trade on economic development in the periphery, 1870–1939: Volatility and secular change. Working Paper 10600, NBER

  • Canova F (2005) The transmission of us shocks to Latin America. J Appl Econ 20:229–251

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Castillo P, Salas J (2010) The terms of trade as drivers of economic fluctuations in developing economies: an empirical study. Technical report (unpublished manuscript)

  • Dancourt O, Mendoza W, Vilcapoma L (1997) Fluctuaciones económicas, shocks externos, Perú 1950–1996. Working Paper 135, Pontificia Universidad Católica del Perú

  • Easterly W, Islam R, Stiglitz J (2001) Shaken and stirred: explaining growth volatility. In: Pleaskovic B, Stern N (eds) Annual world bank conference on development economics 2000. The World Bank, Washington, pp 191–211

    Google Scholar 

  • Elliott G, Rothenberg TJ, Stock JH (1996) Efficient tests for an autoregressive unit root. Econometrica 55:143–159

    Google Scholar 

  • Frankel J (2006) The effect of monetary policy on real commodity prices. Working Paper 12713, NBER

  • Gómez V, Maravall A (1996) Programs tramo (time series regression with arima noise, missing observations and outliers) and seats (signal extraction in arima time series). Working Paper 9628, Bank of Spain

  • Hoffmaister A, Roldós J (1997) Are business cycle different in Asia and Latin America? Working Paper 9, International Monetary Fund

  • Hoffmaister A, Roldós J, Wickman P (1998) Macroeconomic fluctuations in sub-Saharan Africa. IMF Staff Pap 45(1):132–160

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • IMF (2008) World economic outlook. Technical report, International Monetary Fund

  • IMF (2014a) Peru. selected issues paper. IMF Country Report 14/22, International Monetary Fund

  • IMF (2014b) World economic outlook. Recovery strengthens, remains uneven. Technical report, International Monetary Fund

  • Izquierdo A, Romero R, Talvi E (2008) Booms and busts in Latin America: The role of external factors. Working Paper 631, IADB Research Department

  • Johansen S (1991) Estimation and hypothesis testing of cointegration vectors in Gaussian vector autoregressive models. Econometrica 59:1551–1580

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johansen S (1995) Likelihood-based inference in cointegrated vector autoregressive models. Oxford University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Johansen S (1998) Statistical analysis of cointegration vectors. J Econ Dyn Control 12:231–254

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Justiniano A, Preston B (2008) Can structural small open economy models account for the influence of foreign disturbances? Working Paper 14547, NBER

  • King R, Plosser C, Stock JH, Watson M (1991) Stochastic trends and economic fluctuations. Am Econ Rev 81:819–840

    Google Scholar 

  • Kose MA (2002) Explaining business cycles in small open economies: How much do world prices matter? J Int Econ 65:299–327

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kose MA, Riezman R (2001) Trade shocks and macroeconomic fluctuations in Africa. J Dev Econ 65:55–80

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lubik T, Teo W (2005) Do world shocks drive domestic business cycles? Some evidence from structural estimation. Working Paper 522, John Hopkins University

  • Mellander E, Vredin A, Warne A (1992) Stochstic trends and economic fluctuations in a small open economy. J Appl Econ 7(4):369–394

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mendoza E (1995) The terms of trade, the real exchange rate and economic fluctuations. Int Econ Rev 36:101–137

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Misas M, López E, Vásquez D (2003) Tendencias estocásticas comunes y fluctuaciones en la economía Colombiana 1950–2002. Borradores de Economía 275

  • Ng S, Perron P (2001) Lag length selection and the construction of unit roots tests with good size and power. Econometrica 69:1519–1554

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Obstfeld M (1982) Aggregate spending and the terms of trade: Is there a Laursen–Metzler effect? Q J Econ 97(2):251–270

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gonzáles de Olarte E (1996) Inversión privada, crecimiento y ajuste estructural en el Perú, 1950–1995. Working Paper 81, Instituto de Estudios Peruanos

  • Said E, Fuller DA (1984) Testing for unit roots in autoregressive moving average models of unknown order. Biometrika 71:599–607

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stock JH, Watson M (1988) Testing for common trends. J Am Stat Assoc 83:1097–1107

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Svensson L, Razin A (1999) The terms of trade and the current account: the Harberger–Laursen–Metzler effect. J. Political Econ. 91(1):97–125

    Google Scholar 

  • Villanueva Vega P (2013) Inversión privada, inversión pública, términos de intercambio y fluctuaciones en la economía Peruana 1992:1-2007:4. Unpublished Thesis, Pontificia Universidad Católica del Perú

  • Warne A (1993) A common trends model: identification, estimation and inference. Seminar Paper 555, Institute for International Economic Studies, Stockholm University

Download references

Acknowledgements

This paper is drawn from the Thesis of Pierina Villanueva Vega (2013) at the Department of Economics, Pontificia Universidad Católica del Perú (PUCP). Helpful comments and conversations with Oscar Dancourt (PUCP) are especially appreciated. We also thank an anonymous Referee and the Coordinating Editor of the Journal (Professor Robert M. Kunst) for useful comments in order to improve the paper. Any remaining errors are our responsibility.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Gabriel Rodríguez.

Additional information

The points of view expressed in this paper correspond to the author and do not represent those of the Central Reserve Bank of Peru.

Appendices

Appendix

Deriving identification restrictions in a model for a small open economy

In this Appendix we derive a set of equilibrium conditions for identifying the cointegration vectors used in the paper. These restrictions are obtained from a small open economy model where domestic firms export commodities and import investment and consumption goods. Public expenditure, financed with taxes and public debt, is used to provide firms with public goods. Households choose consumption paths optimally.

The commodity-producing sector

Output is produced using a constant-returns-to-scale production function that combines imported capital goods, \(y_{ipri_{t}}\) and public goods, \( y_{gpub_{t}}\), as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} y_{gdp_{t}}=A_{t}y_{ipri_{t}}^{\alpha }y_{gpub_{t}}^{1-\alpha }, \end{aligned}$$
(A.1)

where \(0<\alpha <1\), represents the share of capital goods in domestic output, \(A_{t}\) represents the domestic productivity, \(y_{gdp_{t}}\) is domestic output, \(y_{ipri_{t}}\) is private investment (which we assume as equivalent to capital imported goods), and \(y_{gpub_{t}}\) are public goods provided by the government. The profit function of the typical firm is given by:

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{t}=y_{td_{t}}y_{gdp_{t}}-y_{ipri_{t}}, \end{aligned}$$
(A.2)

where \(y_{td_{t}}\) represents the terms of trade; i.e., the relative price of exports to imports. The efficiency condition that determines the optimal level of investment is given by the following condition, which equates the value of the marginal productivity of capital with its relative price (determined by the inverse of the terms of trade):

$$\begin{aligned} \alpha \frac{y_{gdp_{t}}}{y_{ipri_{t}}}=\left( y_{td_{t}}\right) ^{-1}. \end{aligned}$$
(A.3)

The amount of taxes that firms pay to the government is given by: \( t_{t}=\tau \pi _{t}\), where \(\tau \) represents the average tax rate. The remaining profits are distributed to domestic households.

Household decisions

Households face the following budget constraint:

$$\begin{aligned} y_{c_{t}}+s_{t}=\left( 1-\tau \right) \pi _{t}+s_{t-1}(1+r_{t-1}), \end{aligned}$$
(A.4)

where \(y_{c_{t}}\) denotes consumption, \(s_{t}\) represents household savings, and \(r_{t}\) is the real interest rate that households receive for their savings. Assuming a typical isoelastic utility function, the Euler equation that determines the optimal path for savings is given by:

$$\begin{aligned} 1=E_{t}\left[ \left( \frac{y_{c_{t+1}}}{y_{c_{t}}}\right) ^{-\gamma }\left( 1+r_{t}\right) \right] , \end{aligned}$$
(A.5)

where \(\gamma \) represents the risk aversion coefficient of the representative household.

The government budget constraint

The government faces a budget constraint given by:

$$\begin{aligned} y_{gpub_{t}}-\tau \pi _{t}=d_{t}-d_{t-1}-d_{t-1}r_{t-1}, \end{aligned}$$
(A.6)

where \(d_{t}\) represents government debt.

Balance of payment equation

To derive the balance of payments condition for a small open economy, we apply Walras’ Law and aggregate all the budget constraints in the economy, that is, Eqs. (A.4) and (A.6), respectively:

$$\begin{aligned}&y_{c_{t}}+s_{t} =\left( 1-\tau \right) \pi _{t}+s_{t-1}(1+r_{t-1}), \\&y_{gpub_{t}}-\tau \pi _{t} =d_{t}-d_{t-1}-d_{t-1}r_{t-1}. \end{aligned}$$

Then we obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} y_{c_{t}}+y_{gpub_{t}}+s_{t}=\pi _{t}+\Delta \left( d_{t}-s_{t}\right) -\left( d_{t-1}-s_{t-1}\right) r_{t-1}. \end{aligned}$$
(A.7)

Furthermore, by replacing the definitions of profits (A.2), we obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} y_{c_{t}}+y_{gpub_{t}}+y_{ipri_{t}}=y_{td_{t}}y_{gdp_{t}}+\Delta \left( d_{t}-s_{t}\right) -\left( d_{t-1}-s_{t-1}\right) r_{t-1}. \end{aligned}$$
(A.8)

The final set of equations

We use the following set of key equations to derive the identification restrictions for the common trend model estimated in this paper:

$$\begin{aligned} \alpha y_{td_{t}}y_{gdp_{t}}= & {} y_{ipri_{t}}, \end{aligned}$$
(A.9)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{y_{gpub_{t}}}{y_{td_{t}}y_{gdp_{t}}}-\tau= & {} \frac{ d_{t}-d_{t-1}-d_{t}r_{t-1}}{y_{td_{t}}y_{gdp_{t}}}, \end{aligned}$$
(A.10)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\left( y_{c_{t}}+y_{gpub_{t}}+y_{ipri_{t}}\right) }{ y_{td_{t}}y_{gdp_{t}}}-1= & {} \frac{\Delta \left( d_{t}-s_{t}\right) -\left( d_{t-1}-s_{t-1}\right) r_{t-1}}{y_{td_{t}}y_{gdp_{t}}}. \end{aligned}$$
(A.11)

The first equation is the optimal condition for private investment, which establishes that the value of the marginal product of capital is equal to the inverse of the terms of trade. The second equation is the government deficit as percentage of GDP, and the third equation is the trade deficit as percentage of GDP.

Imposing the conditions that the fiscal deficit and the trade balance, as proportion of GDP, are stationary, and taking logarithms to the efficiency condition for private investment, we obtain the first cointegration relationship in the model:

$$\begin{aligned} \ln y_{ipri_{t}}-\ln \alpha -\ln y_{gdp_{t}}-\ln y_{td_{t}}\sim I(0). \end{aligned}$$
(A.12)

The second condition implies that the \(\frac{y_{gpub_{t}}}{ y_{td_{t}}y_{gdp_{t}}}\) ratio is stationary in the long run, which implies (after taking logarithms) that:

$$\begin{aligned} \ln y_{gpub_{t}}-\ln y_{td_{t}}-\ln y_{gdp_{t}}\sim I(0). \end{aligned}$$
(A.13)

Similarly, if the two previous conditions are satisfied, we obtain that \( \frac{y_{c_{t}}}{y_{td_{t}}y_{gdp_{t}}}\) is also stationary, which (after taking logarithms) implies that:

$$\begin{aligned} \ln y_{c_{t}}-\ln y_{gdp_{t}}-\ln y_{td_{t}}\sim I(0). \end{aligned}$$
(A.14)

Therefore, equations (A.12), (A.13) and (A.14) represent the theoretical support for the three cointegrating vectors used in the paper.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Rodríguez, G., Villanueva Vega, P. & Castillo Bardalez, P. Driving economic fluctuations in Peru: the role of the terms of trade. Empir Econ 55, 1089–1119 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-017-1318-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-017-1318-2

Keywords

Navigation