Skip to main content
Log in

Living arrangement and caregiving expectation: the effect of residential proximity on inter vivos transfer

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Population Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Informal care by adult children provides important support for frail seniors, yet it is unclear whether this costly service is balanced by parents’ financial transfers. This paper examines how family living arrangements affect parents’ relationship with their children. Specifically, it investigates whether a child’s residence affect parents’ decision in making financial gifts, and whether this relationship is based on their expectation to receive care in the future. Results show that children in closer proximity are more likely to receive transfers from their parents on both the intensive and extensive margins. A closer examination of the effects reveals that the difference can be at least partially explained by the increased likelihood of care provision when a child is living in closer proximity. The findings suggest that today’s residential location could be a signal in indicating a child’s prospect of providing care and thus affects parents’ decision in making financial gifts. It also reaffirms the interdependency between caregiving and residential decisions and calls attention to its roles in shaping intergenerational relationship.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Equation 2 can be rearranged as Substitute Eq. 5 into Eq. 1, and Eq. 4 can then be derived.

  2. $$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} T_{i,t} & =& \gamma_{1} \cdot E_{t}(c_{i,t + 1}) + \gamma_{2} \cdot c_{i,t} \\ & = &\gamma_{1} (\beta_{0} + \beta_{1} \cdot E_{t}(d_{i,t + 1}) )+ \gamma_{2} \cdot c_{i,t}\qquad\qquad \text{by Eq.~2}\\ & =& \gamma_{1} \beta_{0} + \gamma_{1} \beta_{1} \alpha \cdot d_{i,t} + \gamma_{2} \cdot c_{i,t} \qquad\qquad\qquad \text{by Eq.~3} \end{array} $$
  3. To obtain Eq. 7, first modify the care function in Eq. 2 to include a variable that could interact with the proximity’s effect on care provision:

    $$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} C_{i,t} &= & \beta_{0} + \beta_{1} d_{i,t} + \beta_{2} g_{i} + \beta_{3} g_{i} d_{i,t} + \epsilon_{i,t} \\ && \beta_{1} \le 0, \; \beta_{2} \ge 0, \; \beta_{3} \le 0 \end{array} $$
    (8)

    In the example, \(g_{i} = 1\) indicates child i is female. The gender difference in providing care is captured by the positive \(\beta _{2}\), and the negative effect of long distance on a child’s ability to provide care is captured by the negative sign for \(\beta _{1}\). However, the total impact of proximity on care provision for female children is modified by β3, which is the differences in the differences of proximity effects between male and female children. Assuming the increases in the likelihood to provide care when a child moves closer is higher for female than male children, I expect \(\beta _{3}\) to be negative.

    Substitute Eq. 8 into 1, and Eq. 7 can then be derived:

    $$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} T_{i,t} & =& \gamma_{1}(\beta_{0} + \beta_{1} E_{t}(d_{i,t + 1}) + \beta_{2} g_{i} + \beta_{3} g_{i} E_{t}(d_{i,t + 1})) + \gamma_{2} c_{i,t} \\ & =& \gamma_{1} \beta_{0} + \gamma_{1} \beta_{2} \cdot g_{i} + \gamma_{1}\alpha(\beta_{1}+\beta_{3} g_{i}) \cdot d_{i,t} + \gamma_{2} \cdot c_{i,t} \end{array} $$
  4. If I factor in the financial transfers from the child in the same period, the net transfer from parents can be negative. However, such cases are rare and do not change the results.

  5. The majority of children (84%) did not receive transfers from parents in a given wave.

References

  • Altonji J G, Hayashi F, Kotlikoff L (2000) The effects of income and wealth on time and money transfers between parents and children. In: Mason A, Tapinos GP (eds) Sharing the wealth: demographic change and economic transfers between generations. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 306–357

  • Arno PS, Levine C, Memmott MM (1999) The economic value of informal caregiving. Health Affairs 18(2):182–188

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrondel L, Masson A (2006) Altruism, exchange or indirect reciprocity: what do the data on family transfers show? In: Serge-Christophe YJ (ed) Handbook on the economics of giving, reciprocity and altruism, chap 14. ISBN: 1574-0714, vol 2. Elsevier, pp 971–1053

  • Barro RJ (1974) Are government bonds net wealth? J Polit Econ 82(6):1095–1117

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS (1974) A theory of social interactions. J Polit Econ 82(6):1063–1093

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Belot M, Ermisch J (2009) Friendship ties and geographical mobility: evidence from Great Britain. J R Stat Soc Ser A Stat Soc 172(2):427–442

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernheim BD, Shleifer A, Summers LH (1985) The strategic bequest motive. J Polit Econ 93(6):1045–1076

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boaz RF, Hu J, Ye Y (1999) The Transfer of resources from middle-aged children to functionally limited elderly parents: providing time, giving money, sharing space. Gerontologist 39(6):648–657. ISSN: 0016-9013

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bonsang E (2009) Does informal care from children to their elderly parents substitute for formal care in Europe? J Health Econ 28(1):143–154

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown M (2006) Informal care and the division of end-of-life transfers. J Hum Resour 41(1):191–219

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox D (1987) Motives for private income transfers. J Polit Econ 95(3):508–546

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cremer H, Roeder K (2017) Rotten spouses, family transfers, and public goods. J Popul Econ 30(1):141–161

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dunn TA, Phillips JW (1997) Do parents divide resources equally among children? Evidence from the AHEAD Survey. Tech. rep. 5

  • Ettner SL (1996) The opportunity costs of elder care. J Hum Resour 31 (1):189–205

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henretta JC, Hill MS, Li W, Soldo BJ, Wolf DA (1997) Selection of children to provide care: the effect of earlier parental transfers. J Gerontol Ser B Psychol Sci Soc Sci 52B(Special):110–119. issn: 1079-5014

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • HRS (2014) Health and Retirement Study, public use dataset. Produced and distributed by the University of Michigan with funding from the National Institute on Aging (grant number NIA U01AG009740). Ann Arbor

  • Hurd MD (2003) Leaving bequests: by accident or by design? Death and dollars. The Brookings Institution Press, Washington, pp 93–118

  • Klimaviciute J, Perelman S, Pestieau P, Schoenmaeckers J (2017) Caring for dependent parents: altruism, exchange or family norm?. J Popul Econ 30 (3):835–873. ISSN: 1432-1475

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Konrad KA, Künemund H, Lommerud KE, Robledo JR (2002) Geography of the family. Am Econ Rev 92(4):981–998

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laferrère A, Wolff FC (2006) Chapter 13 microeconomic models of family transfers. In: Serge-Christophe K, Mercier YJ (eds) Handbook on the economics of giving, reciprocity and altruism. 1574-0714. Elsevier, pp 889–969

  • Laitner JP, Sonnega A (2012) Motives for bequests within the middle class. Michigan Retirement Research Center Research Paper No. 2012-275. ISSN: 1556-5068

  • Latif E (2006) Labour supply effects of informal caregiving in Canada. Can Public Policy/Anal Politiques 32(4):413–429

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee RD (1994) Population age structure, intergenerational transfer, and wealth: a new approach, with applications to the United States. J Hum Resour 29(4):1027–1063. ISSN: 0022166X

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McDonald JF, Moffitt RA (1980) The uses of tobit analysis. Rev Econ Stat 62(2):318–321. ISSN: 00346535

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McGarry K (1998) Caring for the elderly: the role of adult children. In: Wise DA (ed) Inquiries in the economics of aging. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 463–485

  • McGarry K, Schoeni RF (1995) Transfer behavior in the health and retirement study: measurement and the redistribution of resources within the family. J Hum Resour 30:S184–S226. ISSN: 0022166X

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McGarry K, Schoeni RF (1997) Transfer behavior within the family: results from the asset and health dynamics study. J Gerontol Ser B Psychol Sci Soc Sci 52B (Special Issue):82–92

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McGinnis R (1968) A stochastic model of social mobility. Am Sociol Rev 33 (5):712–722. ISSN: 00031224

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • National Alliance for Caregiving (2009) Caregiving in the U.S. Tech. rep. Bethesda

  • Norton EC, Van Houtven CH (2006) Inter-vivos transfers and exchange. South Econ J 73(1):157–172. ISSN: 00384038

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Norton EC, Nicholas LH, Huang SSH (2013) Informal care and inter-vivos transfers: results from the national longitudinal survey of mature women. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper Series No. 18948

  • Pezzin LE, Pollak RA, Schone BS (2007) Efficiency in family bargaining: living arrangements and caregiving decisions of adult children and disabled elderly parents. CESifo Econ Stud 53(1):69–96

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • RAND (2014) RAND HRS data, version N; RAND HRS family data files, version C. Produced by the RAND Center for the Study of Aging, with funding from the National Institute on Aging and the Social Security Administration. Santa Monica

  • Spillman BC, Pezzin LE (2000) Potential and active family caregivers: changing networks and the “sandwich generation”. Milbank Q 78(3):347–374

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Szinovacz ME, Davey A (2007) Division of care among adult children. In: Szinovacz M E, Davey A (eds) Caregiving contexts: cultural, familial, and societal implications. Springer, New York, pp 133–159

  • Szinovacz ME, Davey A (2008) The division of parent care between spouses. Ageing Soc 28(4):571–597

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Terza JV, Basu A, Rathouz PJ (2008) Two-stage residual inclusion estimation: addressing endogeneity in health econometric modeling. J Health Econ 27(3):531–43. ISSN: 0167-6296

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Houtven CH, Norton EC (2004) Informal care and health care use of older adults. J Health Econ 23(6):1159–1180. ISSN: 0167-6296

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Houtven C, Coe NB, Skira M (2010) Effect of informal care on work, wages, and wealth

  • Victorio AG, Arnott RJ (1993) Wealth, bequests and attention. Econ Lett 42(2–3):149–154. ISSN 01651765

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

I would like to express my immense gratitude to Professor Emeritus Neil Bruce, Professor Emeritus Robert D. Plotnick, Professor Jennifer Romich, and Professor Rachel Heath for their guidance during the course of the research. I would also like to thank the anonymous reviewers for sharing their insights on the manuscript and the audiences at several conferences for their comments on an earlier version of the manuscript.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Chien-Hao Fu.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The author declares that he has no conflict of interest.

Additional information

Responsible editor: Alessandro Cigno

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Fu, CH. Living arrangement and caregiving expectation: the effect of residential proximity on inter vivos transfer. J Popul Econ 32, 247–275 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-018-0699-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-018-0699-7

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation