Skip to main content
Log in

Differences in fertility behavior and uncertainty: an economic theory of the minority status hypothesis

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Population Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We revisit the question of why fertility behaviors and educational decisions appear to vary systematically across ethnic groups. We assess the possibility that differences in fertility across groups remain even though their socio-economic characteristics are similar. More specifically, we consider that parents’ fertility decisions are affected by the uncertainty concerning the future economic status of their offspring. We assume that this uncertainty varies across groups and is linked to the size of the group one belongs to. We find theoretical support for the minority status hypothesis according to which members of large minorities usually have a higher fertility than those in the majority facing low potential for social mobility while small minorities have lower fertility.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Number of children ever born to 1,000 women aged 40–44. Source: U.S. Census Bureau.

  2. Source: U.S. Census Bureau.

  3. These differentials become even bigger when we look at the proportion of college graduates or more.

  4. See, for instance, Gordon (1964, 1978), Ryder (1973), Bean and Marcum (1978), Bean and Swicegood (1985), and Trovato (1987) for an exhaustive discussion on the social characteristics hypothesis in sociology.

  5. In a study on Chinese-American women, Espenshade and Ye (1994) explain the lower fertility of this ethnic group with the sacrificial effort in their pursuit of social and economic equality.

  6. This result is not in contradiction with Hondroyiannis (2010) as he documents a negative average effect of aggregate uncertainty on total fertility rates, while we are looking at the heterogeneous effect of uncertainty on completed fertility for different groups. It could perfectly be the case that these heterogeneous effects net out and give a negative overall effect, but this is not the scope of our paper.

  7. See Sly (1970), Roberts and Lee (1974), Jiobu and Marshall (1977), Johnson and Nishida (1980), and Boyd (1994).

  8. Some papers already introduced uncertainty in endogenous fertility models, but, to our knowledge, the uncertainty focuses on the survival rate, never on the expected economic status of children.

  9. We discuss in Section 5 another possible interpretation of our model in which uncertainty arises from the matching process in the marriage market.

  10. The modeling strategy is similar to that of Kalemli-Ozcan (2003), but instead of the survival rate, we take the future wage rate of children as stochastic.

  11. The logarithmic formulation implies that a fixed fraction of parental time (and thus income) is devoted to children, so that consumption is never affected. Furthermore, if the price of well-off children falls (through an increase in the expected wage rate), the relative price of education with respect to childbearing has not changed, which is why the trade-off between quality and quantity of children is not affected by the expected outcome on the labor market and that optimal decisions remain the same.

  12. This feature certainly constrains our results in the sense that we rule out the possibility that, facing a greater risk, parents would decide to decrease their demand for children, but generalizing our model to a less specific utility function would require further research.

  13. See Simon and Warner (1992).

  14. See Bisin and Verdier (2000).

  15. Recall that the Bernoulli distribution yields 1 with some probability p and 0 with probability 1 − p.

  16. Again, thinking the other way around of a poor intragroup outcome and an extragroup match bonus would not change the result. The only crucial assumption is that there should be some variability in the outcome, that is μ s  ≠ μ d .

  17. Given the fact that wages are always positive regardless of the matching outcome so that utility is well-behaved, it is appropriate to use a local approximation like the Delta method.

  18. This mechanism is actually similar to the precautionary demand for children that arises when the survival rate is stochastic as in Kalemli-Ozcan (2003).

  19. Whatever the number of groups, it is noticeable from Eq. 13 that the only way to have a society divided into steady shares is that either one group tends to 1 and all the others to 0, or fertility of the various groups should be equal. In this latter case, the risk term should be the same for all groups and thus they should all be of equal size. We are, thus, able to say that a one-group society or a society divided among groups of equal size are potential steady states. It is, however, very difficult to derive more analytical results with more than two groups.

  20. See Wiggins (1990).

References

  • Bean FD, Marcum JP (1978) Differential fertility and the minority group status hypothesis: an assessment and review. In: Bean FD, Frisbie WP (ed) The demography of racial and ethnic groups. Academic Press, New York, pp 189–211

    Google Scholar 

  • Bean FD, Swicegood GC (1985) Mexican american fertility patterns. University of Texas Press, Austin

    Google Scholar 

  • Bisin A, Verdier T (2000) Beyond the melting pot: cultural transmission, marriage and the evolution of ethnic and religious traits. Q J Econ 115(3):955–988

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyd RL (1994) Educational mobility and the fertility of black and white women. Popul Res Policy Rev 13(3):275–281

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De la Croix D, Doepke M (2003) Inequality and growth: why differential fertility matters. Am Econ Rev 93(4):1091–1113

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De la Croix D, Doepke M (2004) Public versus private education when differential fertility matters. J Dev Econ 73(2):607–629

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doepke M (2005) Child mortality and fertility decline: does the Barro-Becker model fit the facts? J Popul Econ 18(2):337–366

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Espenshade TJ, Ye W (1994) Differential fertility within an ethnic minority: the effect of “Trying Harder” among Chinese-American women. Soc Probl 41(1):97–113

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernàndez R, Fogli A (2006) Fertility: the role of culture and family experience. J Eur Econ Assoc 4(2–3):552–561

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernàndez R, Fogli A (2009) Culture: an empirical investigation of beliefs, work, and fertility. Am Econ J Macroecon 1(1):146–177

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Georgiadis A, Manning A (2011) Change and continuity among minority communities in Britain. J Popul Econ 24(2):541–568

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldscheider C, Uhlenberg PR (1969) Minority group status and fertility. Am J Sociol 74(4):361–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon MM (1964) Assimilation in American life. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Gordon MM (1978) Human nature, class and ethnicity. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Haveman RH, Wolfe B (1995) The determinants of children’s attainments: a review of methods and findings. J Econ Lit 33(4):1829–1878

    Google Scholar 

  • Hondroyiannis G (2010) Fertility determinants and economic uncertainty: an assessment using European panel data. J Fam Econ Issues 31(1):33–50

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jiobu R, Marshall H (1977) Minority status and family size: a comparison of explanations. Popul Stud 31(3):509–517

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson NE, Nishida R (1980) Minority-group status and fertility: a study of Japanese and Chinese in Hawaii and California. Am J Sociol 86(3):496–511

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson WR, Neal DA (1998) Basic skills and the Black-White earnings gap. In: Jencks C, Phillips M (eds) The black-white test score gap. Brookings Institution, Washington DC, pp 480–496

    Google Scholar 

  • Kalemli-Ozcan S (2003) A stochastic model of mortality, fertility, and human capital investment. J Dev Econ 70(1):103–118

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kimball MS (1990) Precautionary saving in the small and in the large. Econometrica 58(1):53–73

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lang K (1986) A language theory of discrimination. Q J Econ 101(2):363–382

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neal DA, Johnson WR (1996) The role of pre-market factors in black-white wage differences. J Polit Econ 104(5):869–895

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ryder NB (1973) Recent trends and group differences in fertility. In: Westoff CF (ed) Toward the end of growth: population in America. Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs, pp 57–68

    Google Scholar 

  • Roberts RE, Lee ES (1974) Minority-group status and fertility revisited. Am J Sociol 80(2):503–523

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon CJ, Warner JT (1992) Matchmaker, matchmaker: the effect of old boy networks on job match quality, earnings, and tenure. J Labor Econ 10(3):306–330

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sly DF (1970) Minority-group status and fertility: an extension of Goldscheider and Uhlenberg. Am J Sociol 76(3):443–459

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Trovato F (1987) A Macrosociological analysis of Native Indian fertility in Canada: 1961, 1971 and 1981. Soc Forces 66(2):463–485

    Google Scholar 

  • Wiggins S (1990) Introduction to applied nonlinear dynamical systems and chaos. Springer, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

Both authors acknowledge the financial support from the Belgian–French-speaking community (Convention ARC 09/14-018 on “Sustainability”) and from the Belgian Federal Government (Grant PAI P6/07 on “Economic Policy and Finance in the Global Economy: Equilibrium Analysis and Social Evaluation”). Paolo Melindi Ghidi also acknowledges financial support from the project “Cultural Assimilation of Ethnic Minorities and Elites”, University of Bologna. This article benefitted from great improvements following comments from Thomas Baudin, Matteo Cervellatti, David de la Croix, Thierry Verdier, Paolo Onofri, as well as participants to the Doctoral Workshop in Economics in Louvain-la-Neuve, Overlapping Generation Days in Vielsam, Summer School in Economic Growth at the Hebrew University in Jerusalem, and macro-lunch seminar at Université catholique de Louvain. We are also grateful to two anonymous referees and editor Alessandro Cigno for valuable comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Bastien Chabé-Ferret.

Additional information

Responsible editor: Alessandro Cigno

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Chabé-Ferret, B., Melindi Ghidi, P. Differences in fertility behavior and uncertainty: an economic theory of the minority status hypothesis. J Popul Econ 26, 887–905 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-012-0434-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-012-0434-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation