Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Scholastic ability vs family background in educational success: evidence from Danish sample survey data

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Population Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This research examines the role of scholastic ability and family background variables in the determination of educational attainment in Denmark. A categorical representation of the highest level of education attained by the individual is the dependent variable. It is analyzed by procedures that take account of the presence of unobservable factors. Parent’s education and occupation, along with an indicator of scholastic ability which is represented by a set of aptitude tests, explain a small but significant portion of the variation in their children’s educational success. Women are shown to respond differently to their environments than men, and including these test scores does not remove the need to deal with unmeasured attributes. On the basis of the available data, family background variables as a group contribute more to the explained variation in the data than the test scores. Finally, credit constraints do not appear to be a factor in educational attainments.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. On page 1155, they write “Our theory incorporates the human capital approach to inequality because parents maximize their utility by choosing optimal investments in the human and non-human capital of children and other members.”

  2. Behrman and Rosenzweig (2002), using twin data, suggest that this result is due to omitted variables correlated with the mother’s education level.

  3. A recent contribution to this literature is an American study based on the Panel Study of Income Dynamics by Conley (2001).

  4. In a novel approach to the problem, Lillard and Willis (1994) treat unobservables in the Mare model by including a random effect. The presence of random effects requires that the higher-stage probabilities be represented by multivariate distributions rather than the product of univariate distributions. Their estimated variance coefficients are highly significant, suggesting that unobservable effects are very important.

  5. This approach is consistent with a dynamic sequential version of the Becker–Tomes model where children maximize their welfare given the parent’s investments. Parents then impose sub-game perfection by maximizing family welfare taking account of their children’s responses.

  6. We know of no studies in this area which impose rationality on the expectation formation mechanism. It is, perhaps, unreasonable even to suggest such a procedure because of the additional complexity involved.

  7. The occupational classification used for fathers is not suitable for mothers because of the small number of women in advanced occupations.

  8. In regression and simple ordered probability models, the t-statistics are identical for the coefficients of a variable x and its normalized value, so that there are no issues of inference involved by using normalized regressors. This is not true for the mixed models estimated here; however, there are no major differences between the two representations.

  9. Simultaneous equation regression models, as well as multivariate count models, were used to explain the three test score variables. Like Neal and Johnson (1996) and Peters and Mullis (1997), we find that household background variables explain a significant proportion of the variation of these variables. These results are described in a companion paper “What Do Test Scores Really Measure?”

  10. Later, we will show that a mixture of two distributions is significantly better than a single distribution function.

  11. This is not what Marks and McMillan (2003) found using an Australian cohort of students who were tested in 1995. There are several possible reasons why this could happen: The first and most important is that we are taking account of the fact that test scores depend on family background variables by adding them as regressors to a model which already contains family background variables. Marks and McMillan do the opposite! Secondly, their measure of educational attainment is “participation at university,” which should be expected to be more dependent on academic ability than our more general measure of educational attainment. They also do not control for unobservables.

  12. See, for example, Cameron and Heckman (1998, 2001), Carniero and Heckman (2001), Heckman (2000), Keane and Wolpin (2001).

  13. Of course, it should be recognized that some children dislike school because they are unhappy or disturbed by problems at home.

  14. Some Danish schools have already adopted procedures to make them more attractive. In their analysis of a sample of Danish elementary schools, Munk and Sloth (2005 p. 11) write “The high-performance schools with low SES in general give priority to social aspects by taking care of the pupils and tackling their difficulties. The schools focus on having a positive approach to and finding the strengths of each individual as well as concentrating on the pupil’s life as a whole. Their goals are to create self-confidence, joy and a unified whole for the children, and also to provide the pupils with the best qualifications possible in view of their background.”

References

  • Arrow KJ, Bowles S, Durlauf S (2000) Meritocracy and economic inequality. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS, Tomes N (1979) An equilibrium theory of the distribution of income and intergenerational mobility. J Polit Econ 87(5):1153–1189

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Behrman JR, Rosenzweig MR (2002) Does increasing women’s schooling raise the schooling of the next generation? Am Econ Rev 92(1):323–334

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Belzil C, Hansen J (2003) Structural estimates of the intergenerational education correlation. J Appl Econ 18(6):679–696

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blau P, Duncan OD (1967) The American occupational structure, New York, John Wiley

  • Bowles S, Gintis H, Osborne M (2001) The determinants of earnings: a behavioral approach. J Econ Lit 39:1137–1176

    Google Scholar 

  • Breen R, Jonsson JO (2000) Analyzing educational careers: a multinomial transition model. Am Sociol Rev 65(5):754–772

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cameron SV, Heckman JJ (1998) Life cycle schooling and dynamic selection bias: models and evidence for five cohorts of American males. J Polit Econ 106(2):262–333

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cameron S, Heckman J (2001) The dynamics of educational attainment for Black, Hispanic, and White males. J Polit Econ 109(3):455–499

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carniero P, Heckman JJ (2001) The evidence on credit constraints in post-secondary schooling. Econ J 112(3):705–734

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Conley D (2001) Capital for college: parental assets and post-secondary schooling. Sociol Educ 74(1):59–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davies R, Heinesen E, Holm A (2002) The relative risk aversion hypothesis of educational choice. J Popul Econ 15(4):683–713

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dearden L (1999) The effects of families and ability on men’s educational attainment in Britain. Labour Econ 6(4):551–567

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dearden L, Machin S, Reed H (1997) Intergenerational mobility in Britain. Econ J 107(440):47–66

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deb P, Trivedi P (1997) Demand For medical care by the elderly: a finite mixture approach. J Appl Econ 12(3):313–336

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ermisch J, Francesconi M (2001) Family matters: impacts of family background on educational attainment. Economica 68(270):137–156

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Featherman DL, Hauser RM (1975) Schooling and achievement in American society. Academic, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Fischer CS, Hout M, Lucas SR, Jankowski MS, Swidler A, Voss K (1996) Inequality by design: cracking the Bell Curve myth. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansen EJ (1995) En generation blev voksen, report 95: 8 (English summary 1996). The Danish National Institute of Social Research, Copenhagen

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansen MN (1997) Social and economic inequality in the educational career: Do the effects of social background characteristics decline? Eur Sociol Rev 13(3):305-320

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansen M, Kreiner S (1996) De kloge og de rige og de dumme og de fattige-en kritisk lae sning af The bell Curve, bogen om den intellektuelle elite. Report 4. University of Copenhagen, Department of Sociology, Copenhagen

    Google Scholar 

  • Haveman R, Wolfe B (1995) The determinants of childrens’ attainments: a review of methods and findings. J Econ Lit 33(4):1829–1878

    Google Scholar 

  • Heckman JJ (2000) Policies to foster human capital. Res Econ 54(1):3–56

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman J, Singer B (1984) A method for minimizing the impact of distributional assumptions in econometric models for duration data. Econometrica 52(2):271–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herrnstein R, Murray C (1994) The Bell Curve. Free Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Keane MP, Wolpin KI (2001) The effect of parental transfers and borrowing constraints on educational attainment. Int Econ Rev 42(4):1051–1103

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Korenman S, Winship C (2000) A re-analysis of the Bell Curve: intelligence, family background, and schooling. In: Arrow KJ, Bowles S, Durlauf S (eds) Meritocracy and economic inequality. Princeton University Press, Princeton, pp 137–178

    Google Scholar 

  • Lauer C (2003) Family background, cohort, and education: a French–German comparison based on a multivariate ordered probit model of educational attainment. Labour Econ 10(2):231–251

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lillard LA, Willis RJ (1994) Intergenerational educational mobility: effects of family and state in Malaysia. J Hum Resour XXIX(4):1127–1166

    Google Scholar 

  • Mare RD (1980) Social background and school continuation decisions. J Am Stat Assoc 75(370):295–305

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mare R (1981) Change and stability in educational stratification. Am Sociol Rev 46(1):72–87

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marks G, McMillan J (2003) Declining inequality? The changing impact of socio-economic background and ability on education in Australia. Br J Sociol 54(4):453–471

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Neal DA, Johnson WR (1996) The role of premarket factors in Black–White wage differences. J Polit Econ 104(5):869–895

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nyborg H (2003) The scientific study of general intelligence. Pergamon, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Nyborg H (1990) Good, bad, and ugly questions about heredity. Behav Brain Sci 13(1):142–143

    Google Scholar 

  • Nørgaard E, Markussen I, Christensen DC (1978) Beskrivelse af officielle og alment accpeterede m/aa ls/ae tninger og undervisningsmetoder i uddannelsessystemets hoveddele 1920–1977. U90, vol 2. Ministry of Education, Copenhagen

    Google Scholar 

  • Peters EH, Mullis NC (1997) The role of family income and sources of income in adolescent achievement. In: Duncan GC, Brooks-Gunn J (eds) Consequences of growing up poor. Russel Sage, New York, pp 340–381

    Google Scholar 

  • Plomin R, Fulker DW, Corley R, DeFries JC (1997) Nature, nurture, and cognitive development from 1 to 16 years: a parent–offspring adoption study. Psychol Sci 8(6):442–447

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shavit Y, Blossfeld H-P (1993) Persistent inequality: changing educational attainment in thirteen countries. Boulder Co, Westview

    Google Scholar 

  • Todd PE, Wolpin KI (2003) On the specification and estimation of the production function for cognitive achievement. Econ J 113(485):F3–F33

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Voung QH (1988) Likelihood ratio tests for model selection and non-nested hypothesis. Econometrica 57(2):307–333

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wedel M, Desarbo WS, Bult JR, Ramaswamy V (1993) A latent class poisson regression model for heterogeneous count data. J Appl Econ 8(4):397–411

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ørum B (1971) Social baggrund, intellektuelt niveau og placering i skolesystemet, Study 20. The Danish National Institute of Social Research, Copenhagen

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

Financial support from the Danish Research Council is gratefully acknowledged. We thank Gøsta Esping-Andersen, Jens Bonke, Claudia Buchman, Else Christensen, Mariah D.R. Evans, Anders Holm, Stephen L. Morgan, Helene Skyt Nielsen, Torben Tranaes, Jørgen Søndergaard, Wout Ultee, Mary Beth Walker, Christopher Winship, and two anonymous referees for comments on earlier versions of the manuscript.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to James McIntosh.

Additional information

Responsible editor: Christian Dustmann

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

McIntosh, J., Munk, M.D. Scholastic ability vs family background in educational success: evidence from Danish sample survey data. J Popul Econ 20, 101–120 (2007). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-006-0061-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-006-0061-3

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation