Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Binge drinking and labor market success: a longitudinal study on young people

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Population Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

An Erratum to this article was published on 08 January 2010

Abstract

This paper presents a two-equation model of joint outcomes on an individual’s decision to binge drink and on his/her annual labor market earnings. The primary data source is the 1979 cohort of the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth (NLSY79), 1979–1994. We show that binge drinking behavior is quite alcohol-price responsive and is a rational addiction. A new result is that an individual’s decision to binge drink has a statistically significant negative effect on his/her earnings. Furthermore, we conducted simulations of the short-run and long-run impacts of increasing the alcohol price. They showed that the tendency for an individual to binge drink heavily is reduced significantly, and the reduction is greater in the long-run than short-run simulation. Also, an individual's annual earnings were increased. However, in the structural model, an individual’s earnings have no significant effect on his/her tendency to engage in binge drinking. Our results contradict earlier findings from cross-section evidence that showed increased alcohol consumption raised an individual’s earnings or wages.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. U.S. per capita consumption of alcohol peaked in 1980–81 and in 1984, the federal government imposed transportation legislation requiring that states wanting federal highway aid must raise their legal minimum drinking age to 21 years.

  2. The NLSY79 asked binge drinking questions only in 1979, 1980, 1983, 1984, 1985, 1988, 1989, and 1992, one half of the years in the 1979–1994 period. Hence, a differences-in-difference model would require discarding a large amount of the available binge drinking data and would preclude testing the rational addiction hypothesis. With a structural model, we can bring all of this data to bear on the parameters in the binge drinking equation, including the hypothesis of rational addiction.

  3. The labor economics literature is mixed in its treatment of the number of children as predetermined and endogenous. Since family size is not the primary focus of this study and the panel data are annual, an individual’s number of children by age group is treated as predetermined.

  4. A good review of the estimation methods for simultaneous equations with limited dependent variables can be found in Amemiya (1974, 1978, and 1979), Lee (1982), and Maddala (1983). We also instrument the lead and lag values of binge drinking because they are endogenous.

  5. The instrumental variable estimation method is similar to the two-stage least square estimation method and the estimation in the first stage is statistically significant. The chi-square statistics for the demand for health, current binge drinking, lag binge drinking, and lead binge drinking in the first stage are 4,838, 9,561, 9,481, and 10,071, respectively.

  6. The R-squared for the local real alcohol price equation is high (0.75), and hence, we do not have a weak correlation between the instrument and the endogenous/stochastic explanatory variable (see Bound et al. 1995). The regression results are available upon request.

  7. The number of groups and boundaries on the categories are, of course, somewhat arbitrary. Compared to binge drinking measures that are continuous, our measure has two advantages. First, we do not force a linear incremental relationship on the severity of binge drinking. Having no occurrences of binge drinking (being in group 1) is much different than binge drinking with one, two, or three occasions per month, but more frequent binge drinking (i.e., three or more times per month) may be very different than lesser values. Second, our measure of binge drinking minimizes the problems of memory lapses—and measurement errors—in those individuals who have a high frequency of binge drinking, e.g., our binge drinking measure treats individuals who report four or more occurrence of binge drinking in the past 30 days equally, rather than needing to accurately distinguish between, for example, four or six or ten occurrences.

  8. Before 1982, the Cost of Living Index only surveyed prices of liquor. Regression analysis is applied to obtain the predicted prices of beer and wine for 1979–1982. We regressed state prices for beer and wine between 1982 and 1996 on state excise tax rates, indicators for geographical regions, and a time trend. The data on state excise tax rates come from the Brewers Almanac.

  9. If the respondents did not live in the same state or the same city in consecutive years, the lead and lag alcohol prices are simply calculated as the average of the pure alcohol prices in the two different cities or states.

  10. The derivation of the price of ethyl alcohol per gallon is as follows: [(beer price per gallon / alcohol content)* consumption share of beer per capita]+[(wine price per gallon / alcohol content) * consumption share of wine per capita]+[(liquor price per gallon / alcohol content) * consumption share of liquor per capita].

  11. This procedure was suggested to us by Wayne Fuller.

  12. Human growth seems to have functional consequences for physical and mental development, health, personality, and personal appearance that have been shown to affect labor productivity and (or) hours of work (Steckel 1995; Fogel 1994; Strauss and Thomas 1998; Biddle and Hamermesh 1998). Also, height (and weight) at early ages have predictive power for the on-set of chronic diseases and premature mortality in middle and late ages (Fogel 1999; Fogel and Costa 1997). Steckel (1995) shows that the average height of US adult, native-born, white males rose steadily for the 75 years before the birth cohort of 1955, but then peaked and declined to 1965, being about 1% below trend in 1965, before starting to increase again.

  13. First stage estimates are available from the authors for all variables that are instrumented.

  14. Some other differences are as follows. In Model 1, the estimated coefficients for HEIGHT and FATHERs ED in the ln EARNINGS equation are negative and significant, but they are positive and significant in Model 2. The latter results seem most plausible. Also, in Model 1, the estimated coefficient of SCHOOLING in the ln EARNINGS equation is 0.06, but is 0.01 in Model 2.

  15. If an individual is living in an urban area, this increases his/her demand for binge drinking, holding the price of alcohol constant, perhaps due to a “wetter” local alcohol culture in urban than rural areas. Also, when an individual is married, his/her demand for binge drinking is reduced, which is consistent with greater personal responsibilities than when he/she is not married.

  16. The details of the derivation are available upon request.

  17. The computations also depend on how quickly the effects of the past and anticipated future values of variables diminish in their impact on the current value of the endogenous variables. The unstable root, 1.93, implies that the effects of anticipated future values of variables are approximately zero after 18 years. The stable root, 0.4, suggests that the effects from past values of variables will approach zero in 10 years. Therefore, the calculation in each year uses the actual values of lead variables for 18 years in the future and the values of lagged variables for 10 years in the past. We impose a stability condition to derive the long-run price elasticities.

References

  • ACCRA Cost of Living Index (1978–1995, various issues). American Chamber of Commerce Researchers Association, Louisville, Kentucky

  • Amemiya T (1974) multivariate regression and simultaneous equation models when thedependent variables are truncated normal. Econometrica 42:999–1012

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amemiya T (1978) The estimation of a simultaneous equation generalized probit model. Econometrica 46:1193–1205

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amemiya T (1979) The estimation of a simultaneous equation tobit model. Int Econ Rev 20:169–181

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barrett GF (2002) The effect of alcohol consumption on earnings. Econ Rec 78(240):79–96

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS, Murphy KM (1988) A theory of rational addiction. J Polit Econ 26:89–106

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS, Grossman M, Murphy KM (1994) An empirical analysis of cigarette addiction. Am Econ Rev 84(3):396–418

    Google Scholar 

  • Berger MC, Leigh JP (1988) The effect of alcohol use on wages. Appl Econ 20:1343–1351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Biddle JE, Hamermesh DS (1998) Beauty, productivity, and discrimination: lawyers’ looks and lucre. J Labor Econ 16(1):172–201

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bound J, Jaeger DA, Baker RM (1995) Problems with instrumental variable estimation when the correlation between instrument and the endogenous explanatory variables is weak. J Am Stat Assoc 90(430):443–450

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brewers Almanac (1978–1995, various issues) U.S. Brewers Association, Washington District of Columbia

  • Card D (1999) The causal effect of education on earnings. In: Ashenfelter O, Card D (eds) Handbook of labor economics, vol 3A. Elsevier, Amsterdam, The Netherlands, pp 1834–1843

    Google Scholar 

  • Center for Human Resource Research (1995a) NLS handbook, 1995. Center for Human Resource Research, Columbus, Ohio

    Google Scholar 

  • Center for Human Resource Research (1995b). NLS user’s guide, 1995. Center for Human Resource Research, Columbus, Ohio

    Google Scholar 

  • Chaloupka FJ (1991) Rational addictive behavior and cigarette smoking. J Polit Econ 99(4):722–742

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Currie J (2000) Child health in developed countries. In: Culyer AJ, Newhouse JP (eds) Handbook of health economics, vol 1B. Elsevier Science, Amsterdam, The Netherlands, pp 1053–1092

    Google Scholar 

  • Efron B, Tibshirani R (1993) An introduction to the bootstrap. Chapman & Hall, New York, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Fogel RW (1994) The relevance of malthus for the study of mortality today: long-run influences on health, morality, labor force participation, and population growth. In: Lindahl-Kiessling Kerstin, Landberg Hans (eds) Population, economic development, and the environment. Oxford University Press, Oxford and New York, pp 231–284

    Google Scholar 

  • Fogel RW (1999) Catching up with the economy. Am Econ Rev 89(1):1–21

    Google Scholar 

  • Fogel RW and Costa DL (1997) A theory of technophysio evolution, with some implications for forecasting population, health care costs, and pension costs. Demography 34(1):49–66

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • French MT and Zarkin GA (1995) Is moderate alcohol use related to wages? Evidence from four worksites. J Health Econ 14:319–344

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greene WH (2003) Econometric analysis, Fifth edn. Prentice Hall, Upper Saddle River, New Jersey

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman M, Markowitz S (1999) Alcohol regulation and violence on college campus. NBER Working Papers No. 6359

  • Grossman M, Chaloupka FJ, Sirtalan I (1995a) An empirical analysis of alcohol addiction: results from monitoring the future panels. NBER Working Papers No. 5200

  • Grossman M, Chaloupka FJ, Brown CC (1995b) The demand for cocaine by young adults: a rational addiction approach. Paper presented at the Pacific Rim Allied Economic Organization Conference, Hong-Kong

  • Gujarati Damodar (1995) Basic econometrics, 3rd edn. McGraw-Hill, Inc., New York, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton B, Hamilton V (1997) Alcohol and earnings: does drinking yield a wage premium? Can J Econ 30(1):135–151

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman J (1976) The common structure of statistical models of truncation, sample selection and limited dependent variables and a simple estimator for such models. Ann Econ Soc Meas 5:475–492

    Google Scholar 

  • Heckman J (1993) What has been learned about labor supply in the past twenty years? Am Econ Rev 83(May):116–121

    Google Scholar 

  • Heien DM (1996) Do drinkers earn less? South Econ J 63(1):60–68

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huffman WE (2001) Human capital: education and agriculture. In: Gardner BL, Rausser GC (eds) Handbook of agricultural economics, vol IA. Elsevier Science, Amsterdam, The Netherlands, pp 333–381

    Google Scholar 

  • Kenkel DS (1996) New estimates of the optimal tax on alcohol. Econ Inq 34:296–319

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kenkel DS, Ribar DC (1994) Alcohol consumption and young adults’ socioeconomic status. Brooking papers on economic activities: microeconomics. Brookings institutions, Washington District of Columbia, pp 119–161

    Google Scholar 

  • Kosman BA, Lachman SP (1993) One nation under God: religion in contemporary american society. Harmony Books, New York, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee LF (1982) Health and wages: a simultaneous equation model with multiple discrete indicators. Int Econ Rev 23(1):199–221

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maddala GS (1983) Limited dependent and qualitative variables in econometrics. Cambridge University Press, New York, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Mullahy J, Sindelar J (1993) Alcoholism, work, and income. J Labor Econ 11(3):494–520

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mullahy J, Sindelar J (1996) Employment, unemployment, and problem drinking. J Health Econ 15:409–434

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • National Council of Alcoholism and Drug Dependence (1990) Estimated cost of alcoholism to business and industry for 1990. U.S. Dept. of Health and Human Services

  • Neal DA, Johnson WR (1996) The role of premarket factors in black-white wage difference. J Polit Econ 104(5):869–895

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson FD, Olson L (1978) Specification and estimation of a simultaneous equation model with limited dependent variables. Int Econ Rev 19:695–710

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pierret C (2005) The national longitudinal survey of youth: 1979 Cohort at 25. Monthly labor review. pp 3–7 Feb

  • Rosenzweig MR, Schultz TP (1991) Who receives medical care? Income, implicit prices, and the distribution of medical services among pregnant women in the United States. J Hum Resour 26(3):473–508

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schultz TP, Tansel A (1997) Wage and labor supply effects of illness in Cote d’Ivoire and Ghana: instrumental variable estimates for days disabled. J Dev Econ 53:251–286

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steckel RH (1995) Stature and the standard of living. Journal of Economic Literature 33(4):1903–1940

    Google Scholar 

  • Strauss J, Thomas D (1998) Health, nutrition, and economic development. Journal of Economic Literature 36(2):766–817

    Google Scholar 

  • The Book of States (1978–1995, various issues). Council of State Governments, Lexington, KY

  • U.S. Department of Health and Human Services (1992) Health United States, 1991. National Center for Health Statistics, Hyattsville, Maryland May

  • U.S. Department of Health and Human Services (1997) Substance abuse and mental health services administrations. National Household Survey on Drug Abuse: Main Findings 1997. Washington, District of Columbia

  • Welch F (1999) In defense of inequality. Am Econ Rev 89(May):1–17

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zabel JE (1998) An analysis of attrition in the panel study of income dynamics and the survey of income and program participation with an application to a model of labor market behavior. J Hum Resour 33(2):479–506

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zarkin G, French M, Morz T, Bray J (1998) Alcohol use and wages: new results from the national household survey on drug abuse. J Health Econ 17:53–68

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ziliak JP, Kniesner TJ (1998). The importance of sample attrition in life cycle labor supply estimation. J Hum Resour 33(2):507–530

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zobeck T, Grant B, Stinson F, Bertolucci Darryl (1994) alcohol involvement in fatal traffic crashes in the United States: 1979–90. Addiction 89(2):227–233

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Shao-Hsun Keng.

Additional information

Responsible editor: Daniel Hamermesh

The authors acknowledge helpful comments and suggestions from Wayne Fuller, Hal Stern, and Peter Orazam and from an anonymous referee and to Daniel Hamermesh, co-editor. They also acknowledge cooperation from the U.S. Department of Labor for access to the NLSY79 panel with geocodes, Agreement # 96–26, and to the Iowa Agriculture and Home Economics Experiment Station for financial assistance

An erratum to this article can be found at http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s00148-009-0302-3

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Keng, SH., Huffman, W.E. Binge drinking and labor market success: a longitudinal study on young people. J Popul Econ 23, 303–322 (2010). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-005-0053-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-005-0053-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation