Skip to main content
Log in

The within-household schooling decision: a study of children in rural Andhra Pradesh

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Population Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Using microdata from a field survey of children in rural Andhra Pradesh, India, we estimate econometric models which aim to identify the key explanatory factors in the decision on schooling. The approach adopted is to focus on the effects of sibling competition within the household, by paying close attention to the number, age and gender of a child's siblings, while also taking account of the characteristics of the household and community. Our findings suggest that the schooling decision depends as much on the child's characteristics and position within the household, as on the circumstances in which the child lives.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Bhalotra and Heady (2004) consider an inter-generational flow of wealth and human capital accumulation through education and work experiences to take account of the dynamic nature of household decision-making. See also Becker and Tomes (1976), Behrman et al. (1982) and Behrman (1988a,b) for household behaviour on intra-household resource allocation (e.g. altruistic, inequality aversion and reinforcing the difference).

  2. Although some literature show that rates of return to female education is higher than those of males (e.g. Todaro 1997; Meier and Rauch 2000), Tilak (1987) reports that the rates for females turn out to be negative when they are adjusted for non-participation in the labour force.

  3. Brides are normally matched with grooms whose educational levels are equal to or higher than theirs. Since grooms with higher educational level are likely to have better-paid jobs, they tend to command higher amounts of dowry. Parents who find it hard to raise money for dowry are reluctant to educate girls. See Debi (2001).

  4. A related theory is that of ‘effective literacy’ which identifies the positive externalities that arise when only some household members are educated (Basu and Foster 1998).

  5. Although this applies to salaried workers whose incomes increase with tenure, it may not apply to waged labourers.

  6. They also present an interesting finding that the effect of birth order on the schooling decision is observed among low-income households, but it decreases among middle- to higher-income households. They attribute this to credit constraints and socio-cultural context as well as to resource constraints (i.e. poverty).

  7. To focus, as we do, on the 5 to 14 age group is consistent with the Constitution of India which stipulates that employment of children below the age of 14 years in hazardous occupations is prohibited and seeks to provide free, compulsory, education for all children up to the age of 14.

  8. Grootaert (1998) states that multi-purpose household surveys, whose original purposes are unrelated to child schooling but which nevertheless contain some relevant information on children, are often the best source of data due to the scarcity of data on children's schooling and work.

  9. It would possible to use a bivariate probit model, as Canagarajah and Coulombe (1997) and Pal (2004) do, to analyse the schooling and work decision simultaneously. However, since in our data set, the numbers of children who both work and attend school and who do neither are very small, the work versus schooling decision is, for practical purposes, a dichotomy, and it is for this reason that we use the simple probit model. For information, when estimating a bivariate probit model for our model 4, the correlation (rho) is estimated as very close to −1.0, confirming the dichotomous nature of the decision and the appropriateness of the univariate approach taken.

  10. Variable set I might be expected to include factors representing a child's innate ability, such as health condition. However, such variables are not included in this study due to non-availability of data.

  11. It is known that school variables have effects on schooling, but these were not used in the analysis due to the lack of variations in the schooling conditions in the sample: All villages have primary schools; the school facilities, such as toilets and drinking water, were mostly not available; the pupil–teacher ratios are not very different; and so on.

  12. Due to missing values, the sample size varies according to the model estimated.

  13. The negative coefficient of the dummy variable sex should be interpreted in conjunction with that of the variable age × sex. The former simply represents the gender difference at age zero. It must also be noted that a quadratic term in age was included during the specification search, but was found not to be significant.

  14. The causes of high drop-out rates for girls are socio-cultural, in addition to the economic causes listed in Section 2. Two examples are early marriage and parents' reluctance to allow girls to travel long distances to school after puberty. See World Bank (1997) and The PROBE Team (1999).

  15. One question we considered was whether it was appropriate for the last-born in a large household to be assigned a higher ‘score’ than the last-born in a small household, as is necessarily the case if birth order itself is used. Using the log of birth order instead is a way of reducing any distortion arising from this. This was tried but did not improve the model according to the AIC.

  16. This statement is also supported by an unreported model in which an interaction term combining the first-born dummy with gender was introduced and found not to be significant.

  17. During the specification search, a dummy variable which distinguishes single-sex from mixed-sex sib-constellations was included, since previous studies have found (see Section 2) that girls with only sisters may be advantaged relative to girls with brothers and sisters. However, this dummy did not show significance.

  18. For example, the schooling probabilities for only-children are the same for a 14-year-old boy and an 8-year-old boy (0.59), while the probabilities are 0.21 for a 14-year-old girl and 0.66 for an 8-year-old girl.

  19. In an attempt to circumvent the endogeneity problems, an instrumental variable estimator was applied due to Newey (1987). The results obtained confirm the results concerning the effects of siblings' schooling status mentioned in the text. Models 4 and this unreported model were also regressed separately for boys and girls. The results suggest that sibling competition takes place first between boys and girls and then within brothers and within sisters. Boys are likely to attend school when they have elder sisters but do not have elder or younger brothers, in particular, school-going brothers. Similarly, girls are likely to attend school when they have elder sisters but do not have younger brothers. Furthermore, they are benefited from having either elder or younger sister who is working. These unreported results are available from the authors upon request.

  20. See Pearson (1998) who reports that daughters work to finance sons' education.

  21. The ‘negative’ teaching effect can be incorporated in the resource dilution effect in this paper, since the issue here relates more to the decision on schooling rather than to a child's performance at school.

  22. Some theoretical models (e.g. Becker 1991) imply that the number of children is an endogenous variable, while some empirical work on schooling decision (e.g. Canagarajah and Coulombe 1997; Morduch 2000) implicitly assumes exogeneity of this variable in the estimation. We follow the latter. Since children do not attend school for the first few years of their lives, it is reasonable to assume that the decision on the number of children is made prior to the schooling decision pertaining to a particular child. Hence, the number of children is pre-determined and can therefore be treated as exogenous (Gujarati 2003).

  23. We have adopted the variable, income group, which divides the sample households by quintiles, rather than the actual amount of income, due to the difficulties involved in the collection of accurate data on income.

  24. See Table A.1 in Appendix for the definition of asset index.

  25. Model 1 uses the variables, educational level and age separately for each parent. In the other models, a single variable is used for each factor for two reasons: these two variables are highly correlated between fathers and mothers; and due to the fact that 35 children are from female-headed households, the use of separate variables entails missing observations and therefore a lower sample size.

  26. The younger the generation, the more likely people are educated.

  27. See Ota (2002) for the supporting evidence.

References

  • Basu K, Foster JE (1998) On measuring literacy. Econ J 108:1733–1749

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS (1991) A treatise on the family. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS, Lewis HG (1973) On the interaction between the quantity and quality of children. J Polit Econ 82(2):279–288

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS, Tomes N (1976) Child endowments and the quantity and quality of children. J Polit Econ 84(2):S143–S162

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Behrman JR (1988a) Nutrition, health, birth-order and seasonality: intrahousehold allocation among children in rural India. J Dev Econ 28(1):43–62

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Behrman JR (1988b) Intra-household allocation of nutrients in rural India: are boys favoured? Do parents exhibit inequality aversion? Oxf Econ Pap 40(1):32–54

    Google Scholar 

  • Behrman JR, Taubman P (1986) Birth-order, schooling and earning. J Labor Econ 4(3):S121–S145

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Behrman JR, Pollak RA, Taubman P (1982) Parental preferences and provision for progeny. J Polit Econ 90(1):52–73

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhalotra S, Heady C (2004) Child farm labour: the wealth paradox. World Bank Econ Rev 17(2):197–229

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhatty K (1998) Educational deprivation in India: a survey of field investigations. Econ Polit Wkly 33(27):1731–1740, 33(28):1858–1869

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhuiya A, Streatfield K (1992) A hazard logit model analysis of covariates of childhood mortality in Matlab, Bangladesh. J Biosoc Sci 24(4):447–462

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Binder M (1998) Family background, gender and schooling in Mexico. J Dev Stud 35(2):54–71

    Google Scholar 

  • Butcher KF, Case A (1994) The effect of sibling sex composition on women's education and earnings. Q J Econ 109(3):531–563

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Canagarajah S, Coulombe H (1997) Child labour and schooling in Ghana. Policy Research Working Paper 1844. World Bank, Washington, DC

  • De Tray DN (1980) On the microeconomics of family behaviour in developing societies. In: Binswanger H, Evenson RE, Florencio CA, White BNF (eds) Rural household studies in Asia. Singapore University Press, Singapore, pp 69–97

    Google Scholar 

  • Debi S (2001) Inequality of access to elementary education in Orissa: an inter- and intra-spatial analysis. In: Vaidyanathan A, Gopinathan Nair PR (eds) Elementary education in rural India: a grassroots view. Sage, New Delhi

    Google Scholar 

  • Drèze J, Kingdon GG (2001) School participation in rural India. Rev Dev Econ 5(1):1–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grootaert C (1998) Child labour in Côte d'Ivoire: incidence and determinants. Policy Research Working Paper 1905. World Bank, Washington, DC

  • Gujarati DN (2003) Basic econometrics, international edition. McGraw-Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Haddad L, Hoddinott J, Alderman H (eds) (1997) Intrahousehold resource allocation in developing countries: models, methods, and policy. Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore, MD

    Google Scholar 

  • Hossain SI (1990) Interrelations between child education, health and family size: evidence from a developing country. Econ Dev Cult Change 38(4):763–781

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kambhampati U, Pal S (2001) Role of parental literacy in explaining gender difference: evidence from child schooling in India. Eur J Dev Res 13:97–119

    Google Scholar 

  • Kanbargi R (ed) (1991) Child labour in the Indian subcontinent: dimensions and implications. Sage, New Delhi

    Google Scholar 

  • Kessler D (1991) Birth-order, family-size, and achievement: family structure and wage determination. J Labor Econ 9(4):413–426

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krishnaji N (2001) Poverty, gender and schooling: a study of two districts in Andhra Pradesh. In: Vaidyanathan A, Gopinathan Nair PR (eds) Elementary education in rural India: a grassroots view. Sage, New Delhi

    Google Scholar 

  • Levy V (1985) Cropping pattern, mechanization, child labour and fertility behaviour in a farming economy: rural Egypt. Econ Dev Cult Change 33(4):777–791

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lieten GK (2000) Children work and education India: general parameters—part I, Field work in 2 UP village—part II. Econ Polit Wkly 35(24):2037–2043, 35(25):2171–2178

    Google Scholar 

  • Lyons B, Matraves C, Moffatt P (2001) Industrial concentration and market integration in the European Union. Economica 68:1–26

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meier GM, Rauch JE (2000) Leading issues, 7th edn. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Morduch J (2000) Sibling rivalry in Africa. Am Econ Rev 90(2):405–409

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mueller E (1984) The value and allocation of time in rural Botswana. J Dev Econ 15:329–360

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newey W (1987) Efficient estimation of limited dependent variable models with endogenous explanatory variables. J Econom 36:231–250

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ota M (2002) Between school and work: children in rural Andhra Pradesh. Unpublished PhD dissertation, University of East Anglia

  • Pal S (2004) How much of the gender difference in child school enrolment can be explained? Evidence from rural India. Bull Econ Res 56:133–158

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parish WL, Willis RJ (1993) Daughters, education and family budgets: Taiwan experiences. J Hum Resour 28(4):863–898

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pearson R (1998) Nimble Fingers' revisited: reflections on women and third world industrialisation in the late 20th century. In: Jackson C, Pearson R (eds) Feminist visions of development: gender, analysis and policy. Routledge, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Psacharopoulos G (1997) Child labour versus educational attainment: some evidence from Latin America. J Popul Econ 10(4):377–386

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Psacharopoulos G, Woodhall M (1985) Education for development: an analysis of investment choices. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Ray R (2000) Analysis of child labour in Peru and Pakistan: a comparative study. J Popul Econ 13(1):3–19

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenzweig MR (1982) Educational subsidy, agricultural development and fertility change. Q J Econ 117(1):67–88

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenzweig MR, Evenson R (1977) Fertility, schooling, and the economic contribution of children in rural India: an econometric analysis. Econometrica 45(5):1065–1079

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenzweig MR, Wolpin KI (1982) Governmental interventions and household behaviour in a developing country. J Dev Econ 10:209–225

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • The PROBE Team (1999) Public report on basic education in India. Oxford University Press, New Delhi

  • Tilak JBG (1987) Economics of inequality in education. Sage/Institute of Economic Growth, New Delhi

    Google Scholar 

  • Todaro MP (1997) Economic development, 6th edn. Longman, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Travis R, Kohli V (1995) The birth-order factor: ordinal position, social strata and educational achievement. J Soc Psychol 135(4):499–507

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vaidyanathan A, Gopinathan Nair PR (eds) (2001) Elementary education in rural India: a grassroots view. Sage, New Delhi

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (1997) Primary education in India. World Bank, Washington, DC

  • Zajonc RB, Markus H, Markus GB (1979) The birth order puzzle. J Pers Soc Psychol 37(8):1325–1341

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are very grateful to the managing editor and two anonymous referees for their useful comments on a previous draft. We are also grateful to Professor Ashok Parikh, Dr. Kunal Sen and Dr. Vegard Iversen for their thoughtful advice.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Masako Ota.

Additional information

Responsible editor: Junsen Zhang

Appendix

Appendix

Table A.1. Definitions, means and standard deviations of variables

Name of variable

Definition

Mean

SD

Sex

1: boy, 0: girl

0.45

0.50

Age

Age of a child in years

9.84

2.67

Sex × age

Interaction term of sex and age

4.32

5.16

Birth order

Birth order of a child: 1, 2, 3... from the eldest (including children of all ages in a household)

2.92

1.47

First-born

1: first-born child, 0: otherwise

0.15

0.35

Mid-born

1: mid-born child, 0: otherwise

0.52

0.50

Last-born

1: last-born child, 0: otherwise

0.31

0.46

Only-child

1: only-child, 0: otherwise

0.03

0.16

No. of elder brothers

Number of elder brothers aged between 5 and 14

0.75

0.85

No. of elder sisters

Number of elder sisters aged between 5 and 14

1.17

1.24

No. of younger brothers

Number of younger brothers aged between 5 and 14

0.47

0.60

No. of younger sisters

Number of younger sisters aged between 5 and 14

0.55

0.77

Household size

Number of household members

6.45

2.06

Household size squared

Square of number of household members

45.78

34.12

No. of children (5–14)

Number of children aged between 5 and 14

3.06

0.94

No. of children (5–14) squared

Square of number of children aged between 5 and 14

10.22

5.72

No. of working adults

Number of working adults in a household

2.39

1.03

No. of working adults squared

Square of number of working adults in a household

6.78

6.18

Infants

1: if infant(s) (aged 0–4) is present, 0: otherwise

0.21

0.41

Infants and the elderly

1: if infant(s) and non-working grandparent(s) are present, 0: otherwise

0.08

0.27

Income group

Quintile income groups (1: the poorest,..., 5: the wealthiest)

3.00

1.16

Asset index

Asset index: sum of point scores given to assets (TV: 4, radio: 1, casette: 1, bike: 1, fun: 1, camera: 1)

1.07

1.80

Land-holding

1: if a household owns land, 0: otherwise

0.49

0.50

Livestock

1: if a household owns livestock, 0: otherwise

0.57

0.50

Room

Number of rooms of a house in which a child lives

1.89

0.97

Education of father

Completed years of schooling for a father

0.48

1.47

Education of mother

Completed years of schooling for a mother

0.17

1.04

Education of household

1: if at least one household member is educated, 0: otherwise

0.33

0.47

Age of father

Age of father

40.95

7.74

Age of mother

Age of mother

33.24

5.69

Age of household head

Age of head

40.31

8.06

SC

1: if a household belongs to scheduled caste, 0: otherwise

0.42

0.49

ST

1: if a household belongs to scheduled tribe, 0: otherwise

0.17

0.38

BC

1: if a household belongs to backward castes, 0: otherwise

0.32

0.47

OC

1: if a household belongs to other castes, 0: otherwise

0.05

0.22

Hindu

1: if a household's religion is Hindu, 0: otherwise

0.82

0.38

Muslim

1: if a household's religion is Muslim, 0: otherwise

0.04

0.20

Christian

1: if a household's religion is Christianity, 0: otherwise

0.13

0.34

Uyyalawada

1: if a child lives in Uyyalawada, 0: otherwise

0.21

0.41

Dhobipet

1: if a child lives in Dhobipet, 0: otherwise

0.17

0.38

Dandu

1: if a child lives in Dandu, 0: otherwise

0.19

0.39

Amdapur

1: if a child lives in Amdapur, 0: otherwise

0.09

0.28

Palapadu

1: if a child lives in Palapadu, 0: otherwise

0.13

0.34

Rajbolaram

1: if a child lives in Rajbolaram, 0: otherwise

0.21

0.41

The numbers of observations are 232 for ‘Education of father’ and ‘Age of father’, 254 for ‘Room’, 265 for ‘Education of mother’ and ‘Age of mother’ and 267 for all of the variables.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Ota, M., Moffatt, P.G. The within-household schooling decision: a study of children in rural Andhra Pradesh. J Popul Econ 20, 223–239 (2007). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-005-0033-z

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-005-0033-z

Keywords

JEL

Navigation