Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The influence of market wages and parental history on child labour and schooling in Egypt

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Population Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper examines the influence of adult market wages and having parents who were child labourers on child labour, when this decision is jointly determined with child schooling, using data from Egypt. The empirical results suggest that low adult market wages are key determinants of child labour; a 10% increase in the illiterate male market wage decreases the probability of child labour by 22% for boys and 13% for girls. The findings also indicate the importance of social norms in the intergenerational persistence of child labour: parents who were child labourers themselves are on average 10% more likely to send their children to work. In addition, higher local regional income inequality increases the likelihood of child labour.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. This accounted for a little less than one fifth of all children between 5 and 14 years old in 2000—ILO (2002).

  2. They find that school enrolment subsidy in Bangladesh increased school attendance but reduced the incidence of child labour by only a small proportion.

  3. The fact that children may be working and going to school at the same time may affect their educational attainment is beyond the scope of this study but is important.

  4. Many educational systems in LDCs are organised into shifts, for example, Bangladesh—Ravallion and Wodon (2000), Peru—Patrinos and Pscaharopoulos (1997) and Egypt—Hanushek and Levy (1993).

  5. Bhalotra and Heady (2003) use community-level variables to instrument household income in rural Ghana and Pakistan. Bhalotra (2001) instruments out household income and child wage and estimates structural labour supply models for rural boys and girls in wage work. She finds a significant negative wage elasticity for boys, whereas the wage elasticity for girls is not significantly different from zero in rural Pakistan. She does not study the impact of adult market wages though.

  6. Rosenzweig and Evenson (1977) provide the basic model in this literature analysing the joint family decision regarding the number of children and children's time allocated to schooling and work and show that Indian families have many children as a result of the high return to the use of child labour.

  7. Diamond and Fayed (1998), using a flexible form production function, show that adult male labour is a complement to child labour, while adult female labour is a substitute to child labour in Egypt.

  8. It is worth noting that this paper provides an alternative explanation for the intergenerational persistence of child labour as compared to what Emerson and Souza (2003) suggested. However, neither paper can provide a definitive test for its suggested explanation.

  9. Swinnerton and Rogers (2000) show that a more equal income distribution can reduce child labour in higher productivity countries but not in low productivity countries. They find supporting empirical evidence using cross-country data and the Gini coefficient as the measure of inequality.

  10. There are 26 governorates/provinces and six regions in Egypt. Four provinces (Cairo, Alexandria, Port Said and Canal Cities) are urban only, while the rest of the provinces are made up of both urban and rural areas.

  11. The 1988 LFSS survey included, for the first time, several individual modules, which collected extensive data on particular aspects, e.g. labour market earnings, migration and child labour. See Fergany (1991) for a detailed discussion on the sampling and questionnaire design of the 1988 LFSS.

  12. The 1988 LFSS adopted the 1982 ILO definition of employment. Hence, unpaid family work is considered economic activity except if it results in goods and services meant entirely for household consumption.

  13. This legislation does not apply to family businesses, domestic work or agriculture. However, the minimum working age is lower than the required age of compulsory education which is 15 years.

  14. Data on the number of working hours and days are only available for 1,154 out of 1,988 working children.

  15. Canagarajah and Coulombe (1997) and Nielsen (1998) also use bivariate probits. However, various other estimation techniques have been used to capture different decision making processes: Patrinos and Psacharopoulos (1997) and Jensen and Nielsen (1997) assume that the two decisions are independent and therefore use logit models; Grootaert (1998) uses a sequential binary probit model where a certain hierarchy of choices is assumed to capture a sequential decision making process.

  16. Since using grouped (aggregated) data in individual level regressions can potentially result in the standard errors being biased because of the correlation of the error term across individuals in a region or industry (Moulton 1990), I correct for the correlation of error terms across individuals within province. In addition, the robust (Huber/White/sandwich) estimator of the variance is used in place of the conventional Maximum Likelihood Estimation variance estimator.

  17. Market wages are calculated using the 1988 LFSS earnings module, which was conducted on a sample of 15,000 workers. Relative wages are used as opposed to absolute wages for normalisation purposes. The correlation between child wage and illiterate adult wages is weak: the child–male wage correlation is 0.056, and the child–female wage correlation is 0.275. However, the male–female wage correlation is 0.396.

  18. Data on the “Gini” coefficient are from Egypt: Human Development Report 1994 and measure expenditure based on household budget surveys that capture earnings, non-labour income and wealth. The 1988 LFSS did not collect information on individual household expenditure or landholdings.

  19. Levy (1985) also finds that wage–child effect has the right sign but is not significant.

  20. Levy (1985) uses pooled cross-section (at the governorate level) and time series data (for the period 1974–1977) to examine the importance of cropping pattern and mechanisation for family size and child schooling in rural Egypt. He estimates simultaneously a set of regression equations explaining the regional variation in fertility, school enrolment and child labour participation rates.

References

  • Baland J-M, Robinson J (2000) Is child labour inefficient? J Polit Econ 108:663–679

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Basu K (1999) Child labour: cause, consequence, and cure, with remarks on international standards. J Econ Lit 37:1083–1119

    Google Scholar 

  • Basu K (2000) The intriguing relation between adult minimum wage and child labour. Econ J 110:c50–c61

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Basu K, Van PH (1998) The economics of child labour. Am Econ Rev 88:412–427

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhalotra S (2001) Is child work necessary? The World Bank Social Protection Discussion Paper No. 0121, The World Bank, Washington, D.C.

  • Bhalotra S, Heady C (2003) Child farm labour: the wealth paradox. World Bank Econ Rev 17(2):197–227

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bonnet M (1993) Child labour in Africa. Int Labour Rev 132:371–389

    Google Scholar 

  • Canagarajah S, Coulombe H (1997) Child labour and schooling in Ghana The World Bank Working Paper Series, No. 1844, The World Bank, Washington, D.C.

  • Corcoran M, Gordon R, Laren D, Solon G (1990) Effects of family and community background on economic status. Am Econ Rev Pap Proc 80:362–366

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond C, Fayed T (1998) Evidence on substitutability of adult and child labour. J Dev Stud 34:62–70

    Google Scholar 

  • Egypt Human Development Report (1994) Institute of National Planning, Cairo

  • Emerson PM, Souza AP (2003) Is there a child labour trap? Intergenerational persistence of child labour in Brazil. Econ Dev Cult Change 51:375–398

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fergany N (1991) Final report. Overview and general features of employment in the domestic economy. CAPMAS, Cairo

  • Grootaert C (1998) Child labour in Côte d'Ivoire: incidence and determinants. The World Bank Social Development Department, The World Bank, Washington, D.C.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grootaert C, Kanbur R (1995) Child labour: an economic perspective. Int Labour Rev 134:187–580

    Google Scholar 

  • Hanushek EA, Levy V (1993) Dropping out of school: further evidence on the role of school quality in developing countries. Rochester Centre for Economic Research Working Paper No 345, University of Rochester

  • Ilhai N, Orazem P, Sedlacek G (2000) The implications of child labour for adult wages, income and poverty: retrospective evidence from Brazil. The World Bank, mimeo

  • International Labour Organization (2002) Every child counts: new global estimates on child labour. IPEC, ILO, Geneva

    Google Scholar 

  • Jensen P, Nielsen HS (1997) Child labour or school attendance? Evidence from Zambia. J Popul Econ 10:407–424

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Levy V (1985) Cropping pattern, mechanization, child labour, and fertility behaviour in a farming economy: rural Egypt. Econ Dev Cult Change 33:777–791

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindbeck A (1997) Incentives and Social Norms in Household Behaviour. The American Economic Review 87(2):370–377

    Google Scholar 

  • Lopez-Calva L (2002) Social norms, coordination, and policy issues in the fight against child labour. In: Basu K, Horn H, Roman L, Shapiro J (eds) International labour standards, issues, theories, and policy option. Blackwell Publishers, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Moulton BR (1990) An illustration of a pitfall in estimating the effects of aggregate variables on micro units. Rev Econ Stat 72:334–338

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nielsen HS (1998) Child labour and school attendance: two joint decisions, University of Aarhus Working Paper 98-15

  • Patrinos HA, Psacharopoulos G (1997) Family size, schooling and child labour in Peru. J Popul Econ 10:387–405

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Ranjan P (1999) An economic analysis of child labour. Econ Lett 64:99–105

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ranjan P (2001) Credit constraints and the phenomenon of child labour. J Dev Econ 64:81–102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ravallion M, Wodon Q (2000) Does child labour displace schooling? Evidence on behavioural responses to an enrolment subsidy? Econ J 110:c158–c175

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ray R (2000a) Analysis of child labour in Peru and Pakistan: a comparative study. J Popul Econ 13:3–19

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ray R (2000b) Child labour, child schooling, and their interaction with adult labour: empirical evidence for Peru and Pakistan. World Bank Econ Rev 14:347–367

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenzweig M (1981) Household and non-household activities of youths: issues of modelling, data and estimation strategies. In: Rodgers G, Standing G (eds) Child work, poverty and underdevelopment. ILO, Geneva, pp 215–244

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenzweig M, Evenson R (1977) Fertility, schooling, and the economic contribution of children in rural India: an econometric analysis. Econometrica 45:1065–1079

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skoufias E (1994) Market wages, family composition and on the time allocation of children in agricultural households. J Dev Stud 30:335–360

    Google Scholar 

  • Solon G (1999) Intergenerational mobility in the labour market. In: Ashenfelter O, Card D (eds) Handbook of labour economics, vol. 3A. Elsevier, North-Holland

    Google Scholar 

  • Swinnerton KA, Rogers CA (1999) The economics of child labour: comment. Am Econ Rev 89:1382–1388

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Swinnerton KA, Rogers CA (2000) Inequality, productivity, and child labour: theory and evidence. Mimeo

Download references

Acknowledgements

I would like to thank Sally Srinivasan, Yves Zenou, three anonymous referees and the editor for helpful comments. I am grateful to Barry McCormick for valuable comments and suggestions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jackline Wahba.

Additional information

Communicated by Deborah Cobb-Clark

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Wahba, J. The influence of market wages and parental history on child labour and schooling in Egypt. J Popul Econ 19, 823–852 (2006). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-005-0014-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-005-0014-2

Keywords

JEL

Navigation