Skip to main content
Log in

The importance of the political process on corporate tax policy

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Constitutional Political Economy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Few would argue that the difficulty in making legislative changes influences policy decisions and often results in less timely and responsive legislation. Despite this, economic research on corporate tax policy often excludes consideration of the political process. This study examines the impact of the political and economic factors on several measures of corporate tax rates and tax incentives offered across 19 developed countries. Our results indicate that while economic conditions influence the rate of tax set by governments, the political process of the federal government also has a significant impact on the economic stimulus given. The impact of the political process on the ability to enact legislation is significant after controlling for economic factors indicating that in a global economy, it will become increasingly important for governments to find opportunities to work within their systems to enact legislation that attracts foreign direct investment and increases domestic growth.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For a more detailed discussion of the definition, types and implications of tax competition, see Talpos and Crasneac (2010).

  2. Specifically, legislative fractionalization, rae_leg, is measured as \(rae\_leg = 1 - \sum\limits_{\text{i - 1}}^{\text{m}} {s_{i}^{2} } ,\) where S i is share of seats for party i and m is the number of parties. Hence, if only one party has legislative power rae_leg is equal to zero.

  3. The institutional constraints variable is "instcons" from the Comparative Political Data Set 1. It is an additive index composed of six dummy variables with a value of 1 for each constraint or zero otherwise. The constraints are: (1) EU membership, (2) strong centralization of state structure, (3) difficulty of amending constitutions, (4) strong bicameralism, (5) central bank autonomy and (6) frequent referenda.

  4. The political structure variable is "structure" from the Comparative Political Data Set 1.The structure variables is an additive index that is composed of five indicators (1) federalism (0 = absence, 1 = weak, 2 = strong), (2) parliamentary government (presidentialism = 0, other = 1), (3) proportional representation = 1; modified proportional representation = 1, majoritarian = 2) bicameralism (0 = no second chamber or second chamber with very weak powers, 1 = weak bicameralism, 2 = strong bicameralism), (5) frequent referenda = 1.

  5. In untabled results, we included an interaction between size and EU membership. This interaction term was positive and statistically significant indication that the negative relationship between size and tax rates does not exist in EU countries. Indeed, the positive relationship vanishes when US is excluded from the sample.

  6. The different results when including country fixed effects suggest that omitting fixed effects result in biased estimates.

  7. In untabled results, we substitute federalism and presidential regimes, which have been included as political variables in prior research, for our political measures fractionalization, institutional constraint and structure. Our results show that federalism has a negative and highly significant impact on statutory rates while presidential regime is insignificant. The use of fractionalization, institutional constraint and structure result in a higher adjusted R-square and provide more insight into the types of political activities that affect statutory rates. We also rerun the sensitivity tests on effective average tax rates and effective marginal tax rates and find once again that only federalism significantly affects either rate and that the adjusted R-squares in these regressions are lower than those reported in our tables.

  8. To expand upon our findings that government structure, institutional constraint and fractionalization all significantly contribute to tax legislation, we constructed a dummy variable called “high integration” that has a value of one when the value of the strategic integration is in the bottom quarter of each annual distribution. The bottom quarter of the strategic integration variable represents those countries in our sample that are close to countries with low tax rates and, in a sense, are most exposed to tax competition. We construct three new integration variables which are the product of high integration multiplied by political structure, institutional constraint and fractionalization, respectively. The fixed effects year and country, instrumental variable regression models presented in Table 3, are run three times including each of the interaction variables. In each of the three regressions, the interaction variable was insignificant. In addition, none of the inferences presented in Table 3 changed. These results suggest that the tax strategic integration does not impact the political constraints on statutory tax rates.

  9. We have also used a random effects model even though the Hausman test shows that the fixed effect model is preferred. In the random effects model the variable structure is positively and significantly correlated with all three tax measures.

  10. In untabled results, we again substitute federalism and presidential regimes, which have been included as political variables in prior research, for our political measures fractionalization, institutional constraint and structure. Our results show that neither federalism nor presidential regimes affect the level of incentives.

References

  • Altshuler, R., & Goodspeed, T. (2002). Follow the leader? Evidence on European and US tax competition? Unpublished working paper.

  • Ashworth, J., & Heyndels, B. (2001). Political fragmentation and the evolution of national tax structure in the OECD. International Tax and Public Finance, 8, 377–393.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ashworth, J., & Heyndels, B. (2002). Tax structure turbulence in OECD countries. Public Choice, 111, 276–347.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R. E., Forslid, R., Martin, P., Ottaviano, G., & Robert-Nicoud, F. (2003). Economic geography and public policy. New York, NY: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R. E., & Krugman, P. (2004). Agglomeration, integration and tax harmonization. European Economic Review, 48, 1–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Basinger, S. J., & Hallerberg, M. (2004). Remodeling the competition for capital: How domestic politics erases the race to the bottom. American Political Science Review, 98, 261–276.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T., Giffith, R., & Klemm, A. (2001). Empirical evidence on fiscal interdependency in OECD countries: Unpublished.

  • Brueckner, J. K. (2003). Strategic interaction among governments: An overview of empirical studies. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 31, 215–245.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (2008). Same players, different game: How better rules make better politics. Constitutional Political Economy, 19, 171–179.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cassette, A., & Paty, S. (2008). Tax competition among Eastern and Western European countries: With whom do countries compete? Economic Systems, 32, 307–325.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crabbé, K., & Vandenbussche, H. (2009). Are your firm’s taxes set in Warsaw? Spatial tax competition in Europe. CEPR Discussion papers 7159.

  • Davies, R., & Voget, J. (2008). Tax competition in an expanding European Union. Working Papers 0830: Oxford University Centre for Business Taxation.

  • Devereux, M., Griffith, R., & Klemm, A. (2002). Corporate income tax reforms and international tax competition. Economic Policy, 35, 451–495.

    Google Scholar 

  • Devereux, M., Lockwood, B., & Redoano, M. (2006). Horizontal and vertical indirect tax competition: Theory and some evidence from the USA. Journal of Public Economics, 91, 451–479.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Devereux, M., Lockwood, B., & Redoano, M. (2008). Do countries compete over corporate tax rates? Journal of Public Economics, 92, 1210–1235.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dreher, A. (2006). The influence of globalization on taxes and social policy: An empirical analysis for OECD countries. European Journal of Political Economy, 22, 179–201.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • European Commission. (2001). Company taxation in the internal market. Technical Report 582, European Commission.

  • Ganghof, S. (2000). Adjusting national tax policy to economic internationalisation: Strategies and outcomes. In E. W. Scharpf & V. A. Schmidt (Eds.), Welfare and work in the open economy, vol II: Diverse responses to common challenges (pp. 597–645). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Garrett, G., & Mitchell, D. (2001). Globalization, government spending and taxation in the OECD. European Journal of Political Research, 39, 145–177.

    Google Scholar 

  • Genschel, P., Kemmerling, A., & Seils, E. (2011). Accelerating downhill: How the EU shapes corporate tax competition in the single market. Journal of Common Market Studies, 49, 585–606.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerard, M., & Ruiz, F. (2009). Corporate taxation and the impact of governance, political and economic factors. Cesifo Working Paper #2901.

  • Ghinamo, M., Panteghini, P., & Revelli, F. (2007). FDI determination and corporate tax competition in a volatile world. Cesifo working paper # 1965.

  • Gomes, P., & Pouget, F. (2008). Corporate tax competition and the decline of public investment. Cesifo working paper #2384.

  • Hansson, Å., & Olofsdotter, K. (2008). Integration and the structure of public spending. Comparative Political Studies, 41(7), 1001–1027.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansson, Å., & Olofsdotter, K. (2012). FDI taxes and agglomeration economies in the EU15. Applied Economics, 45, 2653–2664.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heinemann, F., Overesch, M., & Rincke, J. (2010). Rate-cutting tax reforms and corporate competition in Europe. Economics and Politics, 22, 498–518.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hines, J., & Summers, L. (2009). How globalization affects tax design. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper #14664, Cambridge, Massachusetts.

  • Huber, E., Ragin, C., & Stephens, J. (1993). Social democracy, christian democracy, constitutional structure, and the welfare state. American Journal of Sociology, 99, 711–749.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huizinga, H., & Laeven, N. (2008). International profit shifting within multinationals: A multi-country perspective. Journal of Public Economics, 92, 1164–1182.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • International Bureau of Fiscal Documentation (IBFD), various years, European Tax Handbook, various editions, IBDF, Amsterdam.

  • Jovanovic, M. (2003). Spacial location of firms and industries: An overview of theory. Economia Internazionale, 56, 23–82.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kammas, P. (2011). Strategic fiscal interaction among OECD countries. Public Choice, 147, 459–480.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keen, M., & Kotsogiannis, C. (2002). Does federalism lead to excessively high taxes? The American Economic Review, 92, 364–370.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krogstrup, S. (2004). Are corporate taxes racing to the bottom in the European Union? Working paper, The Graduate Institute of International Studies, Geneva.

  • LeSage, J., & Pace, R. (2009). Introduction to spatial econometrics. Boca Raton, FL: Chapman and Hall.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Loretz, S. (2007). Determinants of bilateral effective tax rates: Effective evidence from OECD countries. Fiscal Studies, 28(2), 227–249.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayer, T., & Zignago, S. (2011). Notes on CEPII’s distance measures: The GeoDist database. CPEII working paper # 25.

  • OECD. (2014). Tax database. Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • Overesch, M., & Rincke, J. (2011). What drives corporate tax rates down? A reassessment of globalization, tax competition and dynamic adjustments to shocks. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 113, 579–602.

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., Roland, G., & Tabellini, G. (2000). Comparative politics and public finance. Journal of Political Economy, 108, 1121–1161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plümper, T., Troeger, V. E., & Winner, H. (2009). Why is there no race to the bottom in capital taxation? International Studies Quarterly, 53, 761–786.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rae, D. (1968). A note on the fractionalization of some European party systems. Comparative Political Studies, 1, 413–418.

    Google Scholar 

  • Redoano, M. (2007). Fiscal interaction among European countries: Does the EU matter? Cesifo working paper # 1952.

  • Rodrik, D. (1997). Has globalization gone too far?. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ruiz, F., & Gerard, M. (2008). Is there evidence of strategic corporate tax interaction among EU countries? MPRA Paper 10094. Germany: University Library of Munich.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmidt, M. G. (1996). When parties matter: A review of the possibilities and limits of partisan influence on public policy. European Journal of Political Research, 30, 155–183.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schwarz, P. (2007). Does capital mobility reduce the corporate-labor tax ratio? Public Choice, 130, 363–380.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Slemrod, J. (2004). Are corporate tax rates, or countries, converging? Journal of Public Economics, 88, 1169–1186.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Swank, D. (2002). Global capital, political institutions, and policy change in developed welfare states. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Swank, D., & Steinmo, S. (2002). The new political economy of taxation in advanced capitalist democracies. American Journal of Political Science, 46, 642–655.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Talpos, I., & Crasneac, A. (2010). The effects of tax competition. Theoretical and Applied Economics, 549, 39–52.

    Google Scholar 

  • Teter, M. (2013). Gridlock, legislative supremacy and the problem of arbitrary inaction. Notre Dame Law Review, 88, 2217–2232.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wildasin, D. (1988). Nash equlibria in models of fiscal competition. Journal of Public Economics, 35, 229–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, J. (1999). Theories of tax competition. National Tax Journal, 52, 269–304.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, J., & Wildasin, D. (2004). Tax competition: Bane or boon. Journal of Public Economics, 88, 1065–1091.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Winner, H. (2005). Has tax competition emerged in OECD countries? Evidence from panel data. International Tax & Public Finance, 12, 667–687.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Åsa Hansson.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Hansson, Å., Porter, S. & Williams, S.P. The importance of the political process on corporate tax policy. Const Polit Econ 26, 281–306 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-014-9185-8

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-014-9185-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation