Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Optimal fertility under age-dependent labour productivity

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Population Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In the so-called Rapport Sauvy (1962), the French demographer Alfred Sauvy argued that Wallonia’s fertility rate was socially suboptimal, and recommended a 20 % rise of fertility, on the grounds that a society with too low a fertility leads to a low-productive economy composed of old workers having old ideas. This paper examines how Sauvy’s intuition can be incorporated in the Samuelsonian optimal fertility model (Samuelson, Int Econ Rev 16:531–538, 1975). We build a four-period OLG model with physical capital and with two generations of workers (young and old), the skills of the latter being subject to some form of decay. We characterize the optimal fertility rate and show that this equalizes, at the margin, the sum of the capital dilution effect (Solow effect) and the labour age-composition effect (Sauvy effect) with the intergenerational redistribution effect (Samuelson effect). Numerical simulations show that it is hard, from a quantitative perspective, to reconcile Sauvy’s recommendation with facts. This leads us to examine other potential determinants of optimal fertility, by introducing technological progress and a more general social welfare function.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. From a formal perspective, one may be tempted to interpret the parameter α differently. For instance, one may interpret it as reflecting the health of older workers, or as reflecting their participation rate to the labour force. Note, however, that our model supposes that α does not affect individual utility directly, whereas health or participation would have such a direct influence. Therefore, we prefer here to keep our interpretation of α as a technical parameter reflecting the decay in human skills.

  2. Note that this objective is here similar to maximizing the average ex post (i.e. realized) lifetime well-being among agents living at the steady-state (some agents being short-lived, whereas others are long-lived).

  3. The necessity to raise fertility when longevity increases raise the number of inactive persons is also emphasized in Sauvy (1956).

  4. More formally, there exists a particular level of α, denoted \(\hat {\alpha }\), for which \(\alpha F_{L}\left (k^{\ast },1+\frac {\alpha }{n^{\ast }}\right ) \) takes its maximum, that is, for which the marginal loss in product per young worker due to a rise in fertility is the largest. This level is defined by the equality:

    $$F_{L}\left( k^{\ast},1+\frac{\hat{\alpha}}{n^{\ast}}\right) =-\frac {\hat{\alpha}}{n^{\ast}}F_{LL}\left( k^{\ast},1+\frac{\hat{\alpha}}{n^{\ast} }\right) $$

    When the first influence dominates the second, a larger decay of old workers’ skills (i.e. a lower α) contributes to reduce the negative effect induced by a higher n, leading, ceteris paribus, to a higher optimal fertility n . But when the second influence dominates the first, a larger decay raises the negative effect induced by a higher n, leading, ceteris paribus, to a lower optimal fertility n .

  5. Indeed, from the resource constraint, we have:

    $$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} F\left( k,1+\frac{\alpha}{n}\right) & =&\left[ n\beta d^{-\frac{1}{\sigma} }\right]^{-\sigma}+\frac{d}{n}+ \frac{\left[\frac{d_{t}^{-\frac{1}{\sigma}}}{\beta n}\right]^{-\sigma}\pi}{n^{2}}+nk\\ & \iff& d=\frac{F\left( k,1+\frac{\alpha}{n}\right) -nk}{\left[ \left[ n\beta\right]^{-\sigma}+\frac{1}{n} +\frac{\left[\frac{1}{\beta n}\right]^{-\sigma}\pi}{n^{2}}\right] } \end{array} $$
  6. Given that, at time t, there are four generations born at times t−3, t−2, t−1 and t, we start the aggregation of well-being by considering the cohort born at t = −3. Since that cohort start consuming at t = −2, we consider a time horizon starting at t = −2.

  7. Note that, since the time horizon of the social planner is infinite, an upper bound requires that ρn ϕ<1 (see Stelter 2016).

  8. We consider here the baseline production function without labour-augmenting technological progress.

  9. Stelter (2016) derives a similar generalized golden rule taking ethical judgements on numbers into account, but when there is only one cohort of workers (instead of two here).

  10. That is, u(c t+1) + βu(d t+2) + β 2 πu(b t+3)>0.

References

  • Abio G (2003) Interiority of the optimal population growth rate with endogenous fertility. Econ Bull 10(4):1–7

    Google Scholar 

  • Aubert P, Crépon B (2007) Are older workers less productive? Firm-level evidence on age-productivity and age-wages profiles. mimeo

  • Blackorby C, Bossert W, Donaldson D (2005) Population issues in social choice theory, welfare economics and ethics. Cambridge University Press

  • Blundell R, Browning M, Meghir C (1994) Consumer demand and the life-cycle allocation of household expenditures. Rev Econ Stud 61(1):57–80

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Börsch-Supan A, Weiss M (2016) Productivity and age: evidence from work teams at the assembly line. The Journal of the Economics of Ageing 7:30–42

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boucekkine R, de la Croix D, Licandro O (2002) Vintage human capital, demographic trends and endogenous growth. J Econ Theory 104(2):340–375

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Browning M, Hansen L, Heckman J (1999) Micro data and general equilibrium models. In: Taylor J, Woodford M (eds) Handbook of macroeconomics, vol 1A. Elsevier Science

  • Capron C, Debuissson M, Eggerickx T, Poulain M (1998) La Dualité démographique de la Belgique: mythe ou réalité?. In: Régimes démographiques et territoires: les frontières en question : colloque international de la rochelle, 22–26 Septembre 1998

  • Deardorff AV (1976) The optimum growth rate for population: comment. Int Econ Rev 17(5):510–515

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de la Croix D, Michel P (2002) A theory of economic growth. Dynamics and policy in overlapping generations. Cambridge University Press

  • de la Croix D, Pestieau P, Ponthiere G (2012) How powerful is demography? The serendipity theorem revisited. J Popul Econ 25:899–922

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Del Rey E, Lopez-Garcia M-A (2013) Optimal education and pensions in an endogenous growth model. J Econ Theory 148(4):1737–1750

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Göbel C, Zwick T (2012) Age and productivity: sector differences. De Economist 160(1):35–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenwood J, Seshadri A, Vandenbroucke G (2005) The baby boom and baby bust. Am Econ Rev 95(1):183–207

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson P (1993) Aging and European economic demography. In: Johnson P, Zimmermann K (eds) Labor markets in an ageing europe. Cambridge University press, Cambridge

  • Jones L, Schoonbroodt A (2016) Baby busts and baby booms: the fertility response to shocks in dynastic models. Mimeo

  • Michel P, Pestieau P (1993) Population growth and optimality: when does the serendipity hold. J Popul Econ 6:353–362

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ng Y-K (1986) Social criteria for evaluating population change: an alternative to the Blackorby-Donaldson criterion. J Public Econ 29:375–381

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parfit D (1984) Reasons and persons. Oxford University Press

  • Pestieau P, Ponthiere G (2014) Optimal fertility along the life cycle. Economic Theory 55(1):185–224

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Phelps E (1961) The golden rule of accumulation: a fable for growthmen. Am Econ Rev 51(4):638–643

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson P (1975) The optimum growth rate for population. Int Econ Rev 16:531–538

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sauvy A (1956) Théorie générale de la population. Volume 1: économie et population. Presses Universitaires de France

  • Sauvy A (1962) Le rapport Sauvy sur le problème de l’économie et de la population en Wallonie. Editions du Conseil Economique Wallon, Liège

  • Skirbekk V (2003) Age and individual productivity: a literature survey. In: Feichtinger G (ed) Vienna yearbook of population research. Austrian Academy of Sciences Press, Vienna, p 2004

  • Stelter R (2016) Over-aging—are present human populations too old? Mathematical Social Sciences. forthcoming

  • van Ours J, Stoeldraijer L (2010) Age, wage and productivity. IZA Discussion Paper:4765

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors would like to thank Alessandro Cigno, David de la Croix, Thomas Baudin, and Pierre Mohnen, as well as two anonymous referees for their comments. We are also grateful to the participants of the XXIemeCongrès des Economistes Belges de Langue Française in Liege.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Gregory Ponthiere.

Additional information

Responsible editor: Alessandro Cigno

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Pestieau, P., Ponthiere, G. Optimal fertility under age-dependent labour productivity. J Popul Econ 30, 621–646 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-016-0627-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-016-0627-7

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation