Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Welfare reform and the subjective well-being of single mothers

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Population Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Although a large body of research examines the impact of welfare reform, there remains considerable uncertainty as to whether single mothers’ well-being improved in the wake of these policy changes. Using unique data from the DDB Worldwide Communications Life StyleTM survey, this paper exploits a large battery of survey questions on self-reported life satisfaction and physical and mental health to study the impact of welfare reform on the subjective well-being of single mothers. The identification strategy relies on a difference-in-differences framework to estimate intent-to-treat effects for the welfare waiver and TANF periods. Results indicate that the bundle of TANF reforms had mostly positive effects on single mothers’ subjective well-being. These women experienced an increase in life satisfaction, greater optimism about the future, and more financial satisfaction. Furthermore, these improvements did not come at a cost of reducing mental and physical health. Welfare waivers, in contrast, had largely neutral effects on well-being. I provide indirect evidence that the increase in single mothers’ employment after welfare reform can plausibly explain the gains in subjective well-being.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Kahneman and Krueger (2006) argue that subjective well-being does not contain a “single, unifying concept that motivates all human choices and registers all relevant feelings and experiences” (p. 4). Consistent with the multi-dimensional nature of subjective well-being, Diener (2006) suggests that it “refers to all of the various types of evaluations, both positive and negative, that people make of their lives. It includes reflective cognitive evaluations, such as life satisfaction and work satisfaction, interest and engagement, and affective reactions to life events, such as joy and sadness. Thus, subjective well-being is an umbrella term for the different valuations people make regarding their lives, the events happening to them, their bodies and minds, and the circumstances in which they live” (pp. 399–400).

  2. See, for example, Frey and Stutzer (2002), Gruber and Mullainathan (2005), and Kahneman and Krueger (2006).

  3. Measures of subjective well-being are also shown to be highly correlated with many objective measures, including income (Stevenson and Wolfers 2008) and macro-economic conditions (e.g., GDP, inflation, and the unemployment rate) (Di Tella et al. 2003).

  4. These measures are, however, not without their criticisms (e.g., Bertrand and Mullainathan 2001). For example, a sizeable body of evidence indicates that subjective well-being measures are prone to reporting error stemming from questions order-effects and, more generally, the relative placement of these questions in the survey. It has been shown using the GSS that preceding the global happiness question with one on marital happiness has non-trivial effects on self-reported happiness. In addition, contemporaneous mood (at the time the survey is administered) is found to influence on how people respond to subjective well-being questions.

  5. To my knowledge, Robert Putnam was the first individual to use these data for the purpose of academic research. Specifically, the Life Style survey was a key dataset in his book Bowling Alone. Please refer to Putnam’s (2000) data appendix for an extensive introduction to these data, as well as a detailed discussion of his reliability tests. See also Putnam and Yonish (1999) and Groeneman (1994) for further information about the survey. This is a proprietary data archive, although the 1975–1998 surveys are freely available on Putnam’s (2000) Bowling Alone website.

  6. Ifcher (2011), who uses the GSS in his welfare reform study, defines the pre-reform period as 1990, 1991, 1993, 1994, and 1996. The post-reform period includes 1998, 2000, 2002, and 2004. As a result, he does not take advantage of the differential timing in states’ implementation of welfare waivers or PRWORA. In addition, the definition of the pre-reform period includes several years in which states implemented welfare waiver reforms. In particular, 3 of the 5 years in the pre-reform period (1993, 1994, and 1996) are marked by state experimentation with federal AFDC statutes, leaving 1990 and 1991 as the only years without any welfare-related policy reforms.

  7. In an early version of the paper, Ifcher’s (2009) analysis sample includes 158 low-skilled single mothers in the pre-reform period and 198 in the post-reform period. In addition, Ifcher (2009) is forced to define the treatment and comparison groups differently in order to maintain a sufficient sample size. The treatment group includes single mothers with less than a high school degree, while the comparison group members (single, childless women) are allowed to have such a degree. Ifcher’s (2009) analysis sample has just 94 single, childless women without a high school degree, which increases to 359 women when using the higher education cut-off. An implication of the educational imbalance between these groups is that it reduces the comparability of treatment and comparison women, a potential problem in a difference-in-differences framework. In a more recent version of the paper, Ifcher (2011) reports the overall analysis sample size, which includes 2,699 when all unmarried women are retained and only 1,212 when low-skilled unmarried women are retained.

  8. The survey underwent a redesign in 2006. Therefore, I end the observation period in 2005.

  9. All Appendix Tables in this paper are available online as Electronic Supplementary Material.

  10. A key motivation for conducting the analysis using multiple education criteria is that the broader welfare reform literature is unsettled as to what the most appropriate education cut-off should be. For example, some studies (e.g., Grogger 2003; Herbst 2008; Meyer and Rosenbaum 2001) do not use any education cut-off, while others examine women with a high school degree or less (e.g., Kaushal and Kaestner 2001). Still other studies experiment with multiple education cut-offs (e.g., Bitler et al. 2005; Bitler and Hoynes 2010).

  11. It is important to reiterate that the measure of life satisfaction used here is fairly close to other standard measures used in the happiness literature. For example, the Eurobarometer survey asks respondents: “On the whole, are you very satisfied, fairly satisfied, not very satisfied, and not at all satisfied with the life you lead?”

  12. The full set of responses is the following: 1 (definitely disagree), 2 (generally disagree), 3 (moderately disagree), 4 (moderately agree), 5 (generally agree), and 6 (definitely agree).

  13. The mean for the continuous life satisfaction index is 3.20 (SD = 1.57) for single mothers and 3.44 (SD = 1.56) for single childless women.

  14. Crouse (1999) and Grogger and Karoly (2005) provide lists of implementation dates for various welfare waivers. It should be noted that not all states implemented a welfare waiver, and that the implementation dates vary dramatically across these states. Twenty-eight states in the Life Style survey analysis sample had a wavier “turned on” at some point between 1992 and 1997. The first states to implement welfare waivers—in 1992—were California, Michigan, and New Jersey. The welfare waiver period ended in 1997, when California implemented its TANF plan (the last state to do so) in January of 1998. The pre-reform period in states with a waiver extends to the year of the waiver’s implementation. In the states that did not implement a welfare waiver, the pre-reform period extends until the on-set of TANF.

  15. TANF implementation dates are taken from Grogger and Karoly (2005). Unlike the waiver period, all states implemented TANF reforms, but like the waiver period, there is temporal variation in the timing of implementation. States implemented TANF over the period 1996 to 1998.

  16. I implement a robustness check that continues to “turn on” these policy dummies in the year of implementation, but allows the waiver and TANF dummies to be “turned on” at the same time (i.e., both dummies take a value of one) during the implementation overlap years. In addition, I implement a check in which the waiver and TANF coding is based on the fraction of the year in which each reform is in effect. Results from these additional analyses are quite similar to those discussed in the paper.

  17. A recent paper by Athey and Imbens (2006), which discusses a “changes-in-changes” model for non-linear outcomes, may have implications for (1), given that it is estimated using an ordered probit model. Under some conditions (e.g., assuming strict monotonicity in the relationship between the unobservables and treatment statuses well as the common assumption of stability in the differences between treatment and comparison group characteristics), estimates from the changes-in-changes model will mirror those from the standard D-in-D model.

  18. With the exception of the presence and number of children in the home and educational attainment, all variables necessary to create the analysis sample (gender, age, and marital status) are measured in precisely the same manner throughout the study period. Between 1986 and 2000, eight age-specific categories capture the presence of children ages 0 to 17. Starting in 2001, the survey was changed to incorporate seven categories. The measure of educational attainment changed three times (1986–1998; 1999, 2000, and 2002–2005; and 2001) throughout the study period. I carefully standardize these measures.

  19. Note that (1) omits controls for employment status and family income, as these are likely to be endogenous. Inclusion of these variables also complicates the interpretation of the estimated effect of Waiver and TANF, given that welfare reform is expected to work through the employment and income channels.

  20. In robustness checks, I replace the vector of year-specific indicator variables with two dummy variables capturing the entire post-Waiver and post-TANF periods (in this case, the pre-reform period is the omitted category). The results are very similar to those reported here.

  21. To explore life satisfaction trends in more detail, I estimate a regression of life satisfaction (“generally agree” or “definitely agree”) on a dummy variable for single mothers and separate linear time trends for single mothers and single women without children (using the less disadvantaged sample). The time trend coefficients reveal an upward trend in single mothers’ life satisfaction over the period 1986 to 2005 and a statistically significant downward trend for single women without children. In addition, I conduct an analogous analysis using the more disadvantaged sample of women. I find that single mothers’ life satisfaction trended upward (more so than in the less disadvantaged sample), while single women without children continued to experience a statistically significant downward trend in well-being.

  22. I conduct a similar time trend analysis for this variable as well. Although the trend coefficient for single mothers is positively signed and the trend coefficient for single women without children is negatively signed, both coefficients are small in magnitude and neither is statistically significant (using the less disadvantaged sample). Similar findings emerge when the analysis is conducted on the more disadvantaged sample.

  23. The Life Style survey includes weight, but there is insufficient documentation on how the weight is constructed. Therefore, I conduct the analyses using unweighted data. However, applying the weight does not change any of the results discussed in the text.

  24. As an additional check, I estimate the model on women with less than a high school degree, which represents an even more disadvantaged sample. Although the estimates are imprecisely estimated (due to a very small sample size), the results suggest that both welfare waivers and TANF are associated with reductions in life satisfaction. For example, the D-in-D TANF estimate is −0.06 (standard error, 0.13).

  25. To conserve space, all robustness checks presented and discussed here come from the less disadvantaged sample of unmarried women (i.e., those ages 18 to 60 with less than a bachelor’s degree). However, all of these analyses are estimated on the more disadvantaged sample (i.e., those ages 18 to 45 with no more than a high school degree) as well, and the results are comparable.

  26. The controls for per capita income and population density further guard against differences across states and over time in the underlying stocks of wealth and human capital that may drive both welfare reform and subjective well-being. The dummy variable for Republican governor accounts for politically induced differences in social policy reforms that affect subjective well-being, while the percentage voting Republican controls for unobserved attitudes, norms, and preferences within the electorate regarding certain types of social policies.

  27. In addition, I estimate the trends model on the pre-waiver and pre-TANF period, 1986 to 1991, conditional on the covariates. The results continue to provide strong evidence of common time trends in the well-being outcomes for single mothers and single childless women. Interestingly, results from an unconditional trends model suggests that single mothers’ life satisfaction remained flat, while single childless women experienced a downward shift in well-being. Such results highlight the importance of conditioning on the observable characteristics.

  28. In a further check, I include the placebo wavier and TANF D-in-Ds as well as a comparable set of unrestricted placebo waiver and TANF dummy variables in the model. In this case, coefficients on eight of the 20 placebo dummy variables are statistically significant.

  29. To perform the F test, I first run a regression of each characteristic on a set of interactions between a single mother dummy variable and the three period dummy variables, the remaining demographic controls, state fixed effects, and year dummy variables. I then test the equality of the single-mother-by-period interactions. Results from the test are shown in column (4).

  30. In a related specification check, I examine only the impact of TANF (i.e., I omit the D-in-D estimator of welfare waivers) and begin the analysis period in 1992. Results are once again robust to this sample definition.

  31. See, for example, Fletcher (2011) and Brewer et al. (2011).

References

  • Athey S, Imbens G (2006) Identification and inference in nonlinear difference-in-differences models. Econometrica 74(2):431–497

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bavier R (1999) An early look at the effects of welfare reform. Mimeo March

  • Bertrand M, Mullainathan S (2001) Do people mean what they say? Implications for subjective survey data. Am Econ Rev 91(2):67–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertrand M, Duflo E, Mullainathan S (2004) How much should we trust difference-in-differences estimates? Q J Econ 119(1):249–275

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchflower D, Oswald A (2004) Well-being over time in Britain and the USA. J Public Econ 88(7–8):1359–1386

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blank R (2002) Evaluating welfare reform in the United States. J Econ Lit 40(4):1105–1166

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bitler M, Hoynes H (2006) Welfare reform and indirect impacts on health. NBER working paper no 12642, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge

  • Bitler M, Hoynes H (2010) The state of the social safety net in the post-welfare reform era. Brookings Pap Econ Act Fall 71–127

  • Bitler MP, Gelbach JB, Hoynes HW (2005) Welfare reform and health. J Hum Resour 40(2): 309–334

    Google Scholar 

  • Bitler M, Gelbach J, Hoynes H (2006) What mean impacts miss: the distributional effects of welfare reform. Am Econ Rev 96(4):988–1012

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bollinger C, Gonzalex L, Ziliak J (2009) Welfare reform and the composition and level of income. In: Ziliak J (ed) Welfare reform and its long-term consequences for America’s poor. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Brewer M, Ratcliffe A, Smith S (2011) Does welfare reform affect fertility? Evidence from the UK. J Popul Econ 25:245–266

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark A, Oswald A (1994) Unhappiness and unemployment. Econ J 104:648–659

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crosby F (1982) Relative deprivation and working women. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Crouse G (1999) State implementation of major changes to welfare policies 1992–1998. http://aspe.hhs.gov/HSP/Waiver-Policies99/policy_CEA.htm. Retrieved 1 Sept 2006

  • de Leeuw E (2005) To mix or not to mix data collection modes in surveys. J Off Stat 21(2):233–255

    Google Scholar 

  • Di Tella R, MacCulloch R, Oswald A (2003) The macroeconomics of happiness. Rev Econ Stat 85(4):809–827

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diener E (1984) Subjective well-being. Psychol Bull 95(3):542–575

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diener E (2006) Guidelines for national indicators of subjective well-being and ill-being. J Happiness Stud 7(4):397–404

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diener E, Oishi S (2004) Are Scandinavians happier than Asians? Issues in comparing nations on subjective well-being. In: Columbus F (ed) Politics and economics of Asia, vol 10. Nova Science Publishers, Hauppauge, pp 1–25

  • Diener E, Seligman M (2004) Beyond money: toward an economy of well-being. Psychol Sci Public Interest 5(1):1–31

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diener E, Lucas R, Scollon C (2006) Beyond the hedonic treadmill: revising the adaption theory of well-being. Am Psychol 61(4):305–314

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dillman D, Sangster R, Tarnai J, Rockwood T (1996) Understanding differences in people’s answers to telephone and mail surveys. New Dir Eval 70:45–61

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dillman D, Phelps G, Tortora R, Swift K, Kohrell J, Berck J, Messer B (2009) Response rate and measurement differences in mixed mode surveys: using mail telephone interactive voice response and the internet. Soc Sci Res 38:1–18

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Di Tella R, MacCullough R, Oswald A (2001) Preferences over inflation and unemployment: evidence from surveys of happiness. Am Econ Rev 91(1):335–341

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edin K, Lein L (1997) Making ends meet: how single mothers survive welfare and low-wage work. Russell Sage Foundation, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Ehrhardt J, Saris W, Veehoven R (2000) Stability of life satisfaction over time. J Happiness Stud 1(2):177–205

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fang H, Keane M (2004) Assessing the impact of welfare reform on single mothers. Brookings Pap Econ Act 35(1):1–116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischer J (2009) Subjective well-being as welfare measure: concepts and methodology. Munich Personal RePEc Archive Working Paper No 16619

  • Fletcher J (2011) The effects of teenage childbearing on the short- and long-term health behaviors of mothers. J Popul Econ 25(1):201–218

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fordyce M (1988) A review of research on happiness measures: a sixty-second index of happiness and mental health. Soc Indic Res 20(4):355–381

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frey B, Stutzer A (2002) What can economists learn from happiness research? J Econ Lit 40(2):402–435

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Groeneman S (1994) Multi-purpose household panels and general samples: how similar and how different? Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Association for Public opinion Research. Danvers MA

  • Grogger J (2003) The effects of time limits the EITC and other policy changes on welfare use work and income among female-headed families. Rev Econ Stat 85(2):394–408

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grogger J, Karoly L (2005) Welfare reform: effects of a decade of change. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman M (1972) On the concept of health capital and the demand for health. J Polit Econ 80(2):223–255

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gruber J, Mullainathan S (2005) Do cigarette taxes make smokers happier? Adv Econ Anal Pol 5:1412–1421

    Google Scholar 

  • Hallberg D, Klevmarken A (2003) Time for children: a study of parents’ time allocation. J Popul Econ 26(2):205–226

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heberlein T, Baumgartner R (1978) Factors affecting response rate to mailed questionnaires: a quantitative analysis of the published literature. Am Sociol Rev 43(4):447–462

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman James J, Robert LaLonde, Jeffrey Smith (1999) The economics and econometrics of active labor market policies. In: Ashenfelter O, Card D (eds) Handbook of labor economics, vol 3A. North Holland, Amsterdam

  • Helliwell J (2003) How’s life? Combining individual and national variables to explain subjective well-being. Econ Model 20:331–360

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helliwell J (2006) Well-being and social capital: does suicide pose a puzzle? Soc Indic Res 81(3):455–496

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herbst C (2008) Do social policy reforms have different impacts on employment and welfare use as economic conditions change? J Policy Anal Manage 27(4):867–894

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herbst C (2010) Footloose and fancy free? Two decades of single mothers’ subjective well-being. Working Paper, School of Public Affairs Arizona State University

  • Herbst C (2011) ‘Paradoxical’ decline? Another look at relative reduction in female happiness. J Econ Psychol 32(5):773–788

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ifcher J (2009) The happiness of single mothers after welfare reform. Working Paper, Department of Economics Santa Clara University

  • Ifcher J (2011) The happiness of single mothers after welfare reform. BE J Econ Anal Pol 11:1–27

    Google Scholar 

  • Ifcher J, Zarghamee H (2010) Trends in the happiness of single mothers: evidence from the General Social Survey. Working Paper, Department of Economics Santa Clara University

  • Kaestner R, Kaushal N (2005) Immigrant and native responses to welfare reform. J Popul Econ 18(1):69–92

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman D, Krueger A (2006) Developments in the measurement of subjective well-being. J Econ Perspect 20(1):3–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman D, Deaton A (2010) High income improves evaluation of life but not emotional well-being. Proc Natl Acad Sci U S A 107:16489–16493

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman D, Wakker P, Sarin R (1997) Back to Bentham? Explorations of experienced utility. Q J Econ 112(2):375–405

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaushal N, Kaestner R (2001) From welfare to work: Has welfare reform worked? J Policy Anal Manage 20:699–719

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krueger A, Schkade D (2008) The reliability of subjective well-being measures. J Public Econ 92(8–9):1833–1845

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Layard R (2005) Happiness: lessons from a new science. Penguin, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Meyer B, Rosenbaum D (2000) Making single mothers work: recent changes in tax and welfare policy and their effects. Natl Tax J 53(4):1027–1062

    Google Scholar 

  • Meyer B, Rosenbaum D (2001) Welfare the earned income tax credit and the labor supply of single mothers. Q J Econ 116(3):1063–1114

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meyer B, Sullivan J (2004) The effects of welfare and tax reform: the material well-being of single mothers in the 1980s and 1990s. J Public Econ 88(7–8):1387–1420

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murphy G, Athanasou J (1999) The effect of unemployment on mental health. J Occup Organ Psychol 72:83–99

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Primus W, Rawlings L, Larin K, Porter K (1999) The initial impacts of welfare reform on the incomes of single-mother families. Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, Washington

  • Putnam R (2000) Bowling alone: the collapse and revival of American community. Simon and Schuster, New York, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Putnam R, Yonish S (1999) How important is response rate? An evaluation of a “mail panel” survey archive. Working Paper Cambridge, JFK School of Government Harvard University, MA

  • Ruhm C (2003) Good times make you sick. J Health Econ 22(4):637–658

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schoeni R, Blank R (2000) What has welfare reform accomplished? Impacts on welfare participation, employment, income, poverty, and family structure. Working Paper No 7627, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge MA

  • Sousa-Poza A, Sousa-Poza AA (2003) Gender differences in job satisfaction in Great Britain 1991–2000: permanent or transitory? Appl Econ Lett 10(11):691–694

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stevenson B, Wolfers J (2008) Economic growth and subjective well-being: reassessing the Easterlin paradox. Brookings Pap Econ Act 1:1–102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stevenson B, Wolfers J (2009) The paradox of declining female happiness. Am Econ J: Econ Pol 1(2):190–225

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Viinamaeki H, Koskela K, Niskanen L (1996) Rapidly declining mental well-being during unemployment. Eur J Psychiatry 10(4):215–221

    Google Scholar 

  • Visser P, Krosnick J, Marquette J, Curtin M (1996) Mail surveying for election forecasting: an evaluation of the Columbus Dispatch poll. Public Opin Q 60(2):181–227

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I would like to thank participants at the 2010 meeting of the Association for Public Policy Analysis and Management, John Ifcher, Lawrence Mead, and an anonymous referee for helpful comments and suggestions. I am also grateful to Chris Callahan, at DDB Worldwide Communications, who provided the Life Style™ survey data between 1999 and 2005 and answered many questions along the way.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Chris M. Herbst.

Additional information

Responsible editor: Junsen Zhang

Electronic Supplementary Material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

(PDF 462 KB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Herbst, C.M. Welfare reform and the subjective well-being of single mothers. J Popul Econ 26, 203–238 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-012-0406-z

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-012-0406-z

Keywords

JEL

Navigation