The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics

2018 Edition
| Editors: Macmillan Publishers Ltd

British Classical Economics

  • Mark Blaug
Reference work entry
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_99

Abstract

Classical economics is not just a period in the history of economic thought immediately prior to the marginal revolution but involves a distinct approach to economic problems. But endless controversy surrounds the definition of that approach. Indeed, the scope of the science of political economy as conceived in Smith’s The Wealth of Nations was sharply contracted in Ricardo’s Principles of Political Economy. Some modern commentators characterize classical economics as surplus theory; others as general equilibrium theory. Economists who are divided in their views will always try to find those views embodied in the writings of the past.

Keywords

Absolute advantage Austrian economics Babbage C. Bailey S. Balance of payment Blaug M. British classical economics Cairnes J. Capital accumulation Capital–Labour ratio Clark J. B. Classical economics Comparative advantage Corn Laws Corn model Cournot A. Distribution Dupuis A.-J.-E. Eagly R. Exchange value Factor endowments Free banking Free trade General equilibrium theory Gossen H. History of economic thought Hollander S. Increasing returns International trade Theory of Invariable measure of value Jevons W. Joint production Jones R. Keynes J.M. Knight F. Labour theory of value Laissez Faire Lloyd W. Longfield M. Malthus T. Marginal productivity theory Marginal revolution Marshall A. Marx K. McCulloch J. Menger C. Mill J. Mill J. S. Money Natural price Neoclassical economics Neo-Ricardian economics Normal price O’Brien D. Opportunity cost Organic composition of capital (Marx) Petty W. Physiocracy Pigou A. Political economy Population growth Poverty alleviation Preferences Pressure groups Production techniques Productive vs unproductive labour Profit and profit theory Quantity theory of money Quesnay F. Rae J. Rate of profit Reciprocal demand Rent Reserve army of the unemployed Ricardian revolution Ricardo D. Say J.-B. Say’s Law Schumpeter J. Senior N. Smith A. Sowell T. Sraffa P. Standard composite commodity (Sraffa) Static equilibrium analysis Steady-state equilibria Subsistence and subsistence wages Supply and demand Surplus Thornton H. Thünen G. Tooke T. Torrens R. Transformation problem Use Value Utility theories of value Vent-for-surplus doctrine Wages fund doctrine Wakefield E. Walrasian theory of general equilibrium Wicksteed P. 

JEL Classifications

B1 
This is a preview of subscription content, log in to check access.

Bibliography

  1. Arrow, K.J., and F.H. Hahn. 1971. General competitive analysis. San Francisco: Holden-Day.Google Scholar
  2. Barkai, H. 1965. Ricardo’s static equilibrium. Economica 32: 15–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Blaug, M. 1958. Ricardian economics: An historical study. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  4. Blaug, M. 1985. Economic theory in retrospect. 4th ed. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  5. Bloomfield, A.I. 1975. Adam Smith and the theory of international trade. In Essays on Adam Smith, ed. Skinner A. and Wilson T. Oxford.Google Scholar
  6. Bloomfield, A.I. 1978. The impact of growth and technology of trade in nineteenth-century economic thought. History of Political Economy 10: 608–635.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Bloomfield, A.I. 1981. British thought on the influence of foreign trade and investment of growth, 1800–1880. History of Political Economy 13: 95–120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Bradley, I., and M.C. Howard. 1982. Classical and Marxian political economy. London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Buchanan, D. 1929. The historical approach to rent and price theory. Economica 9 (26): 123–155.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Cropsey, J. 1957. Polity and economy: An interpretation of the principles of Adam Smith. The Hague: Nijhoff.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Dobb, M. 1973. Theories of value and distribution since Adam Smith. London: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Eagly, R.V. 1974. The structure of classical economic theory. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  13. Eatwell, J. 1977. The irrelevance of returns to scale in Sraffa’s analysis. Journal of Economic Literature 15 (1): 61–68.Google Scholar
  14. Eatwell, J. 1982. Competition. In Classical and Marxian political economy, ed. I. Bradley and M. Howard. London: MacMillan.Google Scholar
  15. Eltis, W. 1984. The classical theory of economic growth. London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Garegnani, P. 1976. On a change in the notion of equilibrium in recent work on value and distribution. In Essays in modern capital theory, ed. M. Brown, K. Sato, and P. Zarembka. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
  17. Garegnani, P. 1984. Value and distribution in the classical economists and Marx. Oxford Economic Papers 36: 291–325.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Gordon, D.F. 1959. What was the labour theory of value? American Economic Review 49: 462–472.Google Scholar
  19. Harcourt, G.C. 1982. The Sraffian contribution: An evaluation. In Classical and Marxian political economy, ed. I. Bradley and M. Howard. London: MacMillan.Google Scholar
  20. Hollander, S. 1973. The economics of Adam Smith. Toronto: University of Toronto Press\London: Heinemann Educational Books.Google Scholar
  21. Hollander, S. 1977. The reception of Ricardian economics. Oxford Economic Papers 29: 221–257.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Hollander, S. 1979. The economics of David Ricardo. Toronto: University of Toronto Press\London: Heinemann Educational Books.Google Scholar
  23. Hollander, S. 1981. Marxian economics as ‘general equilibrium’ theory. History of Political Economy 13: 121–155.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Hollander, S. 1982. On the substantive identity of the Ricardian and neoclassical conception of economic organization: The French connection in British classicism. Canadian Journal of Economics 15: 586–612.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Howard, M.C., and J.E. King. 1985. The political economy of Marx. 2nd ed. London: Longman.Google Scholar
  26. Kaldor, N. 1972. The irrelevance of equilibrium economics. Economic Journal 82 (December): 1237–1255.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Keynes, J.M. 1936. The general theory of employment, interest and money. In The collected writings of John Maynard Keynes, vol. 7. London: Macmillan, 1973.Google Scholar
  28. Knight, F.H. 1956. On the history and method of economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  29. Laidler, D.E.W. 1981. Adam Smith as a monetary economist. Canadian Journal of Economics 14 (2): 187–200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Lindgren, J.R. 1973. The social philosophy of Adam Smith. The Hague: Martinus Nijhoff.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Littlechild, S.C. 1982. Equilibrium and the market process. In Method, process, and Austrian economics, ed. I.M. Kirzner. Lexington: D.C. Heath.Google Scholar
  32. Lowe, A. 1954. The classical theory of economic growth. Social Research 21 (Summer): 127–158.Google Scholar
  33. Marshall, A. 1890. Principles of economics. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  34. Marx, K. 1867. Capital: A critique of political economy. Trans. B. Fowkes. Harmondsworth: Penguin Books, 1976.Google Scholar
  35. McNulty, P.J. 1967. A note on the history of perfect competition. Journal of Political Economy 75: 395–399.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Meek, R.L. 1967. Economics and ideology and other essays. London: Chapman & Hall.Google Scholar
  37. Meek, R.L. 1973. Studies in the labour theory of value. 2nd ed. London: Lawrence & Wishart.Google Scholar
  38. Meek, R.L. 1977. Smith, Marx and after. London: Chapman & Hall.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Mill, J.S. 1844. Essays on some unsettled questions political economy. London: London School of Economics, 1948.Google Scholar
  40. Myint, H. 1948. Theories of welfare economics. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  41. Myint, H. 1958. The ‘classical theory’ of international trade and underdeveloped countries. Economic Journal 68: 317–337.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. O’Brien, D.P. 1975. The classical economists. London: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  43. O’Brien, D.P. 1981. Ricardian economics and the economics of David Ricardo. Oxford Economic Papers 33: 352–386.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Ong, N.-P. 1983. Ricardo’s invariable measure of value and Sraffa’s ‘standard commodity’. History of Political Economy 15: 207–227.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  45. Pasinetti, L.L. 1974. Growth and income distribution: Essays in economic theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  46. Peach, T. 1984. David Ricardo’s early treatment of profitability: A new interpretation. Economic Journal 94: 733–751.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  47. Peacock, A. 1975. The treatment of the principles of public finance in The Wealth of Nations. In Essays on Adam Smith, ed. Skinner, A. S. and Wilson, T. Oxford.Google Scholar
  48. Ricardo, D. 1951–73. The works and correspondence of David Ricardo, ed. P. Sraffa. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  49. Robertson, H.M., and W.L. Taylor. 1957. Adam Smith’s approach to the theory of value. Economic Journal 67 (June): 181–198.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  50. Roncaglia, A. 1978. Sraffa and the theory of prices. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
  51. Rosenberg, N. 1960. Some institutional aspects of the Wealth of Nations. Journal of Political Economy 68: 557–570.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  52. Samuelson, P. 1978. The canonical classical model of political economy. Journal of Economic Literature 16: 1415–1434.Google Scholar
  53. Schumpeter, J.A. 1954. History of economic analysis. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  54. Skinner, A.S. 1979. A system of social science: Papers relating to Adam Smith. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
  55. Skinner, A.S., and T. Wilson. 1975. Essays on Adam Smith. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
  56. Sowell, T. 1974. Classical economics reconsidered. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  57. Spiegel, H.W. 1983. The growth of economic thought. Durham: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
  58. Sraffa, P. 1960. Production of commodities by means of commodities. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  59. Steedman, I. 1977. Marx after Sraffa. London: New Left Books.Google Scholar
  60. Steedman, I., ed. 1981. The value controversy. London: Verso Editions and New Left Books.Google Scholar
  61. Stigler, G.J. 1957. Perfect competition, historically contemplated. Journal of Political Economy 65: 1–17.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  62. Stigler, G.J. 1965. Textual exegesis as a scientific problem. Economica 33: 447–450.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  63. Thweatt, W.O. 1976. James Mill and the early development of comparative advantage. History of Political Economy 8: 207–234.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  64. Walsh, V., and H. Gram. 1980. Classical and neoclassical theories of general equilibrium. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  65. West, E.G. 1976. Adam Smith’s economics of politics. History of Political Economy 8: 515–539.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  66. White, L.H. 1984. Free banking in Britain: Theory, experience and debate, 1800–1845. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  67. Winch, D. 1978. Adam Smith’s politics: An essay in historiographic revision. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  68. Winch, D. 1983. Science and the legislator: Adam Smith and after. Economic Journal 93: 501–520.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 2018

Authors and Affiliations

  • Mark Blaug
    • 1
  1. 1.