Skip to main content

‘Neoclassical’

  • Reference work entry
  • First Online:
The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics

Abstract

The term ‘neoclassical’ was first used by Veblen (1900, pp. 242, 260–2, 265–8), in order to characterize Marshall and Marshallian economics. Veblen did not appeal to any similarity in theoretical structure between the economics of Marshall and classical economics in order to defend this novel designation. Rather, he perceived Marshall’s Cambridge School to have a continuity with classical economics on the alleged basis of a common utilitarian approach and the common assumption of a hedonistic psychology. Derivative from Veblen’s use, this meaning of the term subsequently gained some currency, particularly in the 1920s and 1930s; for example, in the writings of Wesley Mitchell, J.A. Hobson, Maurice Dobb and Eric Roll. It is evident that the emergence of this notion of Marshallian economics as a ‘neoclassical’ project also involved, at least in part, an acquiescence to Marshall’s portrayal of his own economics as a continuation of the classical tradition, though Marshall’s sense of the continuity is not really that perceived by Veblen. Keynes (1936, pp. 177–8) also employed the term, though in an idiosyncratic matter, derivative from his equally idiosyncratic notion of classical economics.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 6,499.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 8,499.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Bibliography

  • Aspromourgos, T. 1986. On the origins of the term ‘neoclassical’. Cambridge Journal of Economics 10: 265–270.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Colander, D. 2000. The death of neoclassical economics. Journal of the History of Economic Thought 22: 127–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dobb, M. 1924. The entrepreneur myth. Economica 4: 66–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, W.H. 1923. Vestigial economics. New Republic, 4 April.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J.R. 1932. Marginal productivity and the principle of variation. Economica 12: 79–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keynes, J.M. 1936. The general theory of employment, interest and money. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P.A. 1955. Economics: An introductory analysis. 3rd ed. New York: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G.J. 1941. Production and distribution theories. New York: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Veblen, T.B. 1900. The preconceptions of economic science III. Quarterly Journal of Economics 14: 240–269.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Copyright information

© 2018 Macmillan Publishers Ltd.

About this entry

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this entry

Aspromourgos, T. (2018). ‘Neoclassical’. In: The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_723

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics