Skip to main content

Agricultural Economics

  • Reference work entry
  • First Online:
  • 129 Accesses

Abstract

Agricultural economics arose in the late 19th century, combined the theory of the firm with marketing and organization theory, and developed throughout the 20th century largely as an empirical branch of general economics. The discipline was closely linked to empirical applications of mathematical statistics and made early and significant contributions to econometric methods. From the 1960s, as agricultural sectors in the OECD countries contracted, agricultural economists were drawn to the development problems of poor countries, to the trade and macroeconomic policy implications of agriculture in richer countries, and to a variety of issues in production, consumption, environmental and resource economics.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   6,499.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD   8,499.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Bibliography

  • Note: This article can only gesture to the agricultural economics literature. The reader is referred to L. R. Martin (general editor) and the four-volume Survey of Agricultural Economics Literature, Minneapolis, University of Minnesota Press, 1977–1987, and Wallace C. Olsen et al., Agricultural Economics and Rural Sociology: The Contemporary Core Literature, Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1991. A compilation of analytical and interpretive essays is B. L. Gardner and G. C. Rausser (eds.), Handbook of Agricultural Economics, vols. 1A, 1B, 2A and 2B, Amsterdam: North-Holland, 2002. An internet-based open source of information is AgEcon Search, maintained at the University of Minnesota: http://www.apec.umn.edu/AgEcon.html (accessed 16 August 2006).

  • Abbott, P., and A. McCalla. 2002. Agriculture in the macroeconomy. In Handbook of agricultural economics, ed. B. Gardner and G. Rausser, vol. 2A. Amsterdam: North- Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Allen, R. 1992. Enclosure and the yeoman. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Allen, D., and D. Lueck. 1998. The nature of the farm. Journal of Law and Economics 41: 343–386.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alston, J., G. Norton, and P. Pardey. 1998. Science under scarcity: Principles and practices for agricultural evaluation and priority setting. New York: CAB International.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alston, J., C. Chan-Kang, M. Marra, P. Pardey, and T. Wyatt. 2000. A meta- analysis of rates of return to agricultural R&D . Washington, DC: International Food Policy Research Institute.Research Report No. 113

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, K., and Y. Hayami. 1986. The political economy of agricultural protection: East Asia in international perspective. London: Allen and Unwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, J., J. Dillon, and B. Hardaker. 1977. Agricultural decision analysis. Ames: Iowa University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Antle, J. 1987. Econometric estimation of risk producers’ risk attitudes. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 69: 509–522.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ardeni, P., and J. Freebairn. 2002. The macroeconomics of agriculture. In Handbook of agricultural economics, ed. B. Gardner and G. Rausser, vol. 2A. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barrett, C.B. 2002. Food security and food assistance. In Handbook of agricultural economics, ed. B. Gardner and G. Rausser, vol. 2B. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beneke, R. 1998. T.W. Schultz and pamphlet No. 5: The oleo margarine war and academic freedom. Choices 2nd Quarter, 4–8.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berndt, E. 1991. The practice of econometrics: Classical and contemporary. Reading: Addison-Wesley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhide, S. 1994. The science of agricultural economics in India: Implications of Heady’s contributions. In Earl O. Heady: His impact on agricultural economics, ed. J. Langley, G. Vocke, and L. Whiting. Ames: Iowa State University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Binswanger, H. 1974. A microeconomic approach to induced innovation. Economic Journal 84: 940–958.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Black, J. 1926. Introduction to production economics. New York: Henry Holt and Co..

    Google Scholar 

  • Boussard, J., and M. Petit. 1967. Representation of farmers’ behavior under uncertainty with a focus loss constraint. Journal of Farm Economics 49: 869–880.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brewster, J. 1959. The impact of technical advance and migration on agricultural society and policy. Journal of Farm Economics 41: 1169–1184.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bromley, D. 1991. Environment and economy: Property rights and public policy. Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buck, J. 1943. An agricultural survey of Szechwan province. Chungking: Farmers Bank of China.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buck, J. 1973. Development of agricultural economics at the University of Nanking, Nanking, China 1920–1946, Agricultural Development Bulletin No. 25. Ithaca: Cornell University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buck, J., O. Dawson, and Y. Wu. 1966. Food and agriculture in communist China. New York: Praeger.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burt, O. 1966. Economic control of groundwater reserves. Journal of Farm Economics 48: 632–647.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burt, O., and J. Allison. 1963. Farm management decisions with dynamic programming. Journal of Farm Economics 45: 121–136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burt, O., and R. Cummings. 1970. Production and investment in natural resource industries. American Economic Review 60: 576–590.

    Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, K. 1985. Some reflections on the development of agricultural economics in Australia. In Agricultural economics in Australia, ed. S. Bearman. Armidale: Department of Agricultural Business and Management, University of New England.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caswell, M., E. Lichtenberg, and D. Zilberman. 1990. The effects of pricing policies on water conservation and drainage. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 72: 883–890.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chambers, R., and J. Quiggin. 1996. Non-point-source Pollution Regulation as a Multi-task principal–agent problem. Journal of Public Economics 59: 95–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chavas, J. 2002. Structural change in agricultural production, economics, technology and policy. In Handbook of agricultural economics, ed. B. Gardner and G. Rausser, vol. 1A. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chenery, H., and M. Syrquin. 1975. Development, 1950–1970. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ciriacy-Wantrup, S. 1952. Resource conservation – economics and policies. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cochrane, W. 1953. Professor Schultz discovers the weather. Journal of Farm Economics 35: 280–283.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cochrane, W. 1958. Farm prices: Myth and reality. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cochrane, W. 1983. Agricultural economics at the University of Minnesota 1886–1979, Miscellaneous publication no. 21. Institute of Agriculture, Forestry and Home Economics, University of Minnesota.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cochrane, W. 1993. The development of American agriculture: A historical analysis. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cochrane, W., and C. Runge. 1992. Reforming farm policy: Toward a national agenda. Ames: Iowa State University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crutchfield, J., and A. Zellner. 1962. Economic aspects of the Pacific halibut industry, Fishery Industrial Research No. 1. Washington, DC: United States Department of the Interior.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cummings, R., and D. Winkelmann. 1970. Water resource management in arid environs. Water Resources Research 6: 1559–1568.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Day, R. 1963. Recursive programming and production response. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Day, R., and E. Sparling. 1977. Optimization models in agricultural and resource economics. In A survey of agricultural economics literature, ed. L. Martin, vol. 2. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Haen, H., and T. Heidhues. 1973. Recursive programming models to simulate agricultural development – applications in West Germany, Working Paper No. 18. Göttingen: Institute for Agricultural Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dillon, J. 1971. An expository review of Bernoullian decision theory in agriculture: Is utility futility? Review of Marketing and Agricultural Economics 39: 3–80.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dillon, J., and P. Scandizzo. 1978. Risk attitudes of subsistence farmers in Northeast Brazil: A sampling approach. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 60: 425–435.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Egbert, A., and E. Heady. 1961. Regional adjustments in grain production: A linear programming analysis, Technical Bulletin No. 1241. Washington, DC: USDA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eltis, W. 1975. François Quesnay: A reinterpretation. 1. The Tableau Economique. Oxford Economic Papers 27: 167–200.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Evenson, R. 1967. The contribution of agricultural research to production. Journal of Farm Economics 49: 1415–1425.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Evenson, R., and Y. Kislev. 1976. A stochastic model of applied research. Journal of Political Economy 84: 265–281.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ezekiel, M. 1930. Methods of correlation analysis. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ezekiel, M. 1938. The cobweb theorem. Quarterly Journal of Economics 52: 255–280.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fox, K. 1953. A spatial equilibrium model of livestock-feed economy in the United States. Econometrica 21: 547–566.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galbraith, J. 1959. John D. Black: A portrait. In Economics for agriculture, ed. J. Cavin. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Georgescu-Roegen, N. 1960. Economic theory and agrarian economics. Oxford Economic Papers 12: 1–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giles, A. 2000. The AES, 1926–2001: A view from the archives. Journal of Agricultural Economics 52: 1–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goodwin, B., and V. Smith. 1995. The economics of crop insurance and disaster aid. Washington, DC: AEI Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gray, R., and D. Rutledge. 1971. The economics of commodity futures markets: a survey. Review of Marketing and Agricultural Economics 39: 57–108.

    Google Scholar 

  • Griliches, Z. 1957. Hybrid corn: An exploration in the economics of technological change. Econometrica 25: 501–522.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griliches, Z. 1958. Research costs and social returns: Hybrid corn and related innovations. Journal of Political Economy 66: 419–431.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griliches, Z. 1963. The sources of measured productivity growth: United States agriculture, 1940–1960. Journal of Political Economy 71: 331–346.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griliches, Z. 1964. Research expenditures, education, and the aggregate agricultural production function. American Economic Review 54: 961–974.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gustafson, R. 1958. Implications of recent research on optimal storage rules. Journal of Farm Economics 40: 290–300.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanf, C. 1988. Adjustment necessities in European agricultural economics research. European Review of Agricultural Economics 15: ix–xvi.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayami, Y., and V. Ruttan. 1971. Agricultural development: An international perspective. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hazell, P. 1971. A linear alternative to quadratic and semivariance programming for farm planning under uncertainty. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 53: 53–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heady, E. 1951. A production function and marginal rates of substitution in the utilization of feed resources by dairy cows. Journal of Farm Economics 33: 485–498.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heady, E., and W. Candler. 1958. Linear programming methods. Ames: Iowa State University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heady, E., and J. Dillon. 1961. Agricultural production functions. Ames: Iowa State University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heidhues, T. 1966. A recursive programming model of farm growth in northern Germany. Journal of Farm Economics 48: 668–684.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henderson, J. 1959. The utilization of agricultural land: a theoretical and empirical inquiry. The Review of Economics and Statistics 41: 242–259.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hertel, T., ed. 1997. Global trade analysis modeling and applications. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J. 1932. The theory of wages. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J. 1939. Value and capital: An inquiry into some fundamental principles of economic theory. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hildreth, C. 1957a. Problems of uncertainty in farm planning. Journal of Farm Economics 39: 1430–1441.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hildreth, C. 1957b. Some problems and possibilities of farm programming. In Fertilizer innovations and resource use, ed. E. Baum et al. Ames: Iowa State College Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hotelling, H. 1931. The economics of exhaustible resources. Journal of Political Economy 39: 137–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hueth, B., and E. Ligon. 2001. Agricultural markets as relative performance evaluation. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 83: 318–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huffman, W. 1974. Decision making: the role of education. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 56: 85–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huffman, W. 2002. Human capital, education and agriculture. In Handbook of agricultural economics, ed. B. Gardner and G. Rausser, vol. 1A. Amsterdam: North- Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jesness, O. 1923. The cooperative marketing of farm products. Philadelphia: Lippencott.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, D. 1977. Postwar policies relating to trade in agricultural products. In A survey of agricultural economics literature, ed. L. Martin. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jorgenson, D., and Z. Griliches. 1967. The explanation of productivity change. Review of Economic Studies 34: 249–283.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Judge, G., and T. Takayama. 1973. Studies in economic planning over space and time. Amsterdam: North–Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Just, R., and J. Antle. 1990. Interactions between agricultural and environmental Policies: A conceptual framework. American Economic Review 80: 197–202.

    Google Scholar 

  • Karp, L., and J. Perloff. 2002. A synthesis of agricultural trade economics. In Handbook of agricultural economics, ed. B. Gardner and G. Rausser, vol. 2B. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kerr, N. 1987. The legacy: A centennial history of the state agricultural experiment stations 1887–1987. Columbia: Missouri Agricultural Experiment Station.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kislev, Y., and W. Peterson. 1982. Prices, technology and farm size. Journal of Political Economy 90: 578–595.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klyukach, V. 2004. Stages in the formation and modern development of Russian agricultural economics. Ekonomika Sel’skokhozyaistvennykh I Pererabatyvayushchikh Predpriyatii 5: 10–13.

    Google Scholar 

  • Knoeber, C., and W. Thurman. 1995. ‘Don’t Count Your Chickens... ’: Risk and risk shifting in the broiler industry. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 77: 486–496.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kreuger, A., Schiff, M. and Valdes, A. 1991–94. The political economy of agricultural pricing policy, 4 vols. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lau, L., and P. Yotopoulos. 1971. A test for relative efficiency and application to Indian agriculture. American Economic Review 61: 94–109.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leontief, W. 1971. Theoretical assumptions and non-observed facts. American Economic Review 61: 1–7.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewis, W. 1954. Economic development with unlimited supplies of labour. The Manchester School 22: 3–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lichtenberg, E. 2002. Agriculture and the environment. In Handbook of agricultural economics, ed. B. Gardner and G. Rausser, vol. 2A. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, A. 1890. Principles of economics. 1st ed. London: Macmillan and Co..

    Google Scholar 

  • Mellor, J. 1966. The economics of agricultural production. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller, G. 1985. Agricultural economics in Canberra. In Agricultural economics in Australia, ed. S. Bearman. Armidale: Department of Agricultural Business and Management, University of New England.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miranda, M., and J. Glauber. 1997. Systematic risk, reinsurance, and the failure of crop insurance markets. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 79: 206–215.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moore, G. 1988. The involvement of experiment stations in secondary agricultural education, 1887–1917. Agricultural History 62: 164–176.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moscardi, E., and A. de Janvry. 1977. Attitudes toward risk among peasants: An econometric approach. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 59: 710–716.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moschini, G., and D. Hennessey. 2002. Uncertainty, risk aversion and risk management for agricultural producers. In Handbook of agricultural economics, ed. B. Gardner and G. Rausser, vol. 2B. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Myers, R. 1989. Econometric testing for risk averse behavior in agriculture. Applied Economics 21: 542–552.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myers, W.H., A. Womack, S. Johnson, J. Brandt, and R. Young. 1987. Impacts of alternative programs indicated by FAPRI analysis. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 69: 972–979.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nazarenko, V. 2004. Conflict in Soviet agricultural economics in the 1920s and 1930s. Ekonomika Sel’skokhozyaistvennykh I Pererabatyvayushchikh Predpriyatii 6: 8–11.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R., and E. Phelps. 1966. Investment in humans, technological diffusion, and economic growth. American Economic Review 56 (2): 69–75.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nerlove, M. 1958. The dynamics of supply, estimation of farmers response to price. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Newbury, D., and J. Stiglitz. 1981. The theory of commodity price stabilization – a study in the economics of risk. Oxford: Clarendon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nou, J. 1967. Studies in the development of agricultural economics in Europe. Uppsala: Almquist and Wiksells.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olsen, W., et al. 1991. Agricultural economics and rural sociology: The contemporary core literature. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peterson, W. 1967. Return to poultry research in the United States. Journal of Farm Economics 49: 656–669.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peterson, W. 1969. The allocation of research, teaching and extension personnel in U.S. colleges of agriculture. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 51: 41–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peterson, W., and Y. Hayami. 1977. Technical change in agriculture. In A survey of agricultural economics literature, ed. L. Martin, vol. 1. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Petit, M. 1982. Is there a french school of agricultural e? Journal of Agricultural Economics 23: 325–337.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Quesnay, F. 1758. The economical table. Milton Keynes: Lightning Source Books. 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  • Raeburn, J., and J. Jones. 1990. The history of the international association of agricultural economists. Brookfield: Gower Publishing Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ricardo, D. 1821. The principles of political economy and taxation. London: M. Dent and Sons. 1911.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roumasset, J. 1976. Rice and risk: Decisionmaking among low income farmers. Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Runge, C. 1981. Common property externalities: isolation, assurance and resource depletion in a traditional grazing context. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 63 (4): 595–606.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Runge, C. 1987. Induced agricultural innovation and environmental quality: the case of groundwater regulation. Land Economics 63: 249–258.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Runge, C., B. Senauer, P. Pardey, and M. Rosegrant. 2003. Ending hunger in our lifetime: Food security and globalization. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ruttan, V. 1956. The contribution of technological progress to farm output, 1950–75. The Review of Economics and Statistics 38: 61–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. 1947. Foundations of economic analysis. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmitz, A., and D. Seckler. 1970. Mechanized agriculture and social welfare: the case of the tomato harvester. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 52: 569–577.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schuh, G. 1974. The exchange rate and U.S. agriculture. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 56: 1–13.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schuh, G. 1976. The new macroeconomics of agriculture. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 58: 802–811.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schultz, T. 1953. The economic organization of agriculture. New York: McGraw Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schultz, T. 1964. Transforming traditional agriculture. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schultz, T. 1971. Investment in human capital. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scott, A. 1955. The fishery: The objectives of sole ownership. Journal of Political Economy 63: 116–124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Segerson, K. 1988. Uncertainty and incentives for nonpoint pollution control. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 15 (1): 87–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sexton, R. 1990. Imperfect competition in agricultural markets and the role of Cooperatives: a spatial analysis. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 72: 709–720.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sexton, R., and N. Lavoie. 2002. Food processing and distribution: An industrial organization approach. In Handbook of agricultural economics, ed. B. Gardner and G. Rausser, vol. 2B. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A. 1776. An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations. Indianapolis: Liberty Classics. 1981.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Sumner, D., and S. Tangermann. 2002. International trade policy and negotiations. In Handbook of agricultural economics, ed. B. Gardner and G. Rausser, vol. 2B. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sunding, D., and D. Zilberman. 2002. The agricultural innovation process: Research and technology adoption in a changing agricultural sector. In Handbook of agricultural economics, ed. B. Gardner and G. Rausser, vol. 1A. Amsterdam: North- Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, H. 1905. An introduction to the study of agricultural economics. New York: Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, H. 1922. The history of the development of the Farm Economic Association. Journal of Farm Economics 4 (2): 92–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, H., and A. Taylor. 1952. The story of agricultural economics in the United States, 1940–1932. Ames: Iowa State University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Timmer, C. 2002. Agriculture and economic development. In Handbook of agricultural economics, ed. B. Gardner and G. Rausser, vol. 2A. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tolley, H., Black, J. and Ezekiel, M. 1924. Input as related to output in farm organization and cost of production studies, Bulletin no. 1277. Washington, DC: USDA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tomek, W., and K. Robinson. 1977. Agricultural price analysis and outlook. In A survey of agricultural economics literature, ed. L. Martin, vol. 1. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Veblen, T. 1900. The preconception of economic science, III. Quarterly Journal of Economics 14: 240–269.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Von Thünen, J. 1828. Isolated state (English translation). Oxford: Oxford University Press. 1966.

    Google Scholar 

  • Walker, J., R. Gardner, and E. Ostrom. 2000. Collective choice in the commons: experimental results on proposed allocation rules and votes. Economic Journal 110: 212–234.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Waugh, F. 1928. Quality factors influencing vegetable prices. Journal of Farm Economics 10 (2): 185–196.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Waugh, F. 1951. The minimum-cost dairy feed. Journal of Farm Economics 33: 299–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Working, H. 1922. Factors determining the price of potatoes in St. Paul and Minneapolis, Agricultural experiment station technical bulletin no. 10. University of Minnesota.

    Google Scholar 

  • Working, H. 1925. The Statistical determination of demand curves. Quarterly Journal of Economics 39 : 503–543.August

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Working, E. 1927. What do statistical ‘demand curves’ show? Quarterly Journal of Economics 41: 212–235.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wright, B. 2002. Storage and price stabilization. In Handbook of agricultural economics, ed. B. Gardner and G. Rausser, vol. 1B. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Copyright information

© 2018 Macmillan Publishers Ltd.

About this entry

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this entry

Runge, C.F. (2018). Agricultural Economics. In: The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_655

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics