The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics

2018 Edition
| Editors: Macmillan Publishers Ltd

Cumulative Causation

  • Carlos J. Ricoy
Reference work entry
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_550

Abstract

The notion of ‘cumulative causation’ constitutes a basic hypothesis on the workings of the market mechanism. The operation of markets is conceived as a continuous process in which economic forces interact upon one another in a cumulative way, thus making for changes in one direction to induce supporting changes which push the system further away from its initial position. In essence, this is the notion which Myrdal refers to as the ‘principle of circular and cumulative causation’ and which plays an organizing role in his analysis of ‘uneven development’ (Myrdal 1957).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in to check access

Bibliography

  1. Arrow, K.J. 1962. The economic implications of learning by doing. Review of Economic Studies 28(3): 155–173.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Cornwall, J. 1977. Modern capitalism: Its growth and transformation. Oxford: Martin Robertson.Google Scholar
  3. Cripps, F., and R. Tarling. 1973. Growing in advanced capitalist economies, 1950–1970. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  4. Dosi, G. 1984. Technical change and industrial transformation. London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Eatwell, J. 1982. Whatever happened to Britain? London: Duckworth..Google Scholar
  6. Hirchman, A. 1958. The strategy of economic development. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  7. Kaldor, N. 1966. Causes of the slow rate of economic growth of the United Kingdom. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  8. ———. 1967. Strategic factors in economic development. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
  9. ———. 1970. The case for regional policies. Scottish Journal of Political Economy 17(3), November, 337–348.Google Scholar
  10. ———. 1972. The irrelevance of equilibrium economics. Economic Journal 82: 1237–1255.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. ———. 1974. Teoria del equilibrio y teoria del crecimiento. Cuadernos de Economica. (Reprinted in translation in Economics and human welfare: Essays in honour of T. Scitovsky, ed. M.J. Boskin, London: Academic Press. 1979).Google Scholar
  12. ———. 1975. Economic growth and the Verdoorn Law: comment on Mr. Rowthorn’s article. Economic Journal 85, December, 891–6.Google Scholar
  13. ———. 1978a. Further essays on economic theory. London: Duckworth.Google Scholar
  14. ———. 1978b. Further essays on applied economics. London: Duckworth.Google Scholar
  15. ———. 1981a. Discussion. In Macroeconomic analysis, ed. D. Currie, R. Nobay, and D. Peel. London: Croom Helm.Google Scholar
  16. ———. 1981b. The role of increasing returns, technical progress and cumulative causation in the theory of international trade and economic growth. Economie Appliquée 34(4): 593–617.Google Scholar
  17. ———. 1985. Economics without equilibrium. Cardiff: University College Cardiff Press.Google Scholar
  18. Kalecki, M. 1966. Studies in the theory of business cycles 1933–1939. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
  19. Myrdal, G. 1957. Economic theory and underdeveloped regions. London: Duckworth.Google Scholar
  20. Nelson, R., and S. Winter. 1982. An evolutionary theory of economic change. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  21. Nurkse, R. 1953. Problems of capital formation in underdeveloped countries. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  22. Pasinetti, L. 1981. Structural change and economic growth. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  23. Prebisch, R. 1950. The economic development of Latin America and its principal problems. New York: United Nations.Google Scholar
  24. ———. 1959. Commercial policy in underdeveloped countries. American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 49, May, 251–273.Google Scholar
  25. Robinson, J. 1962. Essays in the theory of economic growth. London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. ———. 1965. The new mercantilism. In Collected economic papers of Joan Robinson. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
  27. Rosenberg, N. 1976. Perspectives on technology. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. ———. 1982. Inside the black box: Technology and economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  29. Sayers, R.S. 1965. The vicissitudes of an export economy: Britain since 1880. Sydney: University of Sidney.Google Scholar
  30. Schmookler, J. 1966. Invention and economic growth. Cambridge, MA.: Harvard, University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Singh, A. 1977. U.K. industry and the world economy: a case of de-industrialisation? Cambridge Journal of Economics 1(2), June, 113–36.Google Scholar
  32. ———. 1978. North Sea oil and the reconstruction of the UK industry. In De-Industrialisation, ed. F. Blackby. London: Heinemann.Google Scholar
  33. Smith, A. 1776. In An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations, ed. E. Cannan. London: Methuen 1904.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Stigler, G. 1951. The division of labour is limited by the extent of the market. Journal of Political Economy 59, June, 185–93.Google Scholar
  35. Svennilson, I. 1954. Growth and stagnation in the European economy. Geneva: UN Economic Commission for Europe.Google Scholar
  36. Symposium. 1983. Kaldor’s Laws. Journal of Post-Keynesian Economics 5(3): 341–429.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Thirlwall, A.P. 1980. Balance of payments theory and the United Kingdom experience. London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Vernon, R. 1966. International investment and international trade in the product cycle. Quarterly Journal of Economics 80, May, 190–207.Google Scholar
  39. Young, A. 1928. Increasing returns and economic progress. Economic Journal 38: 527–542.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 2018

Authors and Affiliations

  • Carlos J. Ricoy
    • 1
  1. 1.