The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics

2018 Edition
| Editors: Macmillan Publishers Ltd

Finance

  • Stephen A. Ross
Reference work entry
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_514

Abstract

The neoclassical theory of finance is based on the study of (a) efficient markets, meaning markets that use all available information in setting prices, (b) the trade-off between return and risk, (c) option pricing and the principle of no arbitrage, and (d) corporate finance, that is, the structure of financial claims issued by companies. This article surveys these theories and their empirical support and it also identifies certain empirical regularities unexplained by the neoclassical theory that are being addressed by theories of asymmetric information.

Keywords

Arbitrage Arbitrage pricing theory Arrow-Debreu model Asymmetric information Black-Scholes model Capital asset pricing model Consumption beta model Corporate finance Corporate taxation Efficiency Efficient markets hypothesis Finance Hicks, J. Interest rates Martingales Mean variance analysis Merton, R. Modigliani-Miller theorem Option pricing Pareto efficiency Principal and agent Productive efficiency Rational expectations Risk and return Risk premium Security market line equation Signalling models Tobin, J. von Neumann-Morgenstern utility function 
This is a preview of subscription content, log in to check access

Bibliography

  1. Admati, A. 1985. A noisy rational expectations equilibrium for multi-asset securities markets. Econometrica 53 (3): 629–657.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Bhattacharya, S. 1979. Imperfect information, dividend policy and the ‘bird in the hand’ fallacy. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 10 (1): 259–270.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Black, F. 1972. Capital market equilibrium with restricted borrowing. Journal of Business 45 (3): 444–455.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Black, F., and M. Scholes. 1972. The valuation of option contracts and a test of market efficiency. Journal of Finance 27 (2): 399–417.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Black, F., and M. Scholes. 1973. The pricing of options and corporate liabilities. Journal of Political Economy 81 (3): 637–654.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Black, F., and M. Scholes. 1974. The effects of dividend yield and dividend policy on common stock prices and returns. Journal of Financial Economics 1 (1): 1–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Black, F., M. Jensen, and M. Scholes. 1972. The capital asset pricing model: Some empirical tests. In Studies in the theory of capital markets, ed. M.C. Jensen. New York: Praeger.Google Scholar
  8. Breeden, D.T. 1979. An intertemporal asset pricing model with stochasticconsumption and investment opportunities. Journal of Financial Economics 7 (3): 265–296.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Brennan, M.J., and E.S. Schwartz. 1977. The valuation of American put options. Journal of Finance 32 (2): 449–462.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Brown, S., and M. Weinstein. 1983. A new approach to testing asset pricing models: The bilinear paradigm. Journal of Finance 38 (3): 711–743.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Cass, D., and J. Stiglitz. 1970. The structure of investor preferences and asset returns, and separatability in portfolio selection: A contribution to the pure theory of mutual funds. Journal of Economic Theory 2 (2): 122–160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Chamberlain, G. 1983. Funds, factors and diversification in arbitrage pricing models. Econometrica 51 (5): 1305–1323.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Chamberlain, G., and M. Rothschild. 1983. Arbitrage, factor structure and mean-variance analysis on large asset markets. Econometrica 51 (5): 1281–1304.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Chen, N., R. Roll, and S.A. Ross. 1986. Economic forces and the stock market. Journal of Business 59: 383–403.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Chiras, D.P., and S. Manaster. 1978. The information content of option prices and a testofmarketefficiency. Journal of Financial Economics 6 (2–3): 213–234.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Connor, G. 1984. A unified beta pricing theory. Journal of Economic Theory 34 (1): 13–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Cootner, P., ed. 1964. The random character of stock market prices. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  18. Cowles, A. 1933. Can stock market forecasters forecast? Econometrica 1: 309–324.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Cox, J.C., and S.A. Ross. 1976a. The valuation of options for alternative stochastic processes. Journal of Financial Economics 3 (1–2): 145–166.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Cox, J.C., and S.A. Ross. 1976b. A survey of some new results in financial option pricing theory. Journal of Finance 31 (2): 383–402.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Cox, J.C., S.A. Ross, and M. Rubinstein. 1979. Option pricing: A simplified approach. Journal of Financial Economics 7 (3): 229–263.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Cox, J.C., J. Ingersoll, and S.A. Ross. 1985a. An intertemporal general equilibrium model of asset prices. Econometrica 53 (2): 363–384.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Cox, J.C., J. Ingersoll, and S.A. Ross. 1985b. A theory of the term structure of interest rates. Econometrica 53 (2): 385–407.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Diamond, D., and R. Verrecchia. 1981. Information aggregation in a noisy rational expectations economy. Journal of Financial Economics 9 (3): 221–235.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Dybvig, P. 1983. An explicit bound on deviations from APT pricing in a finite economy. Journal of Financial Economics 12 (4): 483–496.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Dybvig, P., and S.A. Ross. 1985. Yes, the APT is testable. Journal of Finance 40 (4): 1173–1188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Fama, E.F. 1970. Efficient capital markets: A review of theory and empirical work. Journal of Finance 25 (2): 383–417.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Fama, E.F., and J. MacBeth. 1973. Risk, return and equilibrium: Empirical tests. Journal of Political Economy 81 (3): 607–636.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Fama, E.F., L. Fisher, M. Jensen, and R. Roll. 1969. The adjustment of stock prices to new information. International Economic Review 10 (1): 1–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Flavin, M. 1983. Excess volatility in the financial markets: A reassessment of the empirical evidence. Journal of Political Economy 91 (6): 929–956.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. French, K. 1980. Stock returns and the weekend effect. Journal of FinancialEconomics 8 (1): 55–69.Google Scholar
  32. French, K., and R. Roll 1985. Stock return variances, the arrival of information and the reaction of traders. UCLA Working Paper.Google Scholar
  33. Galai, D. 1977. Tests of market efficiency of the Chicago Board Options Exchange. Journal of Business 50 (2): 167–197.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Geske, R. 1979. A note on an analytical valuation formula for unprotected American call options on stocks with known dividends. Journal of Financial Economics 7 (4): 375–380.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Geske, R., and R. Roll. 1984. Isolating the observed biases in call option pricing: An alternative variance estimator. UCLA Working Paper, April.Google Scholar
  36. Gibbons, M. 1982. Multivariate tests of financial models: A new approach. Journal of Financial Economics 10 (1): 3–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Gibbons, M., S.A. Ross, and J. Shanken. 1986. A test of the efficiency of a given portfolio. Stanford University Working Paper No. 853.Google Scholar
  38. Granger, C.W.J., and O. Morgenstern. 1962. Spectral analysis of New York stock market prices. Econometric Research Program, Princeton University, Research Memorandum, September.Google Scholar
  39. Grossman, S.J. 1976. On the efficiency of competitive stock markets where traders have diverse information. Journal of Finance 31 (2): 573–585.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Grossman, S.J., and O. Hart. 1980. Takeover bids, the free-rider problem, and the theory of the corporation. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 11 (1): 42–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Grossman, S.J., and J. Stiglitz. 1980. The impossibility of informationally efficient markets. American Economic Review 70: 393–408.Google Scholar
  42. Hamada, R.S. 1972. The effect of the firm’s capital structure on the systematic risk of common stocks. Journal of Finance 27 (2): 435–452.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  43. Hansen, L., and R. Singleton. 1983. Stochastic consumption, risk aversion and the temporal behavior of asset returns. Journal of Political Economy 91 (2): 249–265.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Harrison, J.M., and D.M. Kreps. 1979. Martingales and arbitrage in multiperiod securities markets. Journal of Economic Theory 20 (3): 381–408.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  45. Hicks, J.R. 1946. Value and capital. 2nd ed. London: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  46. Huberman, G. 1982. A simple approach to arbitrage pricing theory. Journal of Economic Theory 28 (1): 183–191.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  47. Ingersoll, J. 1977. A contingent-claims valuation of convertible securities. Journal of Financial Economics 4 (3): 289–322.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  48. Ingersoll, J. 1984. Some results in the theory of arbitrage pricing. Journal of Finance 39 (4): 1021–1039.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  49. Jaffé, J. 1974. The effect of regulation changes on insider trading. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 5 (1): 93–121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  50. Jensen, M.C., and W.H. Meckling. 1976. Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3 (4): 305–360.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  51. Jensen, M.C., and R.S. Ruback. 1983. The market for corporate control: The scientific evidence. Journal of Financial Economics 11 (1–4): 5–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  52. Jobson, J.D., and B. Korkie. 1982. Potential performance and tests of portfolioefficiency. Journal of Financial Economics 10 (4): 433–466.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  53. Kandel, S. 1984. On the exclusion of assets from tests of the mean variance efficiency of the market portfolio. Journal of Finance 39 (1): 63–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  54. Keim, D. 1983. Size-related anomalies and stock return seasonality: Further empirical evidence. Journal of Financial Economics 12 (1): 13–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  55. Kleidon, A. 1986. Variance bounds tests and stock price valuation models. Journal of Political Economy 94 (5): 953–1001.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  56. Leland, H., and D. Pyle. 1977. Informational asymmetries, financial structure andfinancial intermediation. Journal of Finance 32 (2): 371–387.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  57. Lintner, J. 1965. The valuation of risk assets and the selection of risky investmentsin stock portfolios and capital budgets. Review of Economics and Statistics 47: 13–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  58. Litzenberger, R., and K. Ramaswamy. 1982. The effect of dividends on common stock prices: Tax effects or information effects? Journal of Finance 37 (2): 429–443.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  59. Lucas, R.E. Jr. 1978. Asset prices in an exchange economy. Econometrica 46 (6): 1429–1445.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  60. MacBeth, J., and L. Merville. 1979. An empirical examination of the Black-Scholes call option pricing model. Journal of Finance 34 (5): 1173–1186.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  61. Malkiel, B. 1966. The term structure of interest rates: Expectations and behavior patterns. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  62. Markowitz, H.M. 1959. Portfolio selection: Efficient diversification of investments. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
  63. Marsh, T., and R.C. Merton. 1986. Dividend variability and variance bounds tests for the rationality of stock market prices. American Economic Review 76 (3): 483–498.Google Scholar
  64. Merton, R.C. 1973a. An intertemporal capital asset pricing model. Econometrica 41 (5): 867–887.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  65. Merton, R.C. 1973b. Theory of rational option pricing. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 4 (1): 141–183.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  66. Milgrom, P., and N. Stokey. 1982. Information, trade and common knowledge. Journal of Economic Theory 26 (1): 17–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  67. Miller, M.H. 1977. Debt and taxes. Journal of Finance 32 (2): 261–275.Google Scholar
  68. Miller, M.H., and M. Scholes. 1978. Dividends and taxes. Journal of Financial Economics 6 (4): 333–364.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  69. Modigliani, F., and M.H. Miller. 1958. The cost of capital, corporation finance, and the theory of investment. American Economic Review 48: 261–297.Google Scholar
  70. Modigliani, F., and M.H. Miller. 1963. Corporate income taxes and the cost of capital. American Economic Review 53: 433–443.Google Scholar
  71. Mossin, J. 1966. Equilibrium in a capital asset market. Econometrica 34 (4): 768–783.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  72. Myers, S. 1977. Determinants of corporate borrowing. Journal of FinancialEconomics 5 (2): 147–175.Google Scholar
  73. Parkinson, M. 1977. Option pricing: The American put. Journal of Business 50 (1): 21–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  74. Patell, J.M., and M.A. Wolfson. 1979. Anticipated information releases reflected in call option prices. Journal of Accounting and Economics 1 (2): 117–140.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  75. Roll, R. 1970. The behavior of interest rates: An application of the efficient market model to US treasury bills. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
  76. Roll, R. 1977a. An analytic valuation formula for unprotected American call options on stocks with known dividends. Journal of Financial Economics 5 (2): 251–258.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  77. Roll, R. 1977b. A critique of the asset pricing theory’s tests. Journal of Financial Economics 4 (2): 129–176.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  78. Roll, R. 1978. Ambiguity when performance is measured by the securities market line. Journal of Finance 33 (4): 1051–1069.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  79. Roll, R. 1981. A possible explanation of the small firm effect. Journal of Finance 36 (4): 879–888.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  80. Roll, R. 1983. The turn-of-the-year effect and small firm premium. Journal of Portfolio Management 9 (2): 18–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  81. Roll, R. 1984. Orange juice and weather. American Economic Review 74 (5): 861–880.Google Scholar
  82. Roll, R., and S.A. Ross. 1980. An empirical investigation of the arbitrage pricing theory. Journal of Finance 35 (5): 1073–1103.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  83. Ross, S.A. 1973. The economic theory of agency: The principal’s problem. American Economic Review 63 (2): 134–139.Google Scholar
  84. Ross, S.A. 1975. Uncertainty and the heterogeneous capital good model. Review of Economic Studies 42 (1): 133–146.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  85. Ross, S.A. 1976a. Return, risk and arbitrage. In Risk and return in finance, ed. I. Friend and J. Bicksler. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger.Google Scholar
  86. Ross, S.A. 1976b. The arbitrage theory of capital asset pricing. Journal of Economic Theory 13 (3): 341–360.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  87. Ross, S.A. 1976c. Options and efficiency. Quarterly Journal of Economics 90 (1): 75–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  88. Ross, S.A. 1977a. The determination of financial structure: The incentive signalling approach. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 8 (1): 23–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  89. Ross, S.A. 1977b. The capital asset pricing model (CAPM), short-sale restrictions and related issues. Journal of Finance 32 (1): 177–183.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  90. Ross, S.A. 1978a. Mutual fund separation in financial theory – The separating distributions. Journal of Economic Theory 17 (2): 254–286.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  91. Ross, S.A. 1978b. A simple approach to the valuation of risky streams. Journal of Business 51 (3): 453–475.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  92. Rubinstein, M. 1976. The valuation of uncertain income streams and the pricing of options. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 7 (2): 407–425.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  93. Shanken, J. 1982. The arbitrage pricing theory: Is it testable? Journal of Finance 37 (5): 1129–1140.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  94. Sharpe, W. 1964. Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk. Journal of Finance 19: 425–442.Google Scholar
  95. Shiller, R. 1981. Do stock prices move too much to be justified by subsequent changes in dividends? American Economic Review 71 (3): 421–436.Google Scholar
  96. Tobin, J. 1958. Liquidity preference as behavior towards risk. Review of Economic Studies 25: 65–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  97. Williamson, O.E. 1975. Markets and hierarchies: Analysis and antitrust implications. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
  98. Wilson, R.B. 1968. The theory of syndicates. Econometrica 36 (1): 119–132.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 2018

Authors and Affiliations

  • Stephen A. Ross
    • 1
  1. 1.