The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics

2018 Edition
| Editors: Macmillan Publishers Ltd

Distortions

  • T. N. Srinivasan
Reference work entry
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_409

Abstract

The voluminous literature on distortions, including a masterly survey by Jagdish Bhagwati (1971), contains no formal definition of the term distortion. The analysis often proceeds in terms of specific examples. Bhagwati analyses distortions in the context of foreign trade policies and the welfare of home consumers. He characterizes distortions as departures from the equality of the marginal rate of transformation of one commodity into some other through foreign trade (the so-called foreign rate of transformation) with transformation through domestic production (the domestic rate of transformation) and with the marginal rate of substitution in the consumption of the same pair of commodities by each consumer. Also, the failure to achieve aggregate production efficiency, in the sense of not producing on the boundary of the set of production possibilities given available resources and technology, is deemed a distortion.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in to check access.

Bibliography

  1. Arrow, K.J. 1964/1970. Political and economic evaluation of social effects and externalities. In Analysis of public output, ed. J. Margolis. New York: National Bureau for Economic Research.Google Scholar
  2. Atkinson, A.B.., and J.E. Stiglitz. 1980. Lectures on public economics. New York: McGraw Hill.Google Scholar
  3. Bhagwati, J.N. 1968. Distortions and immiserizing growth: A generalization. Review of Economic Studies 35: 481–485.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Bhagwati, J.N. 1971. The generalized theory of distortions and welfare. Chapter 12 in Trade, balance of payments and growth: Papers in international economics in honor of Charles P. Kindleberger, ed. J.N. Bhagwati, R.W. Jones, R. Mundell, and J. Vanek. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
  5. Bhagwati, J.N. 1982. Directly unproductive profit – Seeking (DUP) activities. Journal of Political Economy 90: 988–1002.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Bhagwati, J.N., and T.N. Srinivasan. 1969. Optimal intervention to achieve non-economic objectives. Review of Economic Studies 36: 27–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Guesnerie, R. 1979. General statements on second best Pareto optimality. Journal of Mathematical Economics 6: 169–194.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Guesnerie, R. 1980. Second-best policy rules in Boiteux tradition. Journal of Public Economics 13: 51–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Harris, J.R., and M.P. Todaro. 1970. Migration, unemployment and development: A two sector analysis. American Economic Review 60: 126–142.Google Scholar
  10. Johnson, H.G. 1965. Optimal trade intervention in the presence of domestic distortions. Chapter 11 in Trade, growth and the balance of payments, ed. R.E. Caves, H.G. Johnson, and P.B. Kenen. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
  11. Krueger, A. 1974. The political economy of the rent-seeking society. American Economic Review 64: 291–303.Google Scholar
  12. Lipsey, R.G., and K. Lancaster. 1956. The general theory of the second-best. Review of Economic Studies 24: 11–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Magee, S.P. 1976. International trade and distortions in factor markets. New York: Marcell Dekker.Google Scholar
  14. Srinivasan, T.N., and J.N. Bhagwati. 1978. Shadow prices for project selection in the presence of distortions: Effective rates of protection and domestic resource costs. Journal of Political Economy 86: 97–116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 2018

Authors and Affiliations

  • T. N. Srinivasan
    • 1
  1. 1.