The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics

2018 Edition
| Editors: Macmillan Publishers Ltd

Austrian Economics

  • Israel M. Kirzner
Reference work entry
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_301

Abstract

The birth of the Austrian School of economics is usually recognized as having occurred with the 1871 publication of Carl Menger’s Grundsätze der Volkwirthschaftslehre. On the basis of this work Menger (hitherto a civil servant) became a junior faculty member at the University of Vienna. Several years later, after a stint as tutor and travelling companion to Crown Prince Rudolph, he was appointed to a professorial chair at the University. Two younger economists, Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk and Friedrich von Wieser (neither of whom had been a student of Menger), became enthusiastic supporters of the new ideas put forward in Menger’s book. During the 1880s a vigorous outpouring of literature from these two followers, from several of Menger’s students, and in particular a methodological work by Menger himself, brought the ideas of Menger and his followers to the attention of the international community of economists. The Austrian School was now a recognized entity. Several works of Böhm-Bawerk and Wieser were translated into English; and by 1890 the editors of the US journal Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science were asking Böhm-Bawerk for an expository paper explaining the doctrines of the new school. What follows seeks to provide a concise survey of the history of the Austrian School with special emphasis on (a) the major representatives of the school; (b) the central ideas identified with the school; (c) the relationship between the school and its ideas, and other major schools of thought within economics; (d) the various meanings and perceptions associated today with the term Austrian economics.

Keywords

Austrian capital theory Austrian economics Austrian School Austrian theory of the business cycle Böhm-Bawerk, E. von Exploitation German Historical School Haberler, G. Hayek, F. A. von Higher-order goods Jaffé, W. Jevons, W. S. Labour theory of value Lange, O. R. Libertarianism Machlup, F. Marginal productivity theory Marginal revolution Marginal utility Marginalism Market process Marxist economics Mayer, H. Menger, C. Methodenstreit Methodological individualism Methodological subjectivism Mises, L. E. von Morgenstern, O. Non-market prices Opportunity cost Robbins, L. C. Rosenstein-Rodan, P. N. Rothbard, M. N. Roundabout production processes Schams, E. Schonfield, L. Schumpeter, J. A. Shackle, G. L. S. Socialist calculation debate Strigl, R. Subjective theory of value Surplus value Time preference Uncertainty Utility Value and price Walras, L. Wicksell, J. G. K. Wieser, F. F. von 

JEL Classifications

B2 
This is a preview of subscription content, log in to check access.

Bibliography

  1. Bernholz, P. 1971. Superiority of roundabout processes and positive rate of interest. A simple model of capital and growth. Kyklos 24: 687–721.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Bernholz, P., and M. Faber. 1973. Technical superiority of roundabout processes and positive rate of interest. A capital model with depreciation and n-period horizon. Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswissenschaften 129: 46–61.Google Scholar
  3. Bostaph, S. 1978. The methodological debate between Carl Menger and the German historicists. Atlantic Economic Journal 6 (3): 3–16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Bukharin, N. 1914. The economic theory of the Leisure class (trans: from Russian, London: M. Lawrence, 1927; reprinted). New York: Monthly Review Press, 1972.Google Scholar
  5. Faber, M. 1979. Introduction to modern Austrian capital theory. Berlin: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Garrison, R.W. 1978. Austrian macroeconomics: A diagrammatical exposition. In New directions in Austrian economics, ed. L.M. Spadaro. Kansas City: Sheed, Andrews & McMeel.Google Scholar
  7. Garrison, R.W. 1982. Austrian economics as the middle ground: Comment on Loasby. In Method, process, and Austrian economics: Essays in honor of Ludwig von Mises, ed. I.M. Kirzner. Lexington: Lexington Books.Google Scholar
  8. Garrison, R.W. 1985. Time and money: The universals of macroeconomic theorizing. Journal of Macroeconomics 6: 197–213.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Grassl, W., and B. Smith, eds. 1986. Austrian economics, historical and philosophical background. New York: New York University Press.Google Scholar
  10. Gross, G. 1884. Die Lehre von Unternehmergewinn. Leipzig: Duncker & Humblot.Google Scholar
  11. Hausman, D.M. 1981. Capital, profits, and prices. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
  12. Hayek, F.A. 1931. Prices and production. London: Routledge & Sons.Google Scholar
  13. Hayek, F.A. 1933. Monetary theory and the trade cycle. London: Jonathan Cape.Google Scholar
  14. Hayek, F.A. 1939. Profits, interest and investment: And other essays on the theory of industrial fluctuations. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
  15. Hayek, F.A. 1949. Individualism and economic order. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
  16. Hayek, F.A. 1968. Economic thought VI: The Austrian school. In International encyclopedia of the social sciences, ed. D.L. Sills. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  17. Hicks, J. 1973. Capital and time: A neo-Austrian theory. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
  18. Hicks, J.R., and W. Weber. 1973. Carl Menger and the Austrian school of economics. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
  19. Jaffé, W. 1976. Menger, Jevons and Walras de-homogenized. Economic Inquiry 14: 511–524.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Jevons, W.S. 1871. The theory of political economy. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  21. Kauder, E. 1965. A history of marginal utility theory. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Kirzner, I.M. 1973. Competition and entrepreneurship. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  23. Kirzner, I.M. 1981. Mises and the renaissance of Austrian economics. In Homage to mises, the first hundred years, ed. J.K. Andrews Jr. Hillsdale: Hillsdale College Press.Google Scholar
  24. Kirzner, I.M. 1985. Comment on R.N. Langlois, ‘From the knowledge of economics to the economics of knowledge: Fritz Machlup on methodology and on the “knowledge society”’. In Research in the history of economic thought and methodology, ed. Warren J. Samuels. Greenwich: JAI.Google Scholar
  25. Lachmann, L. 1973. Macro-economic thinking and the market economy. London: Institute of Economic Affairs.Google Scholar
  26. Lachmann, L. 1976. From Mises to Shackle: An essay on Austrian economics and the Kaleidic Society. Journal of Economic Literature 14: 54–62.Google Scholar
  27. Lachmann, L. 1977. Austrian economics in the present crisis of economic thought. In Capital, expectations, and the market process. Kansas City: Sheed, Andrews & McMeel.Google Scholar
  28. Lachmann, L. 1986a. Austrian economics under fire: The Hayek-Sraffa duel in retrospect. In Grassl and Smith (1986).Google Scholar
  29. Lachmann, L. 1986b. The market as a process. Oxford: Basic Blackwell.Google Scholar
  30. Lavoie, D. 1985. Rivalry and central planning: The socialist calculation debate reconsidered. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  31. Leser, N., ed. 1986. Die Wiener Schule der Nationalökonomie. Vienna: Hermann Böhlau.Google Scholar
  32. Machlup, F. 1981. Ludwig von Mises: The academic scholar who would not compromise. Wirtschaftspolitischen Blätter 28 (4): 6–14.Google Scholar
  33. Machlup, F. 1982. Austrian economics. In Encyclopedia of economics, ed. D. Greenwald. New York: McGraw-hill.Google Scholar
  34. Mataja, V. 1884. Der Unternehmergewinn. Vienna.Google Scholar
  35. Mayer, H. 1932. Der Erkenntniswert der Funktionellen Preistheorien. In Die Wirtschaftstheorie der Gegenwart, ed. H. Mayer. Vienna: Springer.Google Scholar
  36. McCulloch, J.H. 1977. The Austrian theory of the marginal use and of ordinal marginal utility. Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 37 (3–4): 249–280.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Menger, C. 1871. Grundsätze der Volkwirthschaftslehre. Trans. as Principles of economics, ed. J. Dingwall and B.F. Hoselitz, 1950; reprinted. New York: New York University Press, 1981.Google Scholar
  38. Menger, C. 1883. Untersuchungen über die Methode der Sozialwissenschaften und der politischen Ökonomie insbesondere. In Trans. F.J. Nock as Problems of economics and sociology, ed. L. Schneider, Urbana: University of Illinois Press, 1963. Reprinted as Investigations into the method of the social sciences with special reference to economics with a new Introduction by L.H. White, New York/London: New York University Press, 1985.Google Scholar
  39. Menger, K. Jr. 1973. Austrian marginalism and mathematical economics. In Carl Menger and the Austrian school of economics, ed. J.R. Hicks and W. Weber. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
  40. Meyer, R. 1887. Das Wesen des Einkommens: Eine volkswirthschaftliche Untersuchung. Berlin: Hertz.Google Scholar
  41. O’Driscoll, G.P. Jr. 1977. Economics as a coordination problem: The contributions of Friedrich A. Hayek. Kansas City: Sheed, Andrews & McMeel.Google Scholar
  42. O’Driscoll, G.P. Jr., and M.J. Rizzo. 1985. The economics of time and ignorance. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
  43. Orosel, G.O. 1981. Faber’s modern Austrian capital theory: A critical survey. Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 41: 141–155.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Robbins, L. 1932. The nature and significance of economic science. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  45. Rothbard, M.N. 1962. Man, economy, and state: A treatise on economic principles. Princeton: Van Nostrand.Google Scholar
  46. Sax, E. 1887. Grundlegung der Theoretischen Staatswirtschaft. Vienna: Holder.Google Scholar
  47. Schumpeter, J.A. 1908. Das Wesen und der Hauptinhalt der Theoretischen Nationalökonomie. Leipzig: Duncker & Humblot.Google Scholar
  48. Schumpeter, J.A. 1912. Theorie der wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung. Leipzig: Duncker & Humblot. English trans. as The theory of economic development. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1934.Google Scholar
  49. Schumpeter, J.A. 1954. History of economic analysis. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  50. Streissler, E. 1969. Structural economic thought: On the significance of the Austrian school today. Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 29 (3–4): 237–266.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  51. Streissler, E. 1972. To what extent was the Austrian school marginalist? History of Political Economy 4: 426–461.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  52. Streissler, E. 1973. The Mengerian tradition. In Carl Menger and the Austrian school of economics, ed. J.R. Hicks and W. Weber. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
  53. Streissler, E. 1986. Arma virumque cano. Friedrich von Wieser, the bard as economist. In Leser (1986).Google Scholar
  54. von Böhm-Bawerk, E. 1884. Geschichte und Kritik der Kapitalzins-Theorien. English trans. as vol. 1 of Capital and interest. South Holland: Libertarian Press, 1959.Google Scholar
  55. von Böhm-Bawerk, E. 1886. Grundzuge der Theorie des Wirtschaftlichen Guterwerths. Conrad’s Jahrbuch 13 (1–88): 477–541.Google Scholar
  56. von Böhm-Bawerk, E. 1889. Positive Theorie des Kapitales. Innsbruck: Wagner.Google Scholar
  57. von Böhm-Bawerk, E. 1891. The Austrian economists. The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 1: 361–384.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  58. von Böhm-Bawerk, E. 1896. Zum Abschluss des Marxschen Systems. In Trans. (1898) as Karl Marx and the close of his system, ed. P. Sweezy. New York: Kelley, 1949.Google Scholar
  59. von Komorzynski, J. 1889. Der Werth in der isolirten Wirthschaft. Vienna: Manz.Google Scholar
  60. von Mises, L. 1912. Theorie des Geldes und der Umlaufsmittel. Trans. as Theory of money and credit (1934). Indianapolis: Liberty Classics, 1980.Google Scholar
  61. von Mises, L. 1933. Grundprobleme der Nationalökonomie. Trans. as Epistemological problems of economics. Princeton: Van Nostrand, 1960.Google Scholar
  62. von Mises, L. 1940. Nationalökonomie Theorie des Handelns und Wirtschaftens. Geneva: Editions Union.Google Scholar
  63. von Mises, L. 1943. ‘Elastic expectations’ and the Austrian theory of the trade cycle. Economica 10: 251–252.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  64. von Mises, L. 1949. Human action: A treatise on economics. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  65. von Mises, L. 1969. The historical setting of the Austrian school of economics. New Rochelle: Arlington House.Google Scholar
  66. von Mises, L. 1978. Notes and recollections. South Holland: Libertarian Press.Google Scholar
  67. von Philippovich, E. Philippsberg. 1893. Grundriss der Politischen Ökonomie. Freiburg: Mohr.Google Scholar
  68. von Wieser, F. 1884. Ursprung des Wirtschaftlichen Wertes. Vienna: Hölder.Google Scholar
  69. von Wieser, F. 1914. Theorie der Gesellschaftlichen Wirtschaft. Tübingen: Mohr. Trans. as Social economics. London: G. Allen & Unwin, 1927; reprinted, New York: Kelley, 1967.Google Scholar
  70. Walras, L. 1874. Eléments d’économie politique pure. Lausanne: Corbaz.Google Scholar
  71. White, L.H. 1977. The methodology of the Austrian school economists. Revised ed. Auburn: The Ludwig von Mises Institute of Auburn University, 1984.Google Scholar
  72. Wieser, F. 1889. Der Naturliche Werth. Vienna: Hölder. In Trans. as Natural value, ed. W. Smart. London: Macmillan, 1893; reprinted, New York: Kelley, 1956.Google Scholar
  73. Zuckerkandl, R. 1889. Zur Theorie des Preises. Leipzig: Stein.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 2018

Authors and Affiliations

  • Israel M. Kirzner
    • 1
  1. 1.