The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics

2018 Edition
| Editors: Macmillan Publishers Ltd

History and Comparative Development

  • Louis Putterman
Reference work entry
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_2889

Abstract

What role do historical factors play in explaining the large differences in level of economic development among different countries and world regions today? Our answer begins with the observation that cross-country differences in level of economic development, as well as in rate of economic growth since the end of the European colonial era, are strongly correlated with the average levels of technological and political advance in the places the current population’s ancestors lived on the eve of that era and earlier. We explore recent literature in economics that addresses the evidence for and the causes of this correlation. The interplay between geography and human capital (broadly understood as including culture, norms, and institutional capability) has a central part in our discussion.

Keywords

Agricultural revolution Ancestry Colonial era Colonies Industrial revolution Less developed countries Linguistic distance Migration neolithic revolution 
This is a preview of subscription content, log in to check access

Bibliography

  1. Abramovitz, M. 1986. Catching up, forging ahead, and falling behind. Journal of Economic History 46: 385–406.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Abramovitz, M. 1995. The elements of social capability. In Social capability and long-term economic growth, ed. D.H. Perkins and B.H. Koo, 19–47. New York: St Martin’s Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Acemoglu, D., and J. Robinson. 2012. Why nations fail: The origins of power, prosperity, and poverty. New York: Crown Publishing.Google Scholar
  4. Acemoglu, D., S. Johnson, and J. Robinson. 2001. The colonial origins of comparative development: An empirical investigation. American Economic Review 91(5): 1369–1401.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Acemoglu, D., S. Johnson, and J. Robinson. 2002. Reversal of fortune: Geography and institutions in the making of the modern world income distribution. Quarterly Journal of Economics 117(4): 1231–1294.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Ang, J. 2013. Institutions and the long-run impact of early development. Journal of Development Economics 108: 1–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Ashraf, Q., and O. Galor. 2011. Dynamics and stagnation in the Malthusian epoch. American Economic Review 101(5): 2003–2041.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Bockstette, V., A. Chanda, and L. Putterman. 2002. States and markets: The advantage of an early start. Journal of Economic Growth 7: 347–369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Burkett, J., C. Humblet, and L. Putterman. 1999. Pre-industrial and post-war economic development: Is there a link? Economic Development and Cultural Change 47(3): 471–495.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Cavali-Sforza, L., P. Menozzi, and A. Piazza. 1994. The history and geography of human genes. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  11. Chanda, A., and L. Putterman. 2004. The quest for development: What role does history play? World Economics 5(2): 1–31.Google Scholar
  12. Chanda, A., and L. Putterman. 2007. Early starts, reversals and catch-up in the process of economic development. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 109(2): 387–413.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Chanda, A., C. J. Cook, and L. Putterman. 2014. Persistence of fortune: Accounting for population movements, there was no post-Columbian reversal. American Economic JournalMacroeconomics [in press, to appear in August issue].Google Scholar
  14. Comin, D., and B. Hobijn. 2010. An exploration of technology diffusion. American Economic Review 100(5): 2031–2059.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Comin, D., B. Hobijn, and E. Rovito. 2008. World technology usage lags. Journal of Economic Growth 13(4): 237–256.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Comin, D., W. Easterly, and E. Gong. 2010. Was the wealth of nations determined in 1000 B.C.? American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 2(3): 65–97.Google Scholar
  17. Diamond, J. 1997. Guns, germs and steel: The fate of human societies. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
  18. Dow, G., C. Reed, and N. Olewiler. 2009. Climate reversals and the transition to agriculture. Journal of Economic Growth 14(1): 27–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Easterly, W., and R. Levine. 2012. The European origins of economic development. NBER working paper no. 18162.Google Scholar
  20. Ertan, A., L. Putterman, and M. Fiszbein. 2012. Determinants and Economic consequences of colonization: A global analysis. Brown University Department of Economics working paper 2012–5.Google Scholar
  21. Gallup, J.L., J. Sachs, and A. Mellinger. 1999. Geography and economic growth. In Annual World Bank conference on development economics 1998, ed. B. Pleskovic and J. Stiglitz, 127–178. Washington: The World Bank.Google Scholar
  22. Glaeser, E., R. La Porta, F. Lopez-de-Silanes, and A. Shleifer. 2004. Do institutions cause growth? Journal of Economic Growth 9(3): 271–303.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Guiso, L., P. Sapienza, and L. Zingales. 2006. Does culture affect economic outcomes? Journal of Economic Perspectives 20(2): 23–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Hall, R., and C. Jones. 1999. Why do some countries produce so much more output per worker than others? The Quarterly Journal of Economics 114: 83–116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Heckman, J., J. Stixrud, and S. Urzua. 2006. The effects of cognitive and noncognitive abilities on labor market outcomes and social behavior. Journal of Labor Economics 24(3): 411–482.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Hibbs, D., and O. Olsson. 2004. Geography, biogeography, and why some countries are rich and others are poor. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 101(10): 3715–3720.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Johnson, A., and T. Earle. 2000. The evolution of human societies: From foraging groups to Agrarian State, 2nd ed. Stanford: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
  28. Landes, D. 1998. The wealth and poverty of nations. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
  29. Maddison, A. 2001. The world economy: A millennial perspective. Paris: Development Centre of the OECD.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Morris, I. 2010. Why the West rules – For now: The patterns of history, and what they reveal about the future. New York: Picador/Farrar/Straus and Giroux.Google Scholar
  31. Nelson, R., and S. Winter. 1982. An evolutionary theory of economic change. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  32. Nunn, N. 2014. Historical development. In Handbook of economic growth, vol. 2, ed. P. Aghion and S. Durlauf. Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
  33. Nunn, N., and N. Qian. 2010. The Columbian exchange: A history of disease, food, and ideas. Journal of Economic Perspectives 24(2): 163–188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Olsson, O., and D. Hibbs. 2005. Biogeography and long-run economic development. European Economic Review 49(4): 909–938.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Olsson, O., and C. Paik. 2013. A western reversal since the Neolithic? The long-run impact of early agriculture. Working papers in economics 552. University of Gothenburg.Google Scholar
  36. Pomeranz, K. 2000. The great divergence: China, Europe, and the making of the modern world economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  37. Putterman, L. 2000. Can an evolutionary approach to development predict post-war economic growth? Journal of Development Studies 36(3): 1–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Putterman, L. 2008. Agriculture, diffusion, and development: Ripple effects of the Neolithic revolution. Economica 75: 729–748.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Putterman, L., and D. Weil. 2010. Post-1500 population flows and the long run determinants of economic growth and inequality. Quarterly Journal of Economics 125(4): 1627–1682.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Richerson, P., B. Vila, and M. B. Mulder. 2001. Principles of human ecology. Unpublished. Davis: University of California. Available at http://www.des.ucdavis.edu/faculty/Richerson/BooksOnline/101text.htm. Accessed 12 March 2014.
  41. Service, E. 1971. Cultural evolutionism: Theory in practice. New York: Holt/Rinehart and Winston.Google Scholar
  42. Spolaore, E., and R. Wacziarg. 2009. The diffusion of development. Quarterly Journal of Economics 124(2): 469–529.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  43. Spolaore, E., and R. Wacziarg. 2012. Long-term barriers to the international diffusion of innovations. In NBER international seminar on macroeconomics 2011, ed. J. Frankel and C. Pissarides, 11–46. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  44. Spolaore, E., and R. Wacziarg. 2013a. How deep are the roots of economic development? Journal of Economic Literature 51(2): 325–369.Google Scholar
  45. Spolaore, E., and R. Wacziarg. 2013b. Long-term barriers to economic development. NBER working paper #19361.Google Scholar
  46. Temple, J., and P. Johnson. 1998. Social capability and economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 113(3): 965–990.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  47. Voigtlander, N., and H.J. Voth. 2013. The three horsemen of riches: Plague, war and urbanization in early modern Europe. Review of Economic Studies 80(2): 774–811.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 2018

Authors and Affiliations

  • Louis Putterman
    • 1
  1. 1.