The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics

2018 Edition
| Editors: Macmillan Publishers Ltd

Labour Supply

  • Richard Blundell
  • Thomas MaCurdy
Reference work entry
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_2360

Abstract

The analysis of labour supply is placed in a general framework within which empirical models and their resulting elasticity estimates can be interpreted. An explicitly intertemporal life-cycle structure is developed for the choice of hours and participation. The relationship between economic substitution effects found in the labour supply literature and wage impacts on different concepts of employment is considered. We provide a separate discussion of the main issues surrounding the analysis of family labour supply and the analysis of the impact of taxation. We conclude with a discussion on the interpretation of labour supply elasticities for policy analysis.

Keywords

Benefit take-up Collective models of the household Cost functions Dynamic programming Employment Engel curve Euler equations Frisch specification Hicksian effect Hours worked Indirect utility function Labour supply Linear expenditure system Marshallian effect Optimal taxation Reservation wage Retirement Slutsky effect Tax credits 

JEL Classifications

J2 
This is a preview of subscription content, log in to check access.

Bibliography

  1. Abbott, M., and O. Ashenfelter. 1976. Labor supply, commodity demand and the allocation of time. Review of Economic Studies 43: 389–411.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Altonji, J.G. 1982. The intertemporal substitution model of labour market fluctuations: An empirical analysis. Review of Economic Studies 49: 783–824.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Altonji, J.G. 1986. Intertemporal substitution in labor supply: Evidence from micro data. Journal of Political Economy 94: S176–S215.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Altug, S., and R. Miller. 1990. Household choices in equilibrium. Econometrica 58: 543–570.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Altug, S., and R. Miller. 1998. The effect of work experience on female wages and labour supply. Review of Economic Studies 65: 45–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Apps, P.F., and R. Rees. 1997. Collective labor supply and household production. Journal of Political Economy 105: 178–190.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Arellano, M., and C. Meghir. 1992. Female labour supply and on-the-job search: An empirical model estimated using complementary data sets. Review of Economic Studies 59: 537–559.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Arrufat, J.L., and A. Zabalza. 1986. Female labour supply with taxation, random preferences, and optimization errors. Econometrica 54: 47–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Ashenfelter, O. 1983. Determining participation in income-tested social programs. Journal of the American Statistical Society 78: 517–525.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Ashenfelter, O., and J. Ham. 1979. Education, unemployment and earnings. Journal of Political Economy 87: S99–S166.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Ashenfelter, O., and J.J. Heckman. 1974. The estimation of income and substitution effects in a model of family labor supply. Econometrica 42: 73–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Ashenfelter, O., and M.W. Plant. 1990. Nonparametric estimates of the labor-supply effects of negative income tax programs. Journal of Labor Economics 8: S396–S415.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Becker, G.S. 1965. A theory of the allocation of time. Economic Journal 75: 493–517.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Ben-Porath, Y. 1973. Economic analysis of fertility in Israel: Point and counterpoint. Journal of Political Economy 81: S202–S233.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Bingley, P., and I. Walker. 1997. The labour supply, unemployment and participation of lone mothers in in-work transfer programs. Economic Journal 107: 1375–1390.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Blau, D.M. 1994. Labor force dynamics of older men. Econometrica 62: 117–156.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Blau, D., and P. Robins. 1988. Child-care costs and family labor supply. Review of Economics and Statistics 70: 374–381.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Blomquist, N.S. 1983. The effect of income taxation on the labour supply of married men in Sweden. Journal of Public Economics 22: 169–197.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Blomquist, S., and W. Newey. 2002. Nonparametric estimation with nonlinear budget sets. Econometrica 70: 2455–2480.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Blundell, R. 1998. Consumer Demand and Intertemporal Allocations: Engel, Slutsky and Frisch, In Stienar Strom (ed), The Raynar Frisch Centennial Symposium, Econometric Society Monographs 31, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
  21. Blundell, R. 2006. Earned income tax credit policies: Impact and optimality: The Adam Smith lecture. Labour Economics 13(4): 423–443.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Blundell, R., and H. Hoynes. 2004. Has in-work benefit reform helped the labour market? In Seeking a premier league economy, ed. R. Blundell, D. Card, and R.B. Freeman. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  23. Blundell, R.W., and T. MaCurdy. 1999. Labor supply: A review of alternative approaches. In Handbook of labor economics, ed. O. Ashenfelter and D. Card, Vol. 3A. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
  24. Blundell, R.W., and I. Walker. 1982. Modelling the joint determination of household labour supplies and commodity demands. Economic Journal 92: 58–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Blundell, R.W., and I. Walker. 1986. A life-cycle consistent empirical model of family labour supply using cross-section data. Review of Economic Studies 53: 539–558.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Blundell, R.W., J. Ham, and C. Meghir. 1987. Unemployment and female labour supply. Economic Journal 97: 44–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Blundell, R.W., C. Meghir, E. Symons, and I. Walker. 1988. Labour supply specification and the evaluation of tax reforms. Journal of Public Economics 36: 23–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Blundell, R.W., A. Duncan, and C. Meghir. 1992. Taxation in empirical labour supply models: Lone mothers in the UK. Economic Journal 102: 265–278.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Blundell, R., C. Meghir, and P. Neves. 1993. Labour supply and intertemporal substitution. Journal of Econometrics 59: 137–160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Blundell, R., A. Duncan, and C. Meghir. 1998. Estimating labor supply responses using tax reforms. Econometrica 66: 827–861.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Blundell, R., A. Duncan, J. McCrae, and C. Meghir. 2000. The labour market impact of the working families’ tax credit. Fiscal Studies 21: 75–104.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Blundell, R., P.-A. Chiappori, and C. Meghir. 2005. Collective labour supply with children. Journal of Political Economy 113: 1277–1306.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Blundell, R., P.A. Chiappori, T. Magnac, and C. Meghir. 2006. Collective labor supply: Heterogeneity and non-participation. Review of Economic Studies 74: 417–445.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Blundell, R.W., T. MaCurdy, and C. Meghir. 2007. Estimation and specification in labor supply models. In Handbook of econometrics, ed. J.J. Heckman and E. Leamer, Vol. 7. Amsterdam: North-Holland (forthcoming).Google Scholar
  35. Boskin, M. 1973. Economics of the labor supply. In Labor supply and income maintenance, ed. G. Cain and H. Watts. Chicago: Rand McNally.Google Scholar
  36. Brewer, M., A. Duncan, A. Shephard, and M.J. Suárez. 2006. Did working families’ tax credit work? The impact of in-work support on labour supply in Great Britain. Labour Economics 13: 699–720.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Browning, M., A. Deaton, and M. Irish. 1985. A profitable approach to labor supply and commodity demands over the life-cycle. Econometrica 53: 503–544.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Burtless, G., and J.A. Hausman. 1978. The effect of taxation on labor supply: Evaluating the Gary negative income tax experiment. Journal of Political Economy 86: 1103–1130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Cain, G. 1966. Married women in the labor force. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  40. Card, D. 1994. Intertemporal labor supply: An assessment. In Advances in econometrics, Sixth World Congress, ed. C. Sims. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  41. Card, D., and P.K. Robins. 1998. Do financial incentives encourage welfare recipients to work? Evidence from a randomized evaluation of the self-sufficiency project. In Research in labor economics, ed. S. Polachek, Vol. 17. Greenwich: JAI Press.Google Scholar
  42. Chiappori, P.-A. 1988. Rational household labor supply. Econometrica 56: 63–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  43. Chiappori, P.-A. 1992. Collective labor supply and welfare. Journal of Political Economy 100: 437–467.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Chiappori, P.-A. 1997. Introducing household production in collective models of labor supply. Journal of Political Economy 105: 191–209.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  45. Chone, P.-A., and G. Laroque. 2005. Optimal incentives for labor force participation. Journal of Public Economics 89: 395–425.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  46. Cogan, J.F. 1980. Labor supply with costs of labor market entry. In Female labor supply: Theory and estimation, ed. J. Smith. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  47. Cogan, J.F. 1981. Fixed costs and labor supply. Econometrica 49: 945–964.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  48. Donni, O. 2003. Collective household labor supply: Nonparticipation and income taxation. Journal of Public Economics 87: 1179–1198.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  49. Eckstein, Z., and K. Wolpin. 1989. Dynamic labour force participation of married women and endogenous work experience. Review of Economic Studies 56: 375–390.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  50. Eissa, N., and H. Hoynes. 2004. Taxes and the labor market participation of married couples: The earned income tax credit. Journal of Public Economics 88: 1931–1958.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  51. Eissa, N., and J. Liebman. 1996. Labor supply response to the earned income tax credit. Quarterly Journal of Economics 111: 605–637.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  52. Feldstein, M. 1995. The effect of marginal tax rates on taxable income: A panel study of the 1986 tax reform act. Journal of Political Economy 103: 551–572.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  53. Fortin, B., and G. Lacroix. 1997. A test of the unitary and collective models of household labour supply. Economic Journal 107: 933–955.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  54. Fraker, T., and R. Moffitt. 1988. The effect of food stamps on labor supply: A bivariate selection model. Journal of Public Economics 35: 25–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  55. Gorman, W.M. 1959. Separable utility and aggregation. Econometrica 27: 469–481.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  56. Gorman, W.M. 1968. The structure of utility functions. Review of Economic Studies 35: 367–390.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  57. Gorman, W.M. 1976. Tricks with utility functions. In Essays in economic analysis, ed. M. Artis and R. Nobay. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  58. Gorman, W.M. 1961. On a class of preference fields. Metroeconomica 13, 53–56. Repr. in Separability and Aggregation: Collected Works of M. Gorman, vol. 1, ed. C. Blackorby and A.F. Shorrocks. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1995.Google Scholar
  59. Gronau, R. 1974. Wage comparisons: A selectivity bias. Journal of Political Economy 82: 1119–1144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  60. Gruber, J., and E. Saez. 2002. The elasticity of taxable income: Evidence and implications. Journal of Public Economics 84: 1–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  61. Hall, R. 1973. Wages, income and hours of work in the US labor force. In Income maintenance and labor supply, ed. G. Cain and H. Watts. Chicago: Chicago University Press.Google Scholar
  62. Ham, J. 1986. Testing whether unemployment represents intertemporal labour supply behaviour. Review of Economic Studies 53: 559–578.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  63. Hanoch, G. 1965. The ‘backward-bending’ supply of labor. Journal of Political Economy 73: 636–642.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  64. Hanoch, G. 1980. A multivariate model of labor supply. In Female labor supply: Theory and estimation, ed. J. Smith. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  65. Hanoch, G., and M. Honig. 1983. Retirement, wages, and labor supply of the elderly. Journal of Labor Economics 1: 131–151.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  66. Hansen, L.P., and K. Singleton. 1983. Stochastic consumption, risk aversion, and the temporal behavior of asset returns. Journal of Political Economy 91: 249–265.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  67. Hausman, J. 1980. The effect of wages, taxes and fixed costs on women’s labor force participation. Journal of Pubic Economics 14: 161–194.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  68. Hausman, J. 1981. Labor supply. In How taxes affect economic behavior? ed. H. Aaron and J. Pechman. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
  69. Hausman, J. 1985a. The econometrics of nonlinear budget sets. Econometrica 53: 1255–1282.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  70. Hausman, J. 1985b. Taxes and labor supply. In Handbook of public economics, ed. A. Auerbach and M. Feldstein, Vol. 1A. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
  71. Hausman, J., and P. Ruud. 1984. Family labor supply with taxes. American Economic Review 74: 242–248.Google Scholar
  72. Heckman, J.J. 1974a. Shadow prices, market wages, and labor supply. Econometrica 42: 679–694.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  73. Heckman, J.J. 1974b. Life cycle consumption and labor supply: An explanation of the relationship between income and consumption over the life cycle. American Economic Review 64: 188–194.Google Scholar
  74. Heckman, J.J. 1974c. Effects of child-care programs on women’s work effort. Journal of Political Economy 82: S136–S163.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  75. Heckman, J.J. 1976. Life-cycle model of earnings, learning and consumption. Journal of Political Economy 84: S11–S44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  76. Heckman, J.J. 1979. Sample selection bias as a specification error. Econometrica 47: 153–161.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  77. Heckman, J.J. 1993. What has been learned about labor supply in the past twenty years. American Economic Review 83: 116–121.Google Scholar
  78. Heckman, J.J., and T.E. MaCurdy. 1980. A life-cycle model of female labour supply. Review of Economic Studies 47: 47–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  79. Hotz, V.J., F.E. Kydland, and G.L. Sedlacek. 1988. Intertemporal preferences and labor supply. Econometrica 56: 335–360.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  80. Hoynes, H. 1996. Welfare transfers in two-parent families: Labor supply and welfare participation under the AFDC-UP program. Econometrica 64: 295–332.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  81. Hoynes, H. 2000. The employment, earnings and income of less skilled workers over the business cycle. In Finding jobs: Work and welfare reform, ed. D.E. Card and R. Blank. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.Google Scholar
  82. Hurd, M.D., and M.J. Boskin. 1984. The effect of social security on retirement in the early 1970s. Quarterly Journal of Economics 99: 767–790.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  83. Immervol, H., H.J. Kleven, C.T. Kreiner, and E. Saez. 2007. Welfare reform in European countries: A microsimulation analysis. Economic Journal 117: 1–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  84. Johnson, T.R., and J.H. Pencavel. 1984. Dynamic hours of work functions for husbands, wives and single females. Econometrica 52: 363–389.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  85. Keane, M.P., and R. Moffitt. 1998. A structural model of multiple welfare program participation and labor supply. International Economic Review 39: 553–589.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  86. Killingsworth, M.R. 1983. Labor supply. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  87. Killingsworth, M.R., and J.J. Heckman. 1986. Female labor supply: A survey. In Handbook of labor economics, ed. O. Ashenfelter and R. Layard, Vol. 1. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
  88. Kooreman, P., and A. Kapteyn. 1990. On the empirical implementation of some game theoretic models of household labor supply. Journal of Human Resources 25: 584–598.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  89. Krueger, A.B.., and J.-S. Pischke. 1992. The effect of social security on labor supply: A cohort analysis of the notch generation. Journal of Labor Economics 10: 412–437.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  90. Laroque, G. 2004. Income maintenance and labour force participation. Econometrica 73: 341–376.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  91. Lewis, H.G. 1967. On income and substitution effects in labor force participation. Unpublished manuscript, University of Chicago.Google Scholar
  92. Low, H. 2005. Self-insurance and unemployment benefit in a life-cycle model of labour supply and savings. Review of Economic Dynamics 8: 945–975.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  93. Lundberg, S. 1988. Labor supply of husbands and wives: A simultaneous equations approach. Review of Economics and Statistics 70: 224–235.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  94. MaCurdy, T.E. 1981. An empirical model of labour supply in a life-cycle setting. Journal of Political Economy 89: 1059–1085.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  95. MaCurdy, T.E. 1983. A simple scheme for estimating an intertemporal model of labor supply and consumption in the presence of taxes and uncertainty. International Economic Review 24: 265–289.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  96. MaCurdy, T.E. 1985. Interpreting empirical models of labour supply in an intertemporal framework with uncertainty. In Longitudinal analysis of labor market data, ed. J.J. Heckman and B. Singer. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  97. MaCurdy, T.E. 1992. Work disincentive effects of taxes: A reexamination of some evidence. American Economic Review 82: 243–249.Google Scholar
  98. MaCurdy, T.E., D. Green, and H. Paarsch. 1990. Assessing empirical approaches for analyzing taxes and labour supply. Journal of Human Resources 25: 415–490.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  99. McElroy, M.B. 1981. Empirical results from estimates of joint labor supply functions of husbands and wives. In Research in labor economics, ed. R.G. Ehrenberg, Vol. 4. Greenwich: JAI Press.Google Scholar
  100. Mincer, J. 1960. Labor supply, family income, and consumption. American Economic Review 50: 574–583.Google Scholar
  101. Mincer, J. 1962. Labor force participation of married women: A study of labor supply. In Aspects in labor economics, ed. H.G. Lewis. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  102. Mirrlees, J. 1971. An exploration in the theory of optimum income taxation. Review of Economic Studies 38: 175–208.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  103. Moffitt, R. 1983. An economic model of welfare stigma. American Economic Review 73: 1023–1035.Google Scholar
  104. Moffitt, R. 1986. The econometrics of piecewise-linear budget constraints: A survey and exposition of the maximum likelihood method. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 4: 317–327.Google Scholar
  105. Moffitt, R. 2002a. Economic effects of means-tested transfers in the US. In Tax policy and the economy, ed. J.M. Poterba, Vol. 16. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  106. Moffitt, R.A. 2002b. Welfare programs and labor supply. In Handbook of public economics, ed. A.J. Auerbach and M. Feldstein, Vol. 4. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
  107. Moffitt, R. 2006. Welfare work requirements with paternalistic government preferences. Economic Journal 116: F441–F458.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  108. Mroz, T.A. 1987. The sensitivity of an empirical model of married women’s hours of work to economic and statistical assumptions. Econometrica 55: 765–799.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  109. Muellbauer, J. 1981. Linear aggregation in neoclassical labour supply. Review of Economic Studies 48: 21–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  110. Pencavel, J. 1986. Labor supply of men: A survey. In Handbook of labor economics, ed. O. Ashenfelter and R. Layard, Vol. 1. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
  111. Rust, J., and C. Phelan. 1997. How Social Security and Medicare affect retirement behavior in a world of incomplete markets. Econometrica 65: 781–831.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  112. Saez, E. 2001. Using elasticities to derive optimal income tax rates. Review of Economic Studies 68: 205–239.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  113. Saez, E. 2002. Optimal income transfer programs: Intensive versus extensive labor supply responses. Quarterly Journal of Economics 117: 1039–1073.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  114. Scholz, J.K. 1996. In-work benefits in the United States: The Earned Income Tax Credit. Economic Journal 106: 156–169.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  115. Shaw, K. 1989. Life-cycle labour supply with human capital accumulation. International Economic Review 30: 431–457.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  116. Stern, N. 1986. On the specification of labor supply functions. In Unemployment, search and labour supply, ed. R.W. Blundell and I. Walker. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  117. van Soest, A. 1995. Structural models of family labor supply: A discrete choice approach. Journal of Human Resources 30: 63–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  118. Wales, T.J., and A. Woodland. 1976. Estimation of household utility functions and labor supply response. International Economic Review 17: 397–410.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 2018

Authors and Affiliations

  • Richard Blundell
    • 1
  • Thomas MaCurdy
    • 1
  1. 1.